wp 2010 00 monetary policy risk taking

Upload: bruegel

Post on 08-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    1/41

    MONETARY POLICY

    AND RISK TAKING

    IGNAZIO ANGELONI*, ESTER FAIA** ANDMARCO LO DUCA

    Highlights

    The financial and economic crisis has taught central banks

    a lesson. They were previously primarily concerned withmaintaining price stability, but the crisis has producedevidence to show that monetary policy can contribute to thedevelopment (or the mitigation) of systemic risk in the

    financial sector. Monetary policy therefore needs to takefinancial stability implications into account, and themacroeconomic implications of bank supervision andregulation must also be considered.

    It is therefore important to understand the linkages between

    financial risk, monetary policy and the business cycle. Thispaper considers the thinking to date on risk taking inmonetary policy, presents comparative evidence for the

    euro area and the United States, and interprets the evidenceusing a macro dynamic stochastic general equilibriummodel.

    This approach produces three preliminary conclusions:central banks' monetary policy approaches affect, with timelags, the propensity of financial markets and banks toassume risk; it is possible to take account of these effectsthrough macroeconomic models that embody optimising

    agents with limited information and include explicitlybanking and financial sectors; and there is some indicationthat the modelling done in the paper can be used as thebasis for predicting the relationship between monetarypolicy and the effect of risk on macroeconomic variables,though this area needs considerable further research.

    * Visiting Scholar at Bruegel and advisor to the ExecutiveBoard of the European Central Bank.

    ** Goethe University Frankfurt, Kiel IfW and CEPREMAP. European Central Bank.

    BRUEGELW

    ORKINGPAPER2010/00

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    2/41

    Monetary Policy and Risk Taking

    Ignazio AngeloniEuropean Central Bank and BRUEGEL

    Ester FaiaGoethe University Frankfurt, Kiel IfW and CEPREMAP

    Marco Lo DucaEuropean Central Bank

    February 15, 2010

    Abstract

    We combine data evidence and a new DSGE model with banks to examine the links betweenmonetary policy, financial risk and the business cycle. The model includes banks (modelled asin Diamond and Rajan, JF 2000 and JPE 2001) and a financial accelerator (Bernanke et al.,1999 Handbook). A monetary expansion increases the propensity of banks to assume risks. Inturn, financial risks affect economic activity and prices. This "risk-taking" channel of monetarytransmission, absent in pure financial accelerator models, operates via the leverage decisions ofbanks. The model results match certain features of the data, as emerged in recent panel datastudies and in our own time series estimates for the US and the euro area.

    Keywords: monetary policy, bank behavior, leverage, financial accelerator.

    The authors are the sole responsible for the views expressed in this paper.

    1

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    3/41

    1 Introduction

    Central banking can be unpredictable at times. Think of what happened recently. Until 2007,

    central banks were operating within a well established paradigm, composed of three fundamental

    elements. The first call it single focus stipulated that in conducting monetary policy central

    banks should aim at maintaining price stability, i.e. a low and stable rate of change in the price of

    a basket of consumer goods and services. The specific time horizon for achieving this objective was

    disputed, but it is safe to say that most believed it should be rather short; the prevailing practice,

    inflation targeting, prescribed that central banks should steer their own inflation forecasts, which (as

    for all economic variables, for that matter) are notoriously unreliable at long horizons. The second

    tenet was that central banks should be independent, i.e. not influenced in their policy decisions

    by other actors, whether governments, businesses, trade unions, or other. The last element was

    a sort of assignment principle: central banks should not be "distracted" by concerns for other

    policy domains, nor should other policy actors share responsibility for price stability. For two

    reasons: first because multiple or shared objectives give rise to confusion on where responsibilities

    really belong; second, because potential failures in attaining other goals may destroy the credibility

    of central banks in achieving their primary objective, price stability. This argument was used in

    several contexts, but perhaps most forcefully to suggest that central banks should not be made

    responsible for banking and financial supervision 1. In the years of the "great moderation" the

    three legs of this paradigmatical tripod seemed so stable and solid that monetary policy was often

    referred to as a "science" (for example Giavazzi and Mishkin, [27]).

    In just two years, the financial crisis has inferted a powerful blow to many of these earlier

    certainties. Revisited in light of the turmoil, the experience of the previous decade suggests that

    the transmission of monetary policy may be more complex than was earlier assumed. Its effects may

    extend much beyond inflation and aggregate demand at short-medium horizons, to encompass the

    risk-taking propensity of economic agents, with second-round effects at much longer and unknown

    lags. Naturally, the existence of a "risk-taking channel" channel of monetary policy for which

    evidence has recently been provided, surveyed in this paper would put the single focus tenet into

    question. But also the assignment argument would somehow be affected; if monetary policy can

    1 See the classic curvey of Goodhart and Schoenmaker [29].

    2

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    4/41

    contribute to the formation (or the mitigation) of systemic risks in the financial sector, and if the

    latter in turn feed back on macroeconomic performance with unknown lags, it is hard to escape

    the conclusion that monetary policy needs to keep financial stability implications into account, and

    that the macroeconomic implications of bank supervision and regulation need to be considered as

    well. Completing the triangle, though nobody has seriously questioned the merits of central banks

    independence yet, recent vibrations in certain political quarters the US Congress, for example

    reveal a temptation to attach to the assignment of new responsibilities to central banks in the area

    offinancial stability a tighter scrutiny over their decisions2.

    In this complex picture, a key priority is to understand the linkages between financial risk,

    monetary policy and the business cycle. Our plan in this paper is the following. First, we briefly

    review the recent arguments and evidence on the risk taking channel of monetary policy. Second, we

    present some comparative time series evidence on this channel in the US and the euro area. Third,

    we introduce a new macro-DSGE model with banks to interpret this evidence. The model combines

    a banking sector based on the theory of Diamond and Rajan (see Angeloni and Faia [6]) with a

    standard financial accelerator (Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist [9]). In the model, firms use both

    internal funds and external finance (bank loans and corporate bonds) to finance their investment.

    Thisfl

    exible structure allows to examine the impact of monetary policy and other shocks on thelending and the funding behavior of banks, hence explicitly modelling the leverage of banks and

    firms. Our empirical results support the idea, corroborated also by other recent empirical evidence,

    that monetary policy influences risk-taking in the financial sector, and that financial risk in turn

    significantly influences output and price dynamics at longer lags. The model results, presented in

    comparison with the two simpler benchmarks (the model by Angeloni and Faia [6] and the classic

    financial accelerator model) broadly confirm certain salient features of the data.

    The paper is organised as follows. In section 2 we start by describing some recently published

    empirical evidence, based mainly on micro-panel data. In section 3 we present our new time-series

    evidence on the transmission of monetary policy on financial risk in the US and the euro area. In

    section 4 we present our macro model. In section 5 we use the model to describe the impact of

    a few selected shocks, including specifically the effects of monetary policy on risk and the effect

    2 Kashyap and Mishkin [31].

    3

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    5/41

    of risk on the rest of the economy. In doing so, we compare its properties of the model with two

    simpler alternative benchmarks: the model in Angeloni and Faia [6], based on the Diamond-Rajan

    theory, and the classic financial accelerator of Bernanke et al. Finally, section 6 concludes.

