un pan 025713

Upload: tunggul-ardhi

Post on 04-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    1/22

    AFRICAN ASSOCIATION FOR PUBLIC

    ADMINISTRATION AND MANAGEMENT

    26THAAPAM ANNUAL ROUNDTABLE CONFERENCE,

    WHITESANDS HOTEL, MOMBASA, KENYA 7TH 11THMARCH,

    2005

    TOPIC : DEMOCRATIZATION, GOOD GOVERNANCE ANDADMINISTRATION REFORM IN AFRICA

    DR PAUL N. NDUE

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    2/22

    I N T R O D U C T I O N

    This paper examines the often neglected relationship between

    democratisation and governance on one hand, and administrative reform

    on the other, that has characterised the literature. It argues that

    administrative reform is an essential prerequisite to democratisation and

    governance and that any attempt to delink the three concepts will make

    democratisation and governance a farce. In other words, any political

    reform at democratizing institutions, in particular the founding of a pluralistic

    democracy, will only be fully effective insofar as it is accompanied by far

    reaching administrative reforms which effectively redistribute power. The

    paper also discusses the implications of this link between democratisation,

    governance and administrative reform for public administration in Africa.

    1- WHAT IS DEMOCRATISATION?

    The concept democratisation defies precise definition. In its

    minimalist/formalist definition or delineation, democratisation has the

    criteria of regular electoral competitions, usually in a multiparty political

    system, and thus governmental succession by constitutional, electoral

    procedures, guaranteed in the rule of law. On the other hand, the

    maximalist socio-economic delineation of democratisation include the

    criteria such as redistributive socio-economic reforms, broadened popular

    participation, social justice and human rights (Qadir et. al., 193:416).

    According to Elly Runierse (1993) three stages of the process of

    democratization may be discerned. First, is the political liberalization, which

    has been defined as the process in which the fear of repression is relaxed

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    3/22

    and there are constitutional guarantees of a range of political freedoms

    (especially the recognition of the right of opposition groupings to function

    and to express dissent) in which there is greater independence for

    legislative assemblies where they still exist, and freedom of the press.

    (Healey and Robinson, 1992:22). To Qadir et. al. (1993:416), political

    liberalization is a process of political change controlled from the top down,

    as means of preserving most of the status quo. They seem to be cynical of

    political liberalization, which they regard as the game the elites play to

    manage the granting of very carefully selected concessions a cosmetic

    exercise and does not install the fundamentals of democratization. Qadir

    et al. (1993:416-417) however concede that political change escapes from

    elite control to encompass broader social forces and its purpose is

    transformed from the preservation to the status quo of interests to genuine

    reform. They conclude that the processes of democratization and political

    liberalization are distinct, and only the truly deserving cases should be

    referred to as democratization, where ultimate outcome of the process and

    its agency are almost the reverse of political liberalization (Qadir,

    1993:417). Anything short of this is to trivialize the concept of

    democratization, and worse still, to mislead people. (Qadir et. al., 1993:

    417) Adrain Ledtwich (1993:616) takes their warning further by pointing that

    faith in the economic and political liberalism of the minimal state as the

    universally appropriate means of development is deeply flawed. Perhaps a

    more forceful and cynical attempt to press home the point that

    democratization and political liberalization are not the same and are

    therefore distinct has been made by lemarchand (1992:183-184):

    For, if by liberalization is meant the dismantling of dictatorships, there are

    good reasons to assume that liberalization can occur without

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    4/22

    democratization and that in some parts of Africa the disintegration of

    authoritarian rule may be followed by anarchy or intensified corruption.

    Second, it is the process of growing political accountability which has been

    viewed as a move towards more inclusive politics, even within a single-

    party system, through the introduction of measures to extend societal

    participation in political decision-making (Healey and Robinson, 1992:151).

    Third, is to regard democratization as a historical process rather than an

    end state that seems to involve the introduction of universal suffrage and

    genuine political competition with free and fair elections to decide who will

    take power (Healey and Robinson, 1992:151).

