chapter five

Post on 24-Feb-2016

27 Views

Category:

Documents

0 Downloads

Preview:

Click to see full reader

DESCRIPTION

Chapter Five. Choice. Economic Rationality. The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The available choices constitute the choice set. How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Chapter Five

Choice

Economic Rationality

The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it.

The available choices constitute the choice set.

How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2Utility

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility x2

x1

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

The most preferredof the affordablebundles.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

Utilityx1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

More preferredbundles

Rational Constrained Choice

Affordablebundles

x1

x2

More preferredbundles

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle.

Rational Constrained Choice

The most preferred affordable bundle is called the consumer’s ORDINARY DEMAND at the given prices and budget.

Ordinary demands will be denoted byx1*(p1,p2,m) and x2*(p1,p2,m).

Rational Constrained Choice

When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR.

If buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.

(x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.(a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget; p1x1* + p2x2* = m.

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior .(b) The slope of the indiff.curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint.

Rational Constrained Choice (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted;

p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) the slope of the budget constraint,

-p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Computing Ordinary Demands

How can this information be used to locate (x1*,x2*) for given p1, p2 and m?

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

Then

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

MU Ux

ax xa b1

1112

MU Ux

bx xa b2

21 2

1

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

axbx

pp

x bpap

x2

1

12

2121

*

** * . (A)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

(x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Substitute

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

p x p bpap

x m1 1 2121

* * .

Substitute

and get

This simplifies to ….

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x ama b p1

1

*( )

.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x bma b p2

2

*( )

.

Substituting for x1* in p x p x m1 1 2 2

* *

then gives

x ama b p1

1

*( )

.

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So we have discovered that the mostpreferred affordable bundle for a consumerwith Cobb-Douglas preferences

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

is( , )

( ),( )

.* * ( )x x ama b p

bma b p1 2

1 2

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x1

x2

x ama b p1

1

*( )

xbm

a b p

2

2

*

( )

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Rational Constrained Choice When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0

and (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget,and indifference curves have no ‘kinks’, the ordinary demands are obtained by solving:

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = y (b) the slopes of the budget constraint,

-p1/p2, and of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Rational Constrained Choice

But what if x1* = 0? Or if x2* = 0? If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the

ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x yp22

*

x1 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x yp11

*

x2 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 < p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the mostpreferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*)where

0,py)x,x(1

*2

*1

and

2

*2

*1 p

y,0)x,x(

if p1 < p2

if p1 > p2.

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 = p2.

yp1

yp2

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p1 = p2.

yp2

yp1

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2Better

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

Which is the most preferredaffordable bundle?

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Notice that the “tangency solution”is not the most preferred affordablebundle.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = 0

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = - ¥

MRS = 0

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = - ¥

MRS = 0

MRS is undefined

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Which is the mostpreferred affordable bundle?

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m(b) x2* = ax1*

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

21

*1 app

mx

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives .

appamx;

appmx

21

*2

21

*1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

A bundle of 1 commodity 1 unit anda commodity 2 units costs p1 + ap2;m/(p1 + ap2) such bundles are affordable.

.app

amx;app

mx21

*2

21

*1

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x mp ap11 2

*

xam

p ap

2

1 2

*

top related