    2 Survey of recent empirical evidence

    The surge of interest for the implications of monetary policy on financial risks after the 2007-2009

    crisis contrasts sharply with the virtual absence of any reference to risk in the earlier literature

    on the monetary policy transmission mechanism. The classic 1995 survey by Mishkin, Taylor

    and others in the Journal of Economic Perspectives [33] does not mention risk except as a factor

    capable of reinforcing the strength of the financial accelerator. In the multi-country empirical

    study of monetary transmission in the euro area conducted by Eurosystem central banks, dated

    2003 (Angeloni, Kashyap and Mojon [7]), extensive use is made of indicators of bank risk in the

    econometric estimates of the lending channel, but only to quantify certain features of the banking

    sector that may affect the strength of the transmission, not because monetary policy may itself

    influence those characteristics or for their financial stability implications.

    In a different context, however, other papers have highlighted the potential importance of the

    link between monetary policy and financial risks well before the onset of the financial crisis. In 2002

    Borio and Lowe [17], described how asset market bubbles, leading to financial risk and instability,

    can develop out of a mix of benign macroeconomic conditions including high growth, low inflation,

    low interest rates and accommodative monetary policy. Their seminal contribution was followed

    by a host of publications by the Bank for International Settlements calling for the adoption of a

    "macroprudential approach" to financial stability including, notably, a response of monetary policy

    to asset prices. Earlier on, Allen and Gale [3] had provided a theoretical underpinning for these

    ideas by showing how leveraged positions in asset markets create moral hazard: leveraged investorscan back-stop losses by defaulting, and this makes asset prices deviate from fundamentals. The

    link with monetary policy, clarified later in Allen and Gale [4], consists is in the fact that credit

    developments in the economy are (at least partly) under the control of monetary policy.

    In 2005, Rajan [35] analysed how the incentives structures in the financial system may induce

    managers of banks and insurance companies to assume more risk under persistently low interest

    4

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    6/41

    rates. In a low interest rate environment, portfolio managers compensated on the basis of nominal

    market returns have an incentive to search for higher yields by taking on more risk. Risk built

    up under monetary accommoation turns into instability when monetary tightness returns, in the

    form of confidence crises and "sudden stops" of credit. Two implications for central banks: first,

    when a high risk level is already entrenched in the financial sector, abrupt policy tightening should

    be avoided; second, and more important, monetary policy should preemptively avoid prolonged

    periods of excessively low interest rates.

    To help the empirical analysis, and also because their policy implications differ, its useful to

    distinguish between two different channels through which the risk-taking mechanism can operate.

    The first is via changes in the degree of riskiness of the intermediarys asset side. In presence

    of low and persistent interest rates levels, asset managers of banks and other investment pools

    may have the incentive to shift the composition of their investments towards a riskier mix, for the

    reasons explained by Rajan. A second way in which more risk can be acquired is via the degree of

    leverage and the maturity composition of the balance sheet (or off-balance sheet structures implicitly

    guaranteed by the mother institution). In other words, a riskier balance sheet configuration can

    be realised, even if the asset mix remains the same, by borrowing in money markets. Risk-taking

    is stronger, other things equal, the shorter is the maturity of borrowing. This "leverage channel"operates specifically when short term rates are low and the yield curve upward sloping, an effect

    emphasised by Adrian and Shin [1]. While the two channels (asset mix vs. leverage-maturity

    changes) are conceptually distinct, it may be difficult to distinguish them since they tend to move

    together. All statistical and anecdotal information we have suggests that financial institutions on

    both sides of the Atlantic (banks, conduits and SIVs, investment funds, insurance companies, etc.)

    became riskier, in the pre-crisis years, due to a mix of riskier investments and more fragile balance

    sheet structures.

    The empirical evidence on these transmission mechanisms is limited. Two strands can be

    distinguished. A first one tries to identify effective leading indicators of financial crises. It has

    been noted that, in a variety of different national contexts and historical periods, financial crises

    tend to be preceded by a recurrent set or economic developments (Reinhardt and Rogoff, [37]). In

    particular, using time series using data for 18 OECD countries between 1970 and 2007, Alessi and

    5

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    7/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    8/41

    determines less strict credit "standards" by banks may or may not have implications for risk.

    Optimizing banks receiving more liquidity from the central bank and facing lower opportunity

    costs will naturally move down the expected loan return schedule, in fact typically lowering their

    lending rates. Though they probably interpret it as softening "credit standards", this does not

    necessarily increase lending risk. Even if some more risky borrowers happen to be financed, this

    may still be efficient and remain within acceptable safety bounds. So, a positive answer to the

    question above does not necessarily imply that a monetary expansion has an undesirable impact on

    bank risk. Conversely, even if the answer is in the negative, this does not mean that bank risk may

    not be increasing, perhaps exessively, in other ways. Asset quality is only one of the ways financial

    intermediaries use to take on more risk; leverage and maturity mismatch are other, probably more

    important channels.

    Another recent paper (Altunbas et al. [5]) uses a more comprehensive sample and a different

    measure of bank risk. They consider over 600 listed European banks, in 16 countries, for which

    Moodys KMV has computed expected default frequencies (EDF). EDFs are a widely used measure

    of bank risk, shown to have predictive power in many cases. EDFs are obtained translating, with a

    model, several market and balance sheet indicators into a single measure, a time-varying probability

    of default at a specifi

    c time horizon. The authors make this the dependent variable in a panelregression, that includes a variety of explanatory factors macroeconomic variables, market data,

    other bank characteristics as well as monetary policy. The results suggest that an increase of

    short term rates decreases bank risk on impact but increases it over time. This is interpreted as

    the combination of two effects: in the short run, an increase in rates lowers the risk of outstanding

    loans; over time, the higher level of rates induces hazardous lending behavior, leading to more risk.

    A similar conclusion is reached by Jimenez et al. [30] in their analysis of a large sample of Spanish

    banks, using more detailed credit register data.

    The estimates of Altunbas et al. [5] have the advantage of having direct implications for

    bank risk, but, given the very general nature of the risk measure employed, they do not allow to

    distinbguish among different transmission channels. To do this, we now turn to our time series

    evidence.

    7

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    9/41

    3 Some new time series evidence

    Table 1 reports the results of Granger causality tests to investigate the relationship between mon-

    etary policy (measured as de-trended nominal policy rate) and different indicators capturing bank

    leverage and balance sheet risk. The column Equation specifies the dependent variable, column

    Excluded shows the variable whose exclusion is being tested; the p-value of the test is reported

    in the last column. Our data definitions are given in the Appendix. In the US (Panel A), we find

    strong evidence of causality from monetary policy to the different measures of leverage and balance

    sheet risk, while causality in the other direction is not detected. For the euro area, causality from

    monetary policy to leverage and balance sheet risk is also detected, but the evidence is weaker than

    for the US. The results for the euro area show that causality runs also in the other direction, i.e.

    from leverage and risk to monetary policy.