    II DEMOCRATIZATION AND GOOD GOVERNANCE

    Democratization has been linked to good governance, which the World

    Bank defines as the exercise of political power to manage a nations

    affairs (World Bank, 1989:60) and also regards as synonymous with sound

    development (World Bank, 1992-1). The relationship between

    democratization and good governance, supported and promoted by

    institutions such as the World Bank, United States, British and French

    governments, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and

    Development (OECD) the United Nations Development Programme

    (UNDP), the European Council and the Commonwealth Secretariat, is

    based on the fact that the latter (good governance) has the ingredients,

    features, the functional and institutional prerequisites as well as the building

    blocks of democratization. These include an efficient public service; an

    independent judicial system and legal framework to enforce contracts; the

    accountable administration of public funds ; an independent public auditor,

    representative legislature; respect for the law and human rights at all levels

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    5/22

    of government; a pluralistic institutional structure; and a free press (World

    Bank, 1989:6, 15, 60-61, 192). According to Leftwich (1993; 1994) the

    concept of democratic good governance has the three main levels of

    meaning which can be classified into systemic, political and administrative.

    First, from a systematic angle, good governance is government that

    embraces the formed institutional structure location of authoritarian

    decision making in the modern state power. In this sense, good

    governance denotes the structures of political and crucially, economic

    relationships and rules by which the productive and distributive life of a

    society is governed (Leftwich, 1993:611; Leftwich, 1994:371). In short,

    good governance means a democratic capitalist regime presided over by

    a minimal state which forms part of the wider governance of the New World

    Order (World Bank, 1989; World Bank, 1992; Healey and Robinson;

    Leftwich 1994).

    Second, from a political sense, good governance presupposes a regime or

    state which enjoys legitimacy and authority, derived from a democratic

    mandate and built on the traditional liberal notion of a clear separation of

    legislative, executive and judicial powers. Whether in a presidential or

    parliamentary system, this presupposes a pluralist polity with a freely and

    regularly elected representative legislature, with the capacity at least to

    influence and check executive power (Leftwich, 1993: Leftwich, 1994).

    Third, from an administrative point of view, good governance means an

    efficient, independent, accountable and open audited public service which

    has the bureaucratic competence to help design and implement

    appropriate policies and manage whatever public sector there is. It also

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    6/22

    entails an independent judicial system to uphold the law and resolve

    disputes arising in a largely free market economy. The administrative

    aspect of good governance focuses on four main areas of public

    administration in general and public sector management in particular. They

    are:

    - accountability, which in essence means holding officials responsible for

    their actions;

    - a legal framework for development, which means a structure of rules

    and laws which provide clarity, predictability and stability for the private

    sector, which are impartially and fairly applied to all, and which provide

    the basis for conflict resolution through an independent judicial system;

    - information, by which is meant that information about economic

    conditions, budgets, markets and government intentions is reliable and

    accessible to all, something which is crucial for private sector

    calculations;

    - insistence on transparency, which is basically a call for open

    government, to enhance accountability, limit corruption and stimulate

    consultative processes between government and private interests over

    policy development (World Bank, 1992; Leftwich, 1993; Leftwich, 1993).

    Viewed from the foregoing connotations of good governance, it is no

    wonder that the concept is inseparable from the process of

    democratization.

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    7/22

    III - WHAT IS ADMINISTRATIVE REFORM?

    Like democratization, the concept of administrative reform does not lend

    itself to a clear-cut definition. However, the definition, which is commonly

    used because of its comprehensiveness and scope, is the one offered by

    Gerald Caiden (1969). According to Caiden (1960:65) administrative reform

    is the artificial inducement of administrative need to improve on the

    status), artificial transformation (departure from existing arrangements and

    natural change processes), and administrative resistance (opposition is

    assumed). Administrative reform is political rather than merely

    organizational. It is a political process designed to adjust the relationship

    between a bureaucracy and other elements in society or within the

    bureaucracy itself (Montgomery, 1967:17). Succinctly put, administrative

    reform is:

    Power politics in action; it contains ideological rationalization, fights for

    control of areas, services, and people, political participants and

    institutions (Caiden, 1969:9).

