dividend policy and the method of payment

Upload: lesleykong

Post on 06-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    1/46

    Dividend Policy and the Method of Paymentin Mergers and Acquisitions

    Jin Q Jeon*Dongguk Business School

    Dongguk University

    3-26 Pil-dong, Chung-gu

    Seoul 100-715, KOREA

    +822-2260-8884

    [email protected]

    James A. LigonDepartment of Economics, Finance & Legal Studies

    The University of Alabama

    P.O. Box 870224

    Tuscaloosa, AL 35487-0224

    205-348-6313

    [email protected]

    Charn SoranakomCollege of Management

    Mahidol University

    69 Vipawadee Rangsit Rd.

    Phayathai, Bangkok, 10400 THAILAND

    +662-206-2000 Ext. 2105

    [email protected]

    Last modified: July 2010

    * Corresponding Author.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    2/46

    Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment in Mergers and Acquisitions

    ABSTRACT

    This study examines how relative differences in dividend policies affect the choice of

    payment method in mergers and acquisitions. Using the dividend clientele hypothesis, we

    hypothesize that, at the margin, the method of payment is more likely to be stock if the

    dividend policies of the two firms involved in a merger or acquisition are quite similar, but

    more likely to be cash if the dividend policies are much different. The empirical data support

    the relevance of the dividend clientele hypothesis for the method of payment in mergers and

    acquisitions. We also find some evidence that in stock-based deals a difference in dividend

    policies is negatively correlated with announcement returns.

    JEL classification: G32, G34, G35

    Keywords: Mergers and Acquisitions; Method of Payment; Dividend Clientele; Dividend

    Policies; Announcement Returns

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    3/46

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    4/46

    2

    price movement as the change in dividend policy is more apparent to those investors who

    find it less favorable (present stockholders) than to those who find it more favorable."

    Baker, Coval, and Stein (2007) show that if the demand curve for the acquirers stock

    is downward sloping, then the cost of a stock for stock merger is decreasing in the fraction of

    target shareholders who passively accept and retain acquirer shares. Each share retained by a

    passive target shareholder is one less share that must be absorbed by market investors with a

    lower evaluation of the acquirer. Demand curves for stocks may slope down for a number of

    reasons. Miller (1977) suggested the combined effects of differences of opinion and short-

    sale constraints. The empirical literature provides clear support for downward-sloping

    demand curves (e.g. Harris and Gurel, 1986; Shleifer, 1986; Bagwell, 1992; Hodrick, 1999;

    Kaul, Mehrotra, and Morck, 2000; Wurgler and Zhuravskaya, 2002; and Greenwood, 2005).

    In the context of mergers, Mitchell, Pulvino, and Stafford (2004) focus on price pressure

    around mergers and Baker, et al. (2007) find evidence in support of inertial behavior by

    target shareholders and that acquirer returns are lower when inertia is lower.

    We argue that if the target firm's dividend policy is very different from the acquiring

    firm's, this may serve as a disincentive to a stock based acquisition. If the dividend clientele

    hypothesis holds and the dividend policies of the acquirer and the target are materially

    different and stock is used in the acquisition, this may cause a change in the shareholder

    composition of the targets shareholder base. That is, target shareholders may decide to

    rebalance their portfolios. They may decide to sell their position in the target, before the

    merger is consummated, or in the survivor firm, after the merger is consummated, if they do

    not like the dividend policy of the acquiring firm. In the language of Baker, et al. (2007), a

    similarity in dividend policies between the target and the acquirer increases inertia, while a

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    5/46

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    6/46

    4

    management faces the qualitative decision to pay in the form of either stock, cash, or some

    mix of the two. The results of our multinomial regressions show that the degree of difference

    in dividend policies is significantly higher for pure cash deals than pure stock deals. We

    alternatively examine the determinants of the proportion of cash payment used in takeovers

    using a two-limit Tobit approach. The results are similar to our discrete analysis showing that

    a difference in dividend policies significantly increases the percentage of cash payment. In

    addition, consistent with previous studies, we find that several deal, target, and acquirer

    characteristics serve as important determinants of the payment choice.

    We also examine the relationship between the degree of similarity in dividend

    policies and takeover abnormal announcement returns. According to the dividend clientele

    hypothesis, target shareholders who do not prefer the dividend policy of the acquiring firm

    may sell at any point from the announcement date until after the merger consummation.

    However, clienteles preferring the dividend policy of the acquirer would not buy until the

    likelihood of merger consummation was high enough and the price drop large enough to

    compensate them for the risk of merger failure and the transaction costs of rebalancing.