    We then extend the analysis and we estimate VAR models where we also incorporate macro

    variables. We adopt the approach of Bloom[13], [14] and extend it in two directions: first, to

    examine the effect of monetary policy on financial risk alongside with the effect of risk on the

    business cycle; second, to consider both the euro area and the US.

    To help identify the different transmission channels, we consider three indicators of risk in our

    baseline model. The first (henceforth RISK1) is a stock market volatility index, constructed as a

    binary variable changing value when the stock market index change is beyond a given threshold

    (see Appendix for the description of the variables). This is the variable preferred by Bloom [13]

    for uncertainty/corporate risk; he also shows that it is highly correlated with several other proxies

    of the variability or dispersion of corporate returns. Our other two variables are based on bank

    balance sheets. RISK2 is the de-trended ratio of consumer credit and household mortgages to

    total bank assets. We interpret this as a measure of the (change of) bank assets specific riskiness,

    based on the fact that personal loans were the most risky component of the bank loan portfolios,

    particularly in the years preceding the latest financial crisis.

    Finally, RISK3 is a measure of bank leverage, calculated as the 12 month difference of the ratio

    total bank assets to total deposits. We decided to use this measure instead of the more customary

    ratio of assets to capital for two reasons: first because data on capital are often not reliable and

    not easily comparable across countries; second, more importantly, because regular deposits have

    8

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    10/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    11/41

    Finally, chart 3 shows the effect of a monetary policy shock on the three measures of risk. A

    monetary policy restriction tends to have a negative effect on risk, but its strength, profile and

    significance depends on the risk measure used and differs in the US relative to the euro area. The

    reduction of leverage (RISK3) is significant only in the US. The effect on bank asset risk (RISK2) is

    significant, delayed and persistent in both areas. Finally, the effects on corporate risk / uncertainty

    are insignificant4.

    We finally did a series of robustness checks to assess the stability of our results. We changed the

    definition and the measurement of our variables measuring overall risk and uncertainty (RISK1),

    balance sheet risk (RISK2) and leverage (RISK3). The alternative variables used are those listed

    in the Appendix tables that do not enter in the baseline specification. For the US the results

    are stable, only the proxy for overall balance sheet uncertainty turns insignificant in a few of the

    specifications. The impact of monetary policy on leverage is very robust. For the euro area, the

    results are less stable and the impact on monetary policy on overall balance sheet risk vanishes in

    several specifications. Finally, we ran the estimates on quarterly data and used alternative proxies

    of uncertainty calculated by Bloom for the US. The effects on leverage and balance sheet risk in

    the US are robust.

    4 A macroeconomic model with banks

    The real sector of the model consists in a conventional DSGE model with nominal rigidities. The

    economy is populated by workers (that are also bank depositors and bank capitalists), entrepreneurs

    and bank managers. Entrepreneurs launch projects that require an initial investment, financed

    partly by bank loans and partly by internal funds (net worth of the entrepreneur). The bank

    macro variables to a shock to uncertainty is at best weakly significant. One reason for the lack of significance could bethat the series for the euro area are too short. We therefore exclude from the model the variables RISK2 and RISK3

    that are available only since the end of the 90s and we re-estimated the model with data since 1990 using only withthe macro variables and RISK1 (or the implied volatility). In this specification, RISK1 is still only weakly significantwhile when the implied volatility is used, it has a strong negative and significant initial impact on inflation, a slightand significant negative impact on industrial production and no impact on employment.

    4 The option implied volatility that we use as measure of overall uncertainty and corporate risk as suggested byBloom, can be decomposed into a component that reflects actual expected stock market volatility (uncertainty) and aresidual (the so-called variance premium) that reflects risk aversion and other non-linear pricing effects (see Bekaert,Hoerova and Scheicher [11]). In a related paper, Bekaert Hoerova and Lo Duca [10] investigate the impact of monetarypolicy on the two components of implied volatility using SVAR. They find that the monetary policy shock for theUS has a positive impact on risk aversion while it does not affect the component related to uncertainty

    10

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    12/41

    raises funds from depositors and bank capitalists. Bank capitalists claims the residual value after

    depositors are paid out. The bank capital structure is determined by the bank manager, that

    acts on behalf of depositors and capitalists by maximizing their overall return. The bank lends to

    the entrepreneur the funds needed, in addition to internal funds, to finance capital investment. If

    the return on the investment project (a stochastic variable) is insufficient to reimburse the bank

    loan, inclusive of its contractual return, the firm fails and the project is appropriated by the bank.

    Likewise, if the return to the bank is insufficient to pay out depositors, there is a run on the bank, in

    which case the bank capital holders get zero while depositors get the market value of the liquidated

    loan.

    4.1 Households

    There is a continuum of identical households who consume, save and work. Households include real

    sector "workers" and bankers. Following Gertler and Karadi [25] we assume that in every period a

    fraction of household members are bankers and a fraction (1 ) workers. Bankers have a finite

    tenure in their job; with probability they remain bankers every period, otherwise they become

    workers. A corresponding fraction of workers become bankers every period, so that the share of

    bankers remains constant over time. This finite survival scheme is needed to avoid that bankers

    accumulate enough wealth to ease up the liquidity constraint; we will return on this point later.

    Workers earn wages and return them to the household; similarly bankers earn a fee from their

    services, that is returned to the household. Consumption and investment decisions are made by

    the household, pooling all available resources.

    Households maximize the following discounted sum of utilities:

    0

    X=0

    ( ) (1)

    where denotes aggregate consumption and denotes labour hours. The households receive

    at the beginning of time a real labour income As households can work both in the industrial

    and in the banking sector, we consider labour income as inclusive of the fees workers receive as

    managers of the banks. Those fees are determined in the next section.

    Households save and invest in bank deposits and bank capital. Deposits, pay a gross

    11

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    13/41

    nominal return one period later. Alternatively, and without qualitative change in the analysis,

    we could assume the existence of another asset, say government bonds; in this case deposits can be

    assumed to be held for their transaction or liquidity services, that justify a wedge between the bond

    rate and the deposit rate. Finally, households are the owners of both the monopolistic competitive

    sector and the banking sector. Because of this they are entitled to receive from the monopolistic

    sector nominal profits for an amount, , and from any banker who ceases activity nominal profits

    of an amount, . The budget constraint reads as follows:

    + + +1 + + + (2)

    Note that the return from, and the investment in, bank capital do not appear in equation

    2. The reason is that we have assumed, as explained later, that all returns on bank capital are

    reinvested every period.