    Administrative reform has a moral content in that it seeks to create a

    better system by removing faults and imperfections. It is usually

    undertaken to change the status quo for the better. It aims at making the

    administrative and political structures and procedures compatible with

    broader goals. Administrative reform sets additional political values to be

    used as yardsticks against which administrative performance may be

    judged. The crux of administrative reform, therefore, is innovation and

    wealth creation that is, injection of new ideas and new people in a new

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    8/22

    combination of tasks and relationships into the policy and administrative

    process. Administrative reform may occur where two conditions are met.

    - a set value with which the existing bureaucratic arrangements, public

    personnel and values are seen to be in conflict.

    - The concern by politicians and the general public that the existing

    bureaucratic structures cannot realize new goals set for them.

    Consequently, administrative reform may involve centralizing or

    decentralizing initiatives or both: the denominators are away from or

    towards the centre (Caiden, 1969; United Nations, 1973; Dror, 1976;

    Leemans, 1976).

    Administrative reform involves system diagnosis, that is, examination of

    administrative systems to detect what is wrong and what can be improved.

    Given that all systems are imperfect, system diagnosis is not difficult.

    Getting the right solution is something else. As in medicine, the same

    symptoms may have several possible causes, some of little consequence,

    others serious. A wrong diagnosis may prove quite harmful. Every system,

    like patient, needs careful examination and the selection of those remedies

    that best fit in peculiar circumstances, not a superficial examination,

    acceptance of the clients own diagnosis, and hasty reference to standard

    texts (Caiden, 1978: 114; Caiden, 1988).

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    9/22

    IV DEMOCRATIZATION, GOOD GOVERNANCE AND

    ADMINISTRATION REFORM AS A MEANS OF INNOVATION AND

    WEALTH CREATION.

    Democratization, good governance and administrative reform are related in

    a number of ways first, they are all concerned with institution and capacity

    building. The process of democratization and the concept of governance

    involve institution and capacity building aimed at not only the improvement

    of governmental capacity but also the creation of more efficient and more

    autonomous state and civil institutions, capable of ushering in development

    in the Third World. The over-development of the post-colonial state, with

    the vast expansion of its size, regulatory powers and administrative

    responsibilities led to the erosion of its efficiency, authority and economic

    viability and these are supposed to be corrected via institution and

    capacity building methods of rolling the state back (decentralization,

    privatization, and deregulation) and liberalization. For instance, with

    economic liberalization, the corruption and other administrative weakness

    encouraged by over-regulation would be minimised, if not eradicated

    (Jeffries, 1993). Administrative reform, in the other hand, is also concerned

    with incorporated, foster and protect (new) normative relationships and

    actions patterns, (b) perform functions and services which are valued in

    the environment, and (c) facilitate the assimilation of new physical and

    social technologies. Such organizations are instruments of planned change

    in the administrative system. They bring about reform by their linkages

    (enabling, functional, normative and diffused) with their environment. Their

    effectiveness depends on the quality of their leadership and the

    appropriateness of their internal structures. Quality leadership can be

    trusted to decide on correct tactics while appropriate structures will ensure

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    10/22

    survival. In short, to distinguish institution and capacity building

    characteristics of democratization, good governance and administrative

    reform concentrate their energies on building a few key strategic

    instruments in an administrative system and maximise the use of scarce

    reform resources. The three concepts also draw attention to factors such

    as legitimacy, leadership, timing, rationale, appropriateness, goals and

    reform resources which can be incorporated into useful reform monitoring

    guides.

    Secondly, democratization, good governance and administrative reforms

    are being embarked upon to promote development in the Third World.