    Target announcement returns will be lower if some dividend related selling occurs at the

    announcement date and the effect is not fully transferred by merger arbitragers immediately

    to the acquirer. Acquirer announcement returns will be lower if merger arbitragers

    immediately transfer, at least partially, the effects of any selling by target shareholders to the

    acquirer. Therefore, our second hypothesis states that in stock based acquisitions abnormal

    announcement returns of targets, acquirers, or both are lower if the level of difference in

    dividend policies is larger.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    7/46

    5

    To test this hypothesis, we conduct both OLS and a 2-step procedure that controls for

    the potential endogeneity of the choice of the payment methods. Our results show that target

    cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) at the takeover announcement date for stock deals are

    significantly lower when one firm pays a dividend but the other does not and decreases in the

    difference in dividend policies between target and acquiring firms when dividend yield is

    used to measure the differential in dividend policies. We also find some evidence that

    acquirer CARs decrease in the difference in dividend policies. In addition, our results are

    largely consistent with adverse selection explanations that announcement returns are lower

    for stock based acquisitions because acquirers may use their stock to pay for acquisitions

    only when their stock is overvalued (Myers and Majluf, 1984; Travlos, 1987; Amihud, Lev

    and Travlos, 1990).

    In sum, this study provides a new perspective regarding the takeover method of

    payment choice by showing that, in addition to other factors related to traditional

    explanations of method of payment, the dividend policies of target and acquiring firms are a

    key determinant of the payment choice. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.

    In Section 2, we present the research hypotheses and describe the dependent and test

    variables and the testing techniques. Section 3 details the sample selection process and

    provides the descriptions of the control variables and the rationales for including them,

    including references to relevant literature, and presents the descriptive statistics. Section 4

    analyzes the determinants of the payment method. Section 5 analyzes announcement returns,

    and Section 6 concludes.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    8/46

    6

    2. Hypotheses Development, Dependent and Test Variables, and Testing Techniques

    2.1. Hypotheses

    We construct and test two hypotheses in this study. The first hypothesis states that, if

    the dividend policies of the two firms involved in an acquisition are quite similar, it is more

    likely that a method of payment for the acquisition is going to be stock, other things equal. A

    method of payment is more likely to be cash if the dividend policies are much different, other

    things equal. Ceteris paribus, the management should consider using a stock based

    acquisition when the dividend policies are similar and use cash when the dividend policies

    are fundamentally different.

    Our second hypothesis states that for stock based mergers, abnormal stock returns on

    the announcement day for the target, the acquirer, or both are lower if the level of difference

    in dividend policies is greater. In this case, selling activities by target shareholders who do

    not like the change in dividend policy that a successful merger would entail may put

    downward pressure on the target stock price. Potential buyers who prefer the new dividend

    policy may delay their purchase until the merger has a reasonably high probability of

    consummation and they can cover the transaction costs of rebalancing through a temporarily

    depressed stock price. These factors may result in a lower announcement return, ceteris

    paribus, for targets when the dividend policies of the target and the acquirer differ

    substantially. A negative effect of dividend differences on announcement returns for stock

    based mergers for acquiring firms is also possible if dividend related effects are anticipated

    and arbitraged by the market. Both may experience negative return if any effect is only

    partially arbitraged.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    9/46

    7

    2.2. The Dependent and Test Variables

    2.2.1. Dependent Variables : Method of Payment and Announcement Returns

    We take both dummy variable and continuous variable approaches to measure the

    payment method. First, we categorize deals into three groups in terms of their payment

    methods; Cash Only, Mixed Paymentand Stock Only. Cash Only includes deals where at

    least 90% of consideration is paid with cash. Stock Only includes deals where at least 90% of

    consideration is paid with acquirer stock.2Mixed Paymentincludes deals financed with both

    stock and cash. Alternatively, we use a continuous variable, %Cash PMTor%Stock PMT,

    which takes on any value between zero and one.

    Announcement returns, CARs, are the cumulative abnormal returns over the three-

    day window [-1, +1] or five-day window [-2, +2] around the bid announcement using the

    firm return minus the CRSP value-weighted market return. We calculate the announcement

    returns for both target and acquiring firms.