    Households choose the set of processes { }=0 and assets {+1 +1}

    =0 taking as given

    the set of processes { }

    =0 and the initial wealth 0 0 so as to maximize 1 subject to 2.

    The following optimality conditions hold:

    = (3)

    = {+1} (4)

    Equation 3 gives the optimal choice for labour supply. Note that, since labor income includes

    the bankers fee, the supply of labor determined in 3 depends also on this fee5. Equation 4 gives

    the Euler condition with respect to deposits and government bonds. Optimality requires that the

    first order conditions and No-Ponzi game conditions are simultaneously satisfied.

    5 In principle this fee is endogenous and depends (as will be seen later in the paper) on the bank capital structure.In practice, given the small ratio of bankers relative to workers, this component is negligible and we neglect itsendogeneity for simplicity.

    12

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    14/41

    4.2 Banks

    Our bankfi

    nances itself through uninsured deposits6

    and bank capital, and uses funds to lend torisky entrepreneurs. Lending and fund-raising are administered by separate compartments of the

    bank, a credit department and a funding department, linked together by an internal contract. The

    lending department receives funds from the funding department and uses them to enter into credit

    contracts with entrepreneurs.

    4.2.1 Lending

    The credit side is modelled as a standard financial accelerator (Bernanke et al. [9]).

    In synthesis (for a complete exposition of the model, see Faia and Monacelli [24]), the invest-

    ment projects financed by the bank are characterized by an expected return equal to +1+1,

    where +1, and +1 are respectively the nominal return on capital, the price of capital and

    real capital (individual subscripts are omitted for brevity). Project outcomes are subject to idio-

    syncratic uncertainty, taking the form of a multiplicative random shock applied to productivity.

    The shock is assumed to have a uniform density function () with mean equal to one and is

    defined between zero and two; hence (1 1 + ); () = 12 ; () = 1. Therefore, the

    monetary return of an investment project financed at is given by +1+1+1.

    The contract between the firm and the lending department stipulates ex-ante a fixed gross

    return for the bank +1and a financing amount +1 = +1 +1, where +1 is

    the entrepreneurs net worth. +1 includes a fixed proportion 1 of own bank funds, +1,

    while the rest is raised by issuing corporate bonds. Ex-post there are two cases. If the firm doesnt

    default, it pays back the debt, inclusive of the contractual return +1, and the entrepreneur retains

    any surplus. If not, the firm goes bankrupt and the lending department liquidates the project. In

    this case, the lender has to bear a monitoring cost equal to a fraction of the project value.

    Formally, the contract defines a default threshold such that bankrupcy of the firm occurs only if

    , where is defined by

    6 Our arguments apply equally to other leveraged entities, issuing uninsured short-maturity debt such as, forexample, asset-backed commercial paper.

    13

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    15/41

    +1 +1+1

    Y

    +1+1

    (5)

    where Y+1 is the unitary monetary return from holding a unit of capital.

    For each euro lent, the expected return for the lender is

    (+1) 1

    2

    Z+10

    +1 + +1

    Z2+1

    !

    and the expected return to the firm is the complement, 1 (+1). The cost of monitoring is

    (+1)

    2Z+10

    +1

    and the net unit return accruing to the lender is (+1)(+1).

    The firms investment is financed by a mix of internal and external funds. The participation

    constraint for the lender thus takes the form:

    (1 ) +

    (+1 +1) Y

    +1+1((+1)(+1) (6)

    The contract betwen the lender and the firm specifies a pair {+1,+1} which solves the

    maximum problem:

    (1 (+1))Y+1+1 (7)

    subject to 6. The first order conditions are

    0(+1) = (

    0( (+1)) (8)

    +1(1 ) +

    (1 (+1

    )) +

    ((

    +1

    ) (

    +1

    )) =

    (9)

    where is the Lagrange multiplier. For 0 6 must hold with equality.

    The external finance premium can be written as

    +1

    (1 ) + = (+1)

    1

    +1

    +1

    (10)

    14

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    16/41

    where (+1) = [(+1)(+1)]1. Note that the premium increases with the leverage

    ratio +1+1 .

    The aggregate net worth for the firm, in expected terms, accumulates over time according to

    +1 = (1 (+1))Y (11)

    where is a survival probability for the firm. Rearranging and using 6 one can write this as

    +1 = 1

    (1 ) +

    +

    (1 ) (12)

    where =

    () 1

    1 is the expected monitoring cost per unit of loan.

    4.2.2 Funding

    The liability side of the bank is modeled as in Angeloni and Faia [6]. In summary (see [6] for

    details), banks receive finance from two classes of agents: depositors and capitalists. Bank loans in

    the balance sheet are equal to the sum of deposits () and bank capital, ():

    = + (13)

    The funding department determines the capital structure (shares of deposits and capital) on

    behalf of depositors and bank capitalists. Following Diamond and Rajan ([21], [22], we assume the

    banker maximizes the combined expected return of depositors and capitalists, in exchange for a

    fee.

    The timing is as follows. At time , the banker decides the optimal capital structure, expressed

    by the ratio of deposits to the total cost of the project, , collects the funds, and transfers the funds

    to the lending department. At time + 1, the projects outcome is revealed, the contractual return

    is transferred from the lending to the funding department, as discussed below, and payments to

    depositors and capitalists are made. A new round of projects starts.

    The credit and the funding departments are tied by a contract that stipulates that the former

    pays to the latter a return on the funds received , equal to its expected return on assets. More-

    over, we assume that the return on assets for the funding department is subject to an idiosynchratic

    shock with a uniform distribution defined in the space {; } (again, individual subscripts are

    15

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    17/41

    omitted for simplicity; the linearity of the problem allows easy aggregation). We can think of

    as a liquidity shock, due for example to an unexpected withdrawal of deposits. Each period the

    realized return + is split between the depositors, the bank capitalists and the funding de-

    partment itself, that earns a fee for its liability management service. If the cash flow accruing to

    the funding department is insufficient to reimburse the depositors (including the non-contingent

    return on deposits, , there is a run on the bank, which forces an early liquidation of the loan by

    the credit department.

    We assume the bank is a relationship lender: by lending, the credit department acquires a

    specialized non-sellable knowledge of the characteristics of the project that determines an advantage

    in extracting value from it before the project is concluded, relative to other agents. Let the ratio

    of the value for the outsider (liquidation value) to the value for the bank be 0 1. Even if

    the value is extracted by the bank, hence without loss of relationship knowledge, a bank run may

    entail a specific cost 1 0; when a run occurs, the liquidation value of the project extracted

    by the bank loses a constant fraction .

    Consider the payoffs to each of our players (the depositor; the bank capitalist; the bank as

    liability manager). There are three cases.