    Caiden (1973), for instance, has asserted that development is enhanced by

    administrative reform programmes in four ways. First, reform proposals

    challenge bureaucratic inertia and reactionary administrators and although

    defence mechanisms may temporarily suppress change, things can never

    quite be the same and peace tokens have to be made if the situation is to

    be kept in hand. Second, reform programmes attract enterprising

    administrative talent and provide valuable experience for a new generation

    of administrative aspirants. Third, reformers promote badly needed

    administrative modernization which is likely to set off a chain reaction in

    functional reforms as changes in techniques, skills and attitudes in

    specialized fields seems more attainable than possibly the harder changes

    to carry through in administration. Fourth, administrative reform introduces

    some inventiveness in outmoded systems, obsolete institutions, inert

    bureaucracies and in an environment of official indifference, technical

    ignorance, political intransigence and public apathy. Hence administrative

    reform demands most of administrators in countries unable to sustain

    administration at minimal and unacceptable levels:

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    11/22

    encased in outmoded legalistic codes, obsessed by mimicry of great

    powers, deficient in administrative talent, or suffering from excessive

    institutionalised poverty, where reform, even if partial, sporadic, episodic,

    and periodic, is cumulative in transforming and modernizing administrative

    systems for development purposes (Caiden, 1973: 344).

    Fifthly, administrative reform is premised on the fact that lasting change is

    the product of sharing and participation. Proposals for administrative reform

    need to be formulated with the active involvement of those likely to be

    affected to reduce resistance. Human behaviour, it must be pointed out,

    cannot be effectively changed through coercion (Caiden, 1978: 114).

    On the other hand good governance and democratisation have been

    regarded as remedies for the difficult problems of development. For

    instance, the 1989 World Bank report on Africa 1989 has argued that a

    crisis of governance underlay the litany of Africas development

    problems and good governance, which was meant as the exercise of

    political power to manage a nations affairs (World Bank, 1989: 60) is to

    become magin world, pluralistic institutional structure (World Bank,

    1989: 60). In other words, good governance and democratisation are to

    promote a legal framework for development, capacity building, and the civil

    society, which is linked to the fostering of accountability, legitimacy,

    transparency and participation as it is these factors which empower civil

    society and reduce the power of the state (World Bank, 1992; Williams and

    Young, 1994 : 87).

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    12/22

    Some scholars have, however, questioned the validity of democratisation,

    governance and administrative reform in promoting development in the

    Third World, especially Africa. According to Leftwich (1994), effective

    development has often required that some quite radical steps are taken

    early on in a development cycle. These might include land reform or wage

    restraint, which are precisely the kind of measures which may alienate

    major socio-economic groups whose consent is necessary for stable

    democracy. There is also abundant empirical evidence which seems to

    show that many of the successful examples of late development since the

    mid-nineteenth century, as in Germany, Japan, Korea or Thailand, have

    occurred under conditions which have not remotely approximated

    competitive democracy, though some have moved or are now moving in a

    democratic direction, as in Indonesia or Korea (Leftwich, 1994 : 364).

    Democratization cannot result into coherent development strategies in

    Africa where there exists debilitating conditions, like the incapacity of most

    states to exercise effective jurisdiction over their societies, low levels of

    legitimacy, consensus and elite commitment, absence of a robust and

    substantial middle class, powerful middle working class which push for and

    protect democratic advance, limited civil society that is seldom independent

    and has often enmeshed with the state, the fractures nature of many

    African societies and their politics by ethnic, religious and regional

    pluralism, sustained economic crisis and subsequent liberalization that

    have a heavy price on the poor, rumours of coups and counter coups as

    well as a proliferation of political parties that emerged with the opening up

    of democratic possibilities over 200 in Zaire, 100 in Cameroon, 71 in the

    Congo, 30 in Angola and 26 in Cte dIvoire (Leftwich, 1993:617). With

    these conditions in Africa and some other Third World countries, Leftwich

    (1994:364), sounding rather pessimistic, cautions that:

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    13/22

    Democratization in the socio-political and economic conditions which in

    much of the third world and elsewhere is likely to engender political

    turbulence and also blow stable market friendly development strategies

    wildly off course. As the 1990s unfold, therefore, it seems likely that we

    shall see a period of democratic reversal, not consolidation, much of the

    developing world and parts of Eastern Europe.