    2.2.2. Measures of a Difference in Dividend Policies

    We obtain cash dividends for each acquiring firm and target firm from the

    COMPUSTAT database. We collect quarterly dividend data as of the end of the quarter

    immediately preceding the quarter when a merger is announced. We then average actual

    dividend payments over the last 4 quarters in order to account for seasonality in dividend

    payments. For example, if a merger is announced in the second quarter of 2006, we average

    quarterly dividends from the second quarter of 2005 to the first quarter of 2006.3

    We use three measures of a difference in dividend policies between an acquirer and

    2 We use alternative definitions for cash- or stock-based acquisitions and the results are similar to those

    presented here.3 In unreported results, we also use the quarterly dividend prior to the announcement date. The results are

    similar to those presented here.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    10/46

    8

    target. First, One is Payeris a dummy variable equal to 1 if one of the two firms involved in

    the merger pays any dividend during the last 4 quarters prior to the deal announcement, while

    the other does not, and equals 0 otherwise. Dividend policies are significantly different in the

    case that only one of the two firms pays a dividend. There is less difference in dividend

    policies if both or neither firm pay dividends. We also calculate the absolute value of

    differences in the dividend yield between targets and acquirers,Diff.DivYield, and, in order to

    ensure that our results are not affected by stock price variation (Grinstein and Michaely,

    2005; Li and Zhao, 2008), we also use the absolute value of differences in the dividend to

    book value ratio between targets and acquirers,Diff.Div/Book. DivYield is defined as the

    ratio of dividends per share to the market price per share and Div/Book is the ratio of the

    amount of dividends to the book value of assets.

    For example, for a merger between a firm with a dividend yield of 2.0% and a firm

    with a dividend yield of 5.0%, the dividend yield difference between the two companies

    would be |2.0% - 5.0%| = 3.0%. The closer this number is to zero, the more similar the

    dividend policies between the two firms are. For the coefficient on Diff.DivYield to be

    meaningful, we add a control variableAcquirer DivYieldto control for the levels of dividend

    yields of the acquiring firms. Likewise, we add a control variable Acquirer Div/Bookwhen

    Diff.Div/Bookis included as a variable of interest. We do so because a 3% value reported in

    Diff.DivYieldmay result, for example, from a 3%-dividend-yield acquirer takes over a non-

    dividend-paying firm, or it may result from a non-dividend-paying acquirer buys a 3%-

    dividend-yield firm. The impact on the method of payment from these two cases may be

    different. Hence, we use the variableAcquirer DivYieldto control for the differences in the

    acquirers dividend yields.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    11/46

    9

    2.3. Testing Techniques

    To test the first hypothesis, we adopt the multinomial logit model as well as the two-

    limit Tobit model. First, we consider the case where acquirer management faces the

    qualitative financing decision. Faccio and Masulis (2005) argue that in many mixed deals,

    target shareholders have a choice to receive cash or stock, implying that acquiring firms do

    not determine the fraction of cash financing.4

    Accordingly, we categorized the sample into

    three groups in terms of their payment methods. An indicator variable, MOP, takes a value of

    0 for pure cash deals, 1 for mixed deals (whether the mix is acquirer or target determined),

    and 2 for pure stock deals. Using MOPas a dependent variable, we estimate the following

    multinomial logit regression :

    (1)

    where P(MOPi=K) is the probability that a deal i will have the Kth

    payment method. The

    variables of interest are the measures of the degree of similarity in dividend policies, One is

    Payer,Diff.DivYield, orDiff.Div/Book. Following previous literature, we include a number of

    other control variables including; deal characteristic variables such asDeal Premium, ln(Deal

    Value), Related Deal, Hostile, and Tender Offer, acquirer characteristic variables such as

    Insider Ownership, Insider Ownership Squared, Leverage, Change in Leverage, PPE/Book,

    Market/Book, Cash/Deal Value, andPrereturns, and target characteristic variables including

    Relative Size, Insider Ownership, Insider Ownership Squared, Institutional Ownership,

    4 The fact that target shareholders have a choice to receive cash or stock should not affect our investigation of

    the relationship between method of payment and dividend differences since, in equilibrium, the more similar the

    dividend policies of the two firms the more likely stock is the method of payment, ceteris paribus, irrespectiveof whether the choice is made by the acquirer or target shareholders. In our examination of announcement

    returns, our key test variable is an interaction term related to stock only acquisitions.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    12/46

    10

    Leverage, and Market/Book. All the control variables and the rationales for including them

    are discussed fully in Section 3.2.