    Case A: Run for sure. The return is too low to pay depositors; + . Payoff

    s in caseof run are distributed as follows. Capitalists receive the leftover after depositors are served, so they

    get zero in this case. Depositors alone (without bank) would get only a fraction (1 )( + )

    of the projects outcome; the remainder (1)(1 )( + ) is split in half between depositors

    and the bank. Therefore, depositors get

    (1 + )(1 )( + )

    2(14)

    and the bank

    (1 )(1 )( + )

    2(15)

    Case B: Run only without the bank. The return is high enough to allow depositors to be served if

    the projects value is extracted by the bank, but not otherwise; i.e (+) (+).

    In this case, the capitalists alone cannot avoid the run, but with the bank they can. So depositors

    16

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    18/41

    are paid in full, , and the remainder is split in half between the banker and the capitalists,

    each getting+

    2 . Total payment to outsiders is++

    2 .

    Case C: No run for sure. The return is high enough to allow all depositors to be served, with

    or without the banks participation. This happens if ( + ). Depositors get .

    However, unlike in the previous case, now the capitalists have a higher bargaining power because

    could decide to liquidate the project alone and pay the depositors in full, getting (+);

    this is thus a lower threshold for them. The banker can extract ( + ), and again we

    assume that the capitalist and the bank split this extra return in half. Therefore, the bank gets:

    {[( + )] [( + )]}

    2

    =( )(1 + )

    2

    This is less than what the capitalist gets. Total payment to outsiders is:

    (1 + )( + )

    2

    The expected value of total payments to outsiders as follows:

    12

    Z

    (1 + )(1 )( + )2

    + 12

    Z

    ( + ) + 2

    + (16)

    +1

    2

    Z

    (1 + )( + )

    2

    The three terms express the payoffs to outsiders in the three cases described above, in order.

    The bankers problem is to maximise expected total payments to outsiders by choosing the suitable

    value of .

    It can be shown (see [6] for details) that the value of that maximises equation 16 is comprised

    in the interval +

    +

    . In this zone, the third integral in the equation vanishes and

    the expression reduces to

    1

    2

    Z

    (1 + )(1 )( + )

    2 +

    1

    2

    Z

    ( + ) + 2

    (17)

    17

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    19/41

    Differentiating and solving for yields the following equilibrium condition

    = 1

    + 2 + (1 + )

    (18)

    Since the second derivative is negative, this is the optimal value of .

    The optimal deposit ratio depends positively on , and , and negatively on . An

    increase of reduces deposits because it increases the probability of run. Moreover, an increase

    in raises the marginal return in the no-run case (the third effect just mentioned), while it does

    not affect the other two effects, hence it raises . An increase in reduces the cost in the run case

    (first effect), while not affecting the others, so it raises . The effect of is more tricky. At first

    sight it would seem that an increase in the dispersion of the project outcomes, moving the extreme

    values of the distribution both upwards and downwards, should be symmetric and have no effect.

    But this is not the case. When increases, the probability of each given project outcome 12 falls.

    Hence the expected loss stemming from the change in the relative probabilities (sum of the first

    two effects) falls, but the marginal gain in the no-run case (third term) does not, because the upper

    limit increases. The marginal effect is 2 , because depositors get the full return, but half is lost by

    the capitalist to the banker. Hence, the increase of has on a positive effect, as .

    The probability of a run occurring can be written as:

    =1

    2

    Z

    =1

    2

    1

    (19)

    we can interpret as a measure of bank riskiness. For plausible values of and , ranges

    between 0.3 and 1. See Angeloni and Faia [6] for details.

    Aggregate deposits are given by

    =

    +

    2 + (1 + )(20)

    and the banks optimal capital is:

    = (1 1

    +

    2 + (1 + )) (21)

    18

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    20/41

    The above expressions suggest that contractionary monetary policy, raising , increases the

    optimal amount of bank capital on impact. The cyclical behavior of the bank capital structure is

    more complex, depending on several counterbalancing factors. Equation 21 can be interpreted as

    a demand for bank capital given the volume of loans and the interest rate structure (, ).

    As to the supply, we assume that bank capital accumulates in the form of undistributed dividends.

    After remunerating depositors and paying the competitive fee to the banker, a return accrues to the

    bank capitalist as retained earning (including any reinvested dividends). Bank capital accumulates

    from retained earnings as follows:

    +1 = [ + +1+1+1] (22)

    where +1 is the unitary return to the capitalist. The parameter is a decay rate, inclusive

    of both the bank survival rate (Gertler and Karadi [25]) and bank capital depreciation. +1 can

    be derived from equation 17 as follows:

    +1 =1

    2

    Z+1+1+1

    (+1 + +1)+1+12

    +1 =(+1 + +1+1)

    2

    8(23)

    Note that this expression considers only the no-run state because if a run occurs the capitalist

    receives no return. The accumulation of bank capital obtained substituting 23 into 22:

    +1 = [ +(+1 + +1+1)

    2

    8+1+1] (24)

    4.3 Producers

    Each firm has monopolistic power in the production of its own variety and therefore has leverage

    in setting the price. In changing prices it faces a quadratic cost equal to 2 (()

    1() )2 where

    is the steady state inflation rate and where the parameter measures the degree of nominal price

    rigidity. The higher the more sluggish is the adjustment of nominal prices. In the particular case

    of = 0 prices are flexible. Each firm assembles labour (supplied by the workers) and (finished)

    entrepreneurial capital to operate a constant return to scale production function for the variety

    of the intermediate good:

    19

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    21/41

    () = (() ()) (25)

    Each monopolistic firm chooses a sequence {() () ()} taking nominal wage rates

    and the rental rate of capital as given, in order to maximize expected discounted nominal

    profits:

    0{X=0

    0[()() (() + ())

    2

    ()

    1()

    2]} (26)

    subject to the constraint () (), where 0 is the households stochastic discount

    factor.

    Lets denote by {}

    =0 the sequence of Lagrange multipliers on the above demand constraint,

    and by ()

    the relative price of variety The first order conditions of the above problem

    read:

    ()= (27)

    ()= (28)

    0 = ((1 ) +

    1

    1+ (29)

    +

    +1

    +1

    +1

    +12

    where is the marginal product of labour, the marginal product of capital and =

    1

    is the gross aggregate inflation rate (its steady state value, , is equal to 1). Notice that all

    firms employ an identical capital/labour ratio in equilibrium, so individual prices are all equal in

    equilibrium. The Lagrange multiplier plays the role of the real marginal cost of production.

    In a symmetric equilibrium = 1 This allows to rewrite equation 29 in the following form:

    ( ) = {+1(+1 )+1} + (30)

    +()

    (

    1

    )

    20

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    22/41

    The above equation is a non-linear forward looking New-Keynesian Phillips curve, in which

    deviations of the real marginal cost from its desired steady state value are the driving force of

    inflation.7

    4.3.1 Capital Producers

    A competitive sector of capital producers combine investment (expressed in the same composite as

    the final good, hence with price ) and existing capital stock to produce new capital goods. This

    activity entails physical adjustment costs. The corresponding CRS production function is ( )

    so that capital accumulation obeys:

    +1 = (1 ) + (

    ) (31)

    where () is increasing and convex.