    Richard Jeffries (1993:30) has also pointed out that democratisation may

    not result in development. He argued that although democratic regimes

    are electorally accountable and popularly responsive in Africa, they have

    generally been responsive not to the interest of an indigenous, market-

    oriented group, but rather to:

    - pressure from urban-dwellers to expand government employment;

    - clienteles networks pressing for redistribution (rather than concentration)

    of capital, often along ethnic/religion lines;

    - rent-seekers. Consequently, it is important for one to recognise the fact

    that:

    democratisation in an African setting is unlikely in itself to reduce

    corruption/prebendalisation or the pressures for (from a development

    perspective) wasteful government expenditure. Groups of electors support

    particular parliamentary candidates, precisely in the hope that they will

    succeed in prebendalising government offices in their favour Elected

    civilian regimes in African states are, then, under intense popular pressure

    to be economically irresponsible and short-sighted (Jeffries, 1993 :30).

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    14/22

    These criticisms notwithstanding, it is pertinent to point out that

    instrumental to the success of democratisation, governance and

    administrative reform is the building of civil institutions: viable political

    parties which openly function and contest elections as well as a free and

    dynamic press which would curb clientelism and corruption, thus making

    both the private sector and government accountable for their conduct. By

    exposing the misdeeds and mistakes, a free press would not only induce a

    new and creative proposals and policy options. Another key of the success

    of democratisation is the ability of both government and opposition to build

    bridges of compromise and mutual political accommodation.

    Third, democratisation, governance and administrative reform are

    concerned with administrative improvement, effectiveness, efficiency and

    rationality. In this connection, the concepts extol the virtues in revamping

    the performance and strengthening the civil service and local government

    units as well as improving the performance of state-owned enterprises

    through corporate plans, performance contracts, privatisation and

    recapitulisation. Since democratisation, governance and administrative

    reform seek to challenge social mores and long-standing policies,

    procedures, attitudinal and behavioural patterns, there is always

    considerable resistance and foot-dragging in any attempt to implement

    them.

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    15/22

    V CONCLUSION: IMPLICATIONS FOR PUBLIC ADMINISTRATION

    IN AFRICA

    One of the distinct political trends or phenomena, which has characterised

    world politics over the past decade, has been the ascendance of

    democratisation. The process of democratisation fosters and promotes an

    environment which not only encourages but also sustains the rule of law,

    human rights, popular participation, public accountability, transparency in

    government all leading to wealth creation. Democratisation therefore

    requires not only institutional pluralism, but also independent institutions,

    such as an independent judiciary, an impartial civil service, an effective

    parliament and a strong and autonomous local government structure.

    To achieve this, there is the urgent need to reorganise and restructure

    public administration. First, the civil service and local government units

    have to be delinked from the government of the day. Secondly, measures

    have to be undertaken to strengthen democratic control over public

    administration and increase its accountability to democratically elected

    bodies. Administrative reform is therefore undoubtedly and inseparable part

    of the democratisation and governance processes.

    Second, democratisation, governance and administrative reform will be

    meaningless if the government of the day fails to realise that family and

    ethnic ties that strengthen communal actions have no place in central

    government agencies where staff must be selected on merit, and public

    and private monies must not be confused (Wold Bank, 1989: 60). Efforts

    must be made to develop a cadre of public officials committed to an ethic of

    public service as well as more efficient and capable government

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    16/22

    bureaucracy (Jeffries, 1993). Corruption, rent-seeking, prebendalisation or

    pressures for wasteful government expenditure, nepotism, favouritism,

    patronage and clientelism must be reduced or controlled. The supposedly

    democratic character of Fourth Republic must be insulated from the

    bonanza of embezzlement and irresponsible expenditure.

    Third, democratisation, governance and administrative reform depend on

    building administrative capacity at all levels both by involving a wider

    ranger of organisations and by decentralizing authority and responsibility.