    We also examine the effect of a difference in dividend policies on the fraction of cash

    financing by adopting the two-limit Tobit model. In this model, the dependent

    variable, %Cash PMT, can be thought of as a latent variable that is truncated at both lower

    and upper limits, namely at zero and one. %Cash PMTvalues that we actually observe are

    bounded between zero and one. Specifically, we estimate the following model :

    (2)

    wherex is the set of explanatory variables and,

    iCashPMT% = 1 if iCashPMT%*1, all cash

    iCashPMT% = iCashPMT%*

    if 0< iCashPMT%*

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    13/46

    11

    CARs=+1(Stock OnlyMeasures of Dividend Differences) + 2 Measures of

    Dividend Differences +3 Stock Only+ 4X+e (3)

    Announcement returns, CARs, are measured as the cumulative abnormal returns of

    targets and acquirers, respectively, relative to the CRSP value-weighted market index,

    computed for the event windows of [-1, +1] and [-2, +2] days around a bid announcement

    date. Measures of Dividend Differences refers to the three measures of dividend differences

    previously discussed. As discussed in our second hypothesis, we expect the interaction term

    of a dividend difference and a stock based acquisition dummy, Stock Only Measures of

    Dividend Differences, is negatively correlated with target and/or acquirer announcement

    returns. We include several control variables (designated by the vector X) in the

    announcement returns regressions; including the acquirers ln (Market Value), Market/Book,

    Leverage, and PPE/Bookand the targets Relative Size, Institutional Ownership, Leverage,

    Stock Return Volatility, and Market/Book. The control variable descriptions and the

    rationales for including them are again provided inSection 3.2.

    A potential concern in equation (3), however, is that the payment method, Stock Only,

    is an endogenous variable because it is not randomly determined (Faccio and Masulis, 2005).

    If the payment method is indeed endogenous, then the interaction term of the payment

    method and a difference in dividend policies also becomes an endogenous variable. As a

    result, controlling for this endogeneity is integral to estimating the model. In order to control

    for the potential endogenous problem in our regressions, we additionally estimate the

    following 2-stage least squares (2SLS) equations:

    1st

    reduced form: %Stock PMT = 1 z1+ 2 z2+ 3X+u

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    14/46

    12

    2nd

    reduced form: %Stock PMTMeasures of Dividend Differences= 1z1+ 2 z2+ 3 X+w

    Main equation:

    CARs=+1P[%Stock PMTMeasures of Dividend Differences] + 2 Measures of

    Dividend Differences +3 P[%Stock PMT]+ 4X+e (4)

    where P[] refers to the predicted value from the first stage regressions.6

    In this model, we have two sets of instrumental variables; one for %Stock PMTand

    the other for %Stock PMTMeasures of Dividend Differences. The set of instrumental

    variables for%Stock PMTisz1. Since %Stock PMTMeasures of Dividend Differences is an

    interaction term, the instrumental variables, z2, arez1Measures of Dividend Differences.

    Note that in order to satisfy the over-identification condition, all instrumental variable sets (z1

    andz2) and the exogenous variable set,X, must be included in both first and second reduced

    forms.7

    Instrumental variable sets,z1and z2, are described in Section 3.2.

    3. Sample Selection, Control Variable Descriptions, and Summary Statistics

    3.1. Sample

    Our sample consists of all mergers and acquisitions that were announced from

    January 1, 2001 to December 31, 2007, obtained from the Securities Data Corporation (SDC)

    Platinum Mergers and Acquisitions database. All mergers and acquisitions must satisfy the

    following screening criteria : 1) deal value is greater than one million dollars and is publicly

    disclosed, 2) the percentage of shares of the target firm held by an acquirer at announcement

    is less than 50%, 3) stock prices are available in the Center for Research in Securities Prices

    6 Instead of the discrete variable, Stock Only, we use a continuous variable for stock payment, %Stock PMT,

    defined as the percent of stock financing.

    7 See Section 6.2 of Wooldridge (2002) for detailed discussion of this model.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    15/46

    13

    (CRSP) database, 4) Financial data are available in COMPUSTAT for both targets and

    acquirers, and 5) insider ownership data are available in the Thomson Financial Network

    (TFN) Insider Filing database for both targets and acquirers. The sample restrictions result in

    a final sample of 1,022 deal observations.

    3.2. Control Variable Descriptions

    The literature has suggested that various factors may have some impact on the

    outcome of a method of payment in acquisitions. The variables mentioned below will be used

    as our control variables for these factors in our payment choice regression models.

    3.2.1. Ownership Structure

    Managers of an acquiring firm who value control may prefer to use cash as a means

    of payment in an acquisition because stock dilutes their ownership in the combined firm

    (Amihud, Lev, and Travlos, 1990; Harris and Raviv, 1988; Martin, 1996; Mayer and Walker,

    1996; Stulz, 1988; Yook, Gangopadhyay, and McCabe, 1999). Conversely, managers of a

    target firm may be interested in retaining control in the combined firm after the merger or

    acquisition (