    Define as the re-sell price of the capital good. Capital producers maximize profits (

    )

    implying the following first order condition:

    0(

    ) = (32)

    The gross (nominal) return from holding one unit of capital between and + 1 is composed of

    the rental rate plus the re-sell price of capital (net of depreciation and physical adjustment costs):

    + ((1 ) 0(

    )

    + (

    )) (33)

    The gross (real) return to entrepreneurs from holding a unit of capital between and + 1 is

    equalized in equilibrium to the gross (real) return that entrepreneurs return to banks for their loan

    services, +1:

    +1

    +1

    +1

    (34)

    7 Woodford [42].

    21

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    23/41

    4.4 Goods Market Clearing

    Equilibrium in thefi

    nal good market requires that the production of thefi

    nal good equals thesum of private consumption by households and entrepreneurs, investment, public spending, and

    the resource costs that originate from the adjustment of prices:

    = + + +

    2( )

    2 (35)

    In the above equation, is government consumption of the final good which evolves exogenously

    and is assumed to be financed by lump sum taxes.

    4.5 Monetary Policy

    We assume that monetary policy is conducted by means of an interest rate reaction function of this

    form:

    ln

    1 + 1 +

    = (1 )

    ln

    + ln

    + ln

    + ln

    (36)

    + ln1 + 1

    1 + All variables are deviations from the target or steady state (symbols without time subscript).

    Note that the reaction function includes two alternative terms that express leaning-against-the-wind

    behavior, respectively a reaction to asset prices () or to the deposit ratio (). Our approach

    will consist in finding policy specifications { } that maximize household welfare8

    We solve the model by computing a second order approximation of the policy functions around the

    non-stochastic steady state.

    4.6 Parameter values

    Household preferences and production. The time unit is the quarter. The utility function of house-

    holds is ( ) =1 11 + log(1) with = 2 as in most reasl business cycle literature.

    We set set equal to 3, chosen in such a way to generate a steady-state level of employment

    8 See ofr instance Kim and Kim 2003, Kollmann [?], [?] Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe [38], [39], [40], Faia and Monacelli[24], Faia [23].

    22

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    24/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    25/41

    deviation to the standard deviation of a uniform distribution. The result, 0.5, is our benchmark.

    To this we apply a shock as described in the next section.

    One way to interpret is to see it as the ratio of two present values of the project, the first at the

    interest rate applied to firms external finance, the second discounted at the bank internal finance

    rate (the money market rate). A benchmark estimate can be obtained by taking the historical ratio

    between the money market rate and the lending rate. In the US over the last 20 years, based on

    30-year mortgage loans, this ratio has been around 3 percent. This leads to a value of around

    0.6. In the empirical analyses we have chosen a steady state value of 0.5, to which we apply a shock

    as described in the next section. Finally we parametrize the survival rate of banks at 0.97.

    Shocks. Total factor productivity is assumed to evolve as:

    = 1 exp(

    ) (37)

    where the steady-state value is normalized to unity (which in turn implies = 1) and

    where is an i.i.d. shock with standard deviation In line with the real business cycle literature,

    we set = 095 and = 0008. Log-government consumption is assumed to evolve according to

    the following process:

    ln(

    ) = ln(

    1

    ) +

    where is the steady-state share of government consumption (set in such a way that

    = 025)

    and is an i.i.d. shock with standard deviation We follow the empirical evidence for the U.S.

    in Perotti [?] and set = 00074 and = 09

    We introduce a monetary policy shock as as an additive disturbance to the interest rate

    set through the monetary policy rule. The monetary policy shock is assumed to have zero or

    moderate persistence, depending on different cases examined. Following empirical evidence for US

    and Europe, the standard deviations of the shocks is set to 0006.

    5 The transmission of shocks in the model

    Charts 4 to 7 show the effects in the model of four types of shocks: a positive productivity shock;

    an expansionary fiscal shock; a restrictive monetary policy shock; and a risk shock. The first two

    24

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    26/41

    mainly serve the purpose of illustrating the properties of the model; the other two are of more

    direct relevance for our investigation.

    In each of the charts, the results from our model (AFBGG model), represented in green dashed

    lines, are compared with those of two other models: the one of Angeloni and Faia [6] (AF model;

    solid blue line) and the pure financial accelerator (BGG model; dash&dot red line).

    The productivity shock (chart 4) produces in all three models the usual pattern of declining

    inflation and rising output in the short run, rapidly returning to the steady state. Relative to

    the other models, AFBGG displays a stronger amplification of output on impact, followed by

    undershooting before returning to baseline. Similarly, AFBGG displays much more volatility of

    investment and capital in the short run. Employment displays a hump-shaped pattern, declining

    first and rising back. In contrast with the AF model (fourth row of plots) the deposit ratio declines

    on impact, and this determines a sharp decline in bank riskiness. This pattern reflects the decline

    in firms leverage and the associated decline in bank lending (fifth row of plots in the chart). Note

    that, in contrast to BGG, this shock produces a slight increase in the external finance premium.

    A persistent fiscal expansion (chart 5) increases output and inflation, as expected, in all models,

    but the size and timing of the effects are quite different. Again, AFBGG amplifies the effect on

    output and capital, as a consequence of the interaction between thefi

    nancial accelerator and thebehavior of banks. Bank riskiness rises as a result of the increase in the deposit ratio and the

    interest rate. The chain of effects under a fiscal shock tends to be opposite to that observed in the

    case of a productivity shock.

    Chart 6 shows the effect of a persistent monetary policy restriction. Inflation and output

    decline, as in the data, but the model response does not exhibit the usual hump-shape that observed

    in VAR model responses. Note also that the impact of the shock on banks is sharply different in

    the AFBGG model relative to the AF model. In the first, an increase in the deposit ratio and (after

    a lag) in firm leverage is accompanied by an increase in risk. On the contrary, in the AF model

    deposit decline relative to loans, hence reducing bank leverage. This generates a decrease in bank

    riskiness, that matches the results of our VAR estimates (see chart 3).

    Finally, chart 7 shows the results of an increase in market risk, modelled as a positive shock in

    the external finance premium accompanied by a simultaneous decline in the value of the parameter

    25

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    27/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    28/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    29/41

    [10] Bekaert, G., M. Hoerova and M. Lo Duca, 2009, "Risk, uncertainty and monetary policy",

    mimeo, ECB, Frankfurt.

    [11] Bekaert, G., M. Hoerova and Scheicher, 2009, "Uncertainty and Risk Attitude: Evidence from

    Equity Markets", ECB Working Paper No. 1037.

    [12] Bils M. and P. Klenow (2004), "Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices", Journal

    of Political Economy, October.

    [13] Bloom, Nicholas 2009, "The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks," Econometrica, May.