    Esman and Montgomery (1980) have pointed out that human resource

    development programmes requires a variety of organisational

    arrangements for eliciting the participation of those that are to be affected

    by the projects, and for assuring that resources reach the intended groups.

    In addition to using centrally financed and managed bureaucracies,

    programmes should be administered through modified bureaucracies that

    can be realised from conventional central controls to extend their reach in

    unconventional ways. Local authorities often have linkages of interaction

    with local groups that central bureaucracies do not know about and cannot

    reach. Market mechanisms may be used effectively to deliver services with

    only modest government intervention.

    Many voluntary organisations have ties and channels of distribution to

    groups that are frequently identified as beneficiaries of social and economic

    development projects, and through which experimental, pilot, and

    demonstration projects can be carried out. It is therefore necessary to build

    the administrative capacity of, and involve in planning and administration,

    what Esman and Montgomery (1980) call organised special publics, for

    example, interest groups such as credit unions, womens clubs, labour

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    17/22

    unions, co-operatives and the like. Thus, constituencies are created that

    will support projects for their members and act as channels of interaction

    between beneficiaries and the agencies sponsoring development projects.

    Once mobilised, these organisations can also begin to generate their own

    projects, thereby supplementing and extending the impact of government-

    sponsored ones. Because complex and uncertain projects cannot be

    controlled entirely from the centre, administrative capacity must be

    strengthened through decentralisation. Much more attention should be

    given to alternative means of decentralizing authority, responsibility, and

    resources through field administration, creation of local administrative units,

    delegation of functions of regional, special-purpose, or functional

    authorities, and devolution of functions to local government units

    (Rondinelli, 1982).

    Fourth, the success of democratisation, governance and administrative

    reform depends on politicians and administrators attitudes toward error.

    Under conditions of uncertainty, errors and mistakes are not only likely,

    they are to be expected. The concept of development administrative reform

    be designed in such a way that errors and mistakes can be uncovered as

    they proceed; they can then be redesigned and revised incrementally.

    Learning by doing can become an acceptable managerial approach only

    when it is explicitly recognised that democratisation, governance and

    administrative reform are basically experiments. Incentives and rewards

    must be provided to encourage innovation, experimentation and creativity.

    Only uncorrected errors should be considered evidence of poor

    management. Consequently, politicians and administrators must

    continuously monitor and evaluate the processes of democratisation,

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    18/22

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    19/22

    national interest. This is best explained: either by revolution, conquest or

    coup by modernising elites (e.g. Thailand from 1923, China from 1949,

    Korea from 1960, Taiwan from 1949, Indonesia from 1966), or by an

    electoral process that has nonetheless consistently yielded one dominant

    party of government (as in Botswana, Malaysia and Singapore).

    Third, whether democratic or not, a developmental state has all been de

    facto or de jure one-party state for much of the past thirty years, although in

    general the democratic group (Botswana, Singapore and Malaysia) have

    had better human rights rating than the non-democratic group has been

    ruled by military-backed authoritarian regimes (Thailand has had short

    democratic interludes), the democratic states have been ruled either by a

    single party (the BDP in Botswana and the PAP in Singapore) or in

    Malaysia, by a coalition in which a single party (UMNO) has dominated.

    The effect has been to concentrate very considerable and unchallenged

    political power at the top in these states, thus usually enhancing political

    stability and continuity in policy (Leftwch, 1993; Leftwich 1994).

    Finally, elite determination and the relative autonomy of the state has

    helped to shape very powerful, highly competent and insulated economic

    bureaucracies with authority in directing and managing economic and

    social development. Examples of these Economic Planning Board of

    Korea. What differentiates these economic institutions in developmental

    states is their real power, authority, technical competence and insulation in

    shaping development policy. Their existence, form and function should be

    understood as a consequence of the politically-driven urgency for

    development and the politics of a strong state (Leftwich, 1994 : 379). It is

    important for us to note that the concepts of democratisation, good

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    20/22

    governance and administrative reform run counter to the idea of a

    developmental state. While the former concepts eulogise the minimal state,

    a Weberian-type bureaucracy, rigorous respect for human rights, a rich and

    diverse civil society, political pluralism and a sharp separation of economic

    and political life, the latter, whether democratic or not, espouses a strong

    and determined state which protects powerful and competent bureaucracy

    that largely shapes and directs development policy, a dubious (and

    sometimes appalling) civil and human rights, the suppression or control of

    civil society and a fusion at least at the top of the political direction of

    economic power.

    As an agenda for future research, it is pertinent for one to know whether

    democratisation, governance and administrative reform have promoted

    accountability, popular participation, transparency, legitimacy and the

    empowerment of civil society and the subsequent reduction of the power of

    the state as well as the feasibility of the idea of a developmental state in

    Africa.

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    21/22

    REFERENCES

    Caiden, G. (1969), Administrative Reform, Chicago, Aldine

    Caiden, G. (1973), Development, Administrative Capacity andAdministrative Reforms, International Review of Administrative Sciences,Vol. 38 (4) : 327-344

    Caiden, G. (1978), The vitality of Administrative Reform, InternationalReview of Administrative Sciences, Vol. XLIX: 106-120.

    Charlton, R. (1991), Bureaucrats and Politicians in Botswanas PolicyMaking Process: A Reinterpretation, Journal of Commonwealth and

    Comparative Politics, Vol. XXIX (3): 265-282.

    Dror, Y. (1976), Strategies for Administrative Reform, in A.F. Leemans(ed). The Management of Change in Government, The Hague, Nijhoff.

    Esman, M.J & Montgomery, J.D. (1980), The Administration of HumanDevelopment, in Peter Knight (ed), Implementing Programmes of HumanDevelopment, World Bank Working Paper, n403, Washington, D.C, WorldBank: 183-224.

    Healy, J. & M. Robinson (1992), Democracy, Governance and EconomicDevelopment: Sub-Saharan Africa in Comparative Perspective, London:ODI.

    Jefries, R. (1993), The State, Structural Adjustment and GoodGovernment in Africa, Journal of Commonwealth and ComparativePolitics, Vol. 3 (1) March: 20-35.

    Leamans, A.F. (1976). The Management of Change in Government. The

    Hague, Nijhoff.

    Leftwich, A. (1993) Governance, Democracy and Development in the ThirdWorld, Third world Quarterly, Vol. 14 (3): 605-624.

    Leftwich, A. (1994), Governance, the State and the Politics ofDevelopment, Development and Change, Vol. 25 (2): 363-386.

  • 7/30/2019 Un Pan 025713

    22/22

    Lemarchand, R. (1992) African Transitions to Democracy: an Interim (andmost Pessimistic) Assessment, Africa Insight, Vol. 23 (3): 178-185.

    Montgomery, J.D. (1967), Sources of Bureaucratic Reform: Problems ofPower, Purpose and Politics, Bloomington, Indiana, Comparative

    Administrative Group Occasional Paper.

    Qadir, S. et al. (1993), Sustainable Democracy: Formalism orSustenance, Third World Quaterly, Vol. 14 (3): 412-420.

    Rijnierse, Elly (1993), Democratisation in Sub-Saharan Africa: LiteratureOverview, Third World Quaterly, Vol. 14 (3): 647-664.

    Rondinelli, D.A. (1982), The dilemma of Development Administration:

    Complexity and Uncertainty in Control-Oriented Bureaucracies, WorldPolitics, Vol. 5 (1): 43-72.

    United Nations, (1973). Interregional Seminar on Major AdministrativeReforms in Developing Countries, 2 Vols. ST/TAO/M/62, New York, UN.Wade, R. (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role ofGovernment in East Asian Industrialisation, Princeton, NJ: PrincetonUniversity Press.

    Williams, D. & Tom Young (1994), Governance, the World Bank andLiberal Theory, Political Studies, Vol. XXIX (3): 84-100.

    World Bank, (1989) Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to SustainableGrowth Washington, DC, and World Bank.

    World Bank, (1992), Governance and Development, Washington, DC;World Bank.