    [14] Bloom, Nicholas, Max Floteotto and Nir Jiaimovich, 2009. "Really Uncertain Business Cycles".Mimeo.

    [15] Blum, J. and M. Hellwig, 1995. "The Macroeconomic Implications of Capital Requirements

    Adequacy for Banks". European Economic Review, vol. 39.

    [16] Borio, Claudio and H. Zhu (2008), Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: a

    missing link in the transmission mechanism?, BIS Working Papers No. 268.

    [17] Borio, Claudio and Philip Lowe (2002), "Asset prices, financial and monetary stability: ex-ploring the nexus", BIS Working Papers No 114.b

    [18] Brunnermeier, M., A, Crockett, C. Goodhart, M. Hellwig, A. Persaud and H. Shin, 2009, The

    Fundamental Principles of Financial Regulation", Geneva Report on the World Economy 11,

    CEPR and ICMB.

    [19] Carlstrom, C. and T. Fuerst (1997), Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations: A

    Computable General Equilibrium Analysis, American Economic Review, 87, 893-910.

    [20] Cecchetti, S.G., H. Genberg, J. Lipsky and S. Whadwani, 2000, Asset Prices and Central

    Bank Policy, Geneva Report on the World Economy 2, CEPR and ICMB.

    [21] Diamond, Douglas W. and Rajan, Raghuram G. 2000. "A Theory of Bank Capital", Journal

    of Finance, vol. LV. No. 6.

    28

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    30/41

    [22] Douglas W. Diamond & Raghuram G. Rajan, 2001. "Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation and

    Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking," Journal of Political Economy.

    [23] Faia, Ester, 2008 "Optimal Monetary Policy Rules with Labor Market Frictions", Journal of

    Economic Dynamics and Control.

    [24] Faia, Ester, Monacelli, Tommaso, 2007. "Optimal interest rate rules, asset prices, and credit

    frictions", Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control.

    [25] Gertler, Mark and Peter Karadi, 2009. "A model of Unconventional Monetary Policy". NYU.

    [26] Gertler, Mark and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, 2009, "Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy inBusiness Cycle Analysis", mimeo.

    [27] Giavazzi, F. and F.S. Mishkin (2006), An Evolution of Swedish Monetary Policy between

    1995 and 2005, Riksdagstryckeriet, Stockholm.

    [28] Goodhart, Charles and Boris Hofmann (2008), "House Prices, Money, Credit and the Macro-

    economy", ECB Working paper Series n. 802.

    [29] Goodhart, Charles and Dirk Schoenmaker (1995), "Should the Functions of Monetary Policyand Banking Supervision be Separated?, Oxford Economic Papers, 47, 539560

    [30] Jimnez, J., S. Ongena, J.-L. Peydr-Alcalde and J. Taurina (2007), Hazardous Times for

    Monetary Policy: What do Twenty-Three Million Bank Loans Say About the Effects of Mon-

    etary Policy on Credit Risk?, CEPR Discussion Paper 6514.

    [31] Kashyap, A. and F. Mishkin (2009), "The Fed is Already Transparent", the Wall Street

    Journal, 10 November.

    [32] Maddaloni A., and J.L. Peydr Alcalde, 2009, Bank risk-taking, Securitiza-

    tion and Monetary Policy; Evidence from the bank Lending Survey, ECB,

    mimeo. Downloadable at: http://reserved03.timeandmind.net/carefin.unibocconi.it/

    download/21_settembre_Intesa_Sanpaolo/peydro-maddaloni.pdf

    [33] Mishkin, Rick and John Taylor, 2005), "...... " Journal of Economic Perspectives

    29

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    31/41

    [34] Morris, S. and H.S. Shin, 2008, "Financial Regulation in a System Context." Brookings Papers

    of Economic Activity.

    [35] Rajan, R. (2005), Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier?, NBER Working

    Paper 11728.

    [36] Sbordone A. (2002), "Prices and Unit Labor Costs: A New Test of Price Stickiness", Journal

    of Monetary Economics Vol. 49 (2).

    [37] Reinhardt, Carmen and Ken Rogoff, 2009, "Is the 2007 U.S. sub-prime financial crisis so

    different? An international comparison", NBER Working Paper 13761.

    [38] Schmitt-Grohe S. and M. Uribe, 2003. "Optimal, Simple and Implementable Monetary and

    Fiscal Rules." Mimeo Duke University.

    [39] Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie and Uribe, Martin, 2004a. "Solving Dynamic General Equilibrium

    Models Using a Second-Order Approximation to the Policy Function" Journal of Economic

    Dynamics and Control 28, 645-858.

    [40] Schmitt-Grohe S. and M. Uribe, 2004b, "Optimal Operational Monetary Policy in Christiano-

    Eichenbaum-Evans Model of the U.S. Business Cycle." Mimeo Duke University.

    [41] Taylor, J.B. (2009), The Financial Crisis and the Policy Responses: An Empirical Analysis

    of What Went Wrong, NBER Working Paper Series No. 14631.

    [42] Woodford, Michael, 2003 Interest and Prices.

    30

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    32/41

    Table 1. Granger Causality Tests

    Panel A. United States

    Equation Excluded Lags p-Value

    monetary policy leverage I 25 0.321

    leverage I monetary policy 25 0.002 ***

    monetary policy leverage II 17 0.591

    leverage II monetary policy 17 0.058 *

    monetary policy balance sheet risk I 14 0.672

    balance sheet risk I monetary policy 14 0.133

    monetary policy balance sheet risk II 25 0.900

    balance sheet risk II monetary policy 25 0.005 ***

    monetary policy balance sheet risk III 14 0.540

    balance sheet risk III monetary policy 14 0.030 **

    monetary policy balance sheet risk IV 25 0.855

    balance sheet risk IV monetary policy 25 0.009 ***

    Panel B. Euro Area

    Equation Excluded Lags p-Value

    monetary policy leverage I 13 0.001 ***

    leverage I monetary policy 13 0.954

    monetary policy leverage II 5 0.002 ***

    leverage II monetary policy 5 0.016 **

    monetary policy balance sheet risk I 18 0.000 ***

    balance sheet risk I monetary policy 18 0.233

    monetary policy balance sheet risk II 19 0.000 ***

    balance sheet risk II monetary policy 19 0.000 ***

    monetary policy balance sheet risk III 3 0.090 *

    balance sheet risk III monetary policy 3 0.042 **

    monetary policy balance sheet risk IV 13 0.316

    balance sheet risk IV monetary policy 13 0.113

    Notes: The table reports the results of granger causality tests of bivariate VAR models, where theendogenous variables are monetary policy (de-trended effective federal fund rate) and different

    indicators capturing leverage and balance sheet risk of banks (see table X for the description of the

    variables). Column Equation specifies the VAR equation; column Excluded reports the variable

    excluded from the equation; column Lags specifies the number of lags used in the estimation of the

    VAR model, lags are selected by looking at Akaike information criterion. Column p-value specifiesthe p-value of the granger causality test, rejection at 1% (5%) confidence level is marked with *** (**).

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    33/41

    Chart 1: Impulse Responses to a monetary policy shock (macro variables)

    US inflation EA inflation

    -0.0040

    -0.0030

    -0.0020

    -0.0010

    0.0000

    0.0010

    0.0020

    0.0030

    0.0040

    0.0050

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    -0.0020

    -0.0015

    -0.0010

    -0.0005

    0.0000

    0.0005

    0.0010

    0.0015

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    US industrial production EA industrial production

    -0.0070

    -0.0060

    -0.0050

    -0.0040

    -0.0030

    -0.0020

    -0.0010

    0.0000

    0.0010

    0.0020

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    -0.0050

    -0.0040

    -0.0030

    -0.0020

    -0.0010

    0.0000

    0.0010

    0.0020

    0.0030

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    US employment EA unemployment

    -0.0040

    -0.0035

    -0.0030

    -0.0025

    -0.0020

    -0.0015

    -0.0010

    -0.0005

    0.0000

    0.0005

    0.0010

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    -0.0010

    -0.0008

    -0.0006

    -0.0004

    -0.0002

    0.0000

    0.0002

    0.0004

    0.0006

    0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32 36

    Notes: for the calculation of impulse responses we use the same estimation order of thevariables as in Bloom (2009), with the difference that we insert the bank balance sheet

    variables measuring risk and leverage between the macro and the financial block. Therefore,

    the variables in the estimation order are industrial production, employment, inflation, bank

    balance sheet risk, bank leverage, monetary policy rate, the stock market volatility indicator

    and the stock market index. As pointed out by Bloom, including the stock-market levels as thelast variable in the VAR ensures the impact of stock market levels is already controlled for

    when looking at the impact of volatility shocks. The ordering used here is based on the

    assumption that shocks instantaneously influence the stock market (levels and volatility), thenthe interest rate. Subsequently bank balance sheet variables adjusts, followed by macro

    adjustments (first the price index and then quantities). As it is not clear which variable amongleverage and balance sheet risk should be placed first, we estimate different VAR models

    inverting the order of these two variables. The results are not affected. For the US, the model

    is estimated with monthly data from January 1974 to June 2008. For the euro area the sample

    covers the period March 1991 to December 2008.

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    34/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    35/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    36/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    37/41

    0 5 10 15 200

    2

    4

    6

    8x 10

    -3 Inflation

    AF

    AFBGGBGG

    0 5 10 15 20-0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2Output

    0 5 10 15 200

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4Employment

    0 5 10 15 20-0.03

    -0.02

    -0.01

    0Capital

    0 5 10 15 20-0.1

    -0.05

    0

    0.05

    0.1Tobin Q

    0 5 10 15 200

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03Interest rate

    0 5 10 15 20-0.05

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15 Deposit ratio (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 20-0.2

    0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6Bank riskiness (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 200

    1

    2

    3

    4x 10

    -4External finance premium (specific BGG)

    0 5 10 15 20-0.05

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15Firm leverage ratio (specific BGG)

    CHART 5: EXPANSIONARY FISCAL SHOCK

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    38/41

    0 5 10 15 20-0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2Inflation

    AF

    AFBGGBGG

    0 5 10 15 20-4

    -2

    0

    2Output

    0 5 10 15 20-6

    -4

    -2

    0

    2Employment

    0 5 10 15 20-1

    -0.5

    0Capital

    0 5 10 15 20-1.5

    -1

    -0.5

    0

    0.5Tobin Q

    0 5 10 15 200

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8Interest rate

    0 5 10 15 20-1

    -0.5

    0

    0.5

    1 Deposit ratio (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 20-2

    -1

    0

    1

    2Bank riskiness (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 200

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015External finance premium (specific BGG)

    0 5 10 15 20-2

    -1

    0

    1Firm leverage ratio (specific BGG)

    CHART 6: RESTRICTIVE MONETARY POLICY SHOCK

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    39/41

    0 5 10 15 20-0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2Inflation

    AF

    AFBGG

    BGG

    0 5 10 15 20-10

    -5

    0

    5Output

    0 5 10 15 20-15

    -10

    -5

    0

    5Employment

    0 5 10 15 20-1.5

    -1

    -0.5

    0Capital

    0 5 10 15 20-3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1Tobin Q

    0 5 10 15 20-1

    -0.5

    0

    0.5Interest rate

    0 5 10 15 20-2

    0

    2

    4 Deposit ratio (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 20-10

    0

    10

    20Bank riskiness (specific AF)

    0 5 10 15 200

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015

    0.02External finance premium (specific BGG)

    0 5 10 15 20-4

    -2

    0

    2

    4Firm leverage ratio (specific BGG)

    CHART 7: POSITIVE RISK SHOCK

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    40/41

  • 8/6/2019 Wp 2010 00 Monetary Policy Risk Taking

    41/41

    APPENDIX Table A1: Variables Description - euro area

    Variable name DescriptionBaseline

    Model

    Stock marketDe-trended logarithm of the Eurostoxx index. Source:

    Authors calculation and DatastreamY

    Monetary policy rateDe-trended EONIA rate (de-trended German overnight

    rate before 1999). Source: Authors calculation and ECB.Y

    InflationAnnualised rate of change of the HCPI over the last 3

    months. Source: Authors calculation and ECB.Y

    Industrial production

    De-trended logarithm of the industrial production index

    for manufacturing. Source: Source: Authors calculationand OECD.

    Y

    Employment De-trended logarithm of total employment1

    . Source:Authors calculation and Eurostat.

    Y

    Uncertainty shock I

    (RISK1)

    This is the same variable used for the US, see the

    description of Uncertainty Shock I for the US.Y

    Balance sheet risk I

    (RISK2)

    De-trended ratio of consumer credit and mortgages over

    total assets. The series starts in 1999. Source: Authorscalculation and ECB.

    Y

    Leverage I

    (RISK3)

    12 month difference of the ratio total assets to total

    deposits. The series starts in 1997. Source: Authors

    calculation and ECB

    Y

    Uncertainty shock II Implied volatility of the stock market index. Source:Datastream

    N

    Balance sheet risk II

    12 month difference of the ratio of consumer credit and

    mortgages over total assets. Source: Authors calculation

    and ECB

    N

    Balance sheet risk III

    De-trended ratio of consumer credit and mortgages over

    total assets. The series start in 1991. Calculated byaggregating data for 6 euro area countries.

    2Source: ECB

    and authors calculations.

    N

    Balance sheet risk IV

    12 month difference of the ratio consumer credit and

    mortgages over total assets. The series start in 1991.

    Calculated by aggregating data for 6 euro area countries

    (see the description of Balance sheet risk III). Source:

    ECB and authors calculations

    N

    Leverage II De-trended ratio total assets to total deposits. Source:Authors calculation and ECB

    N

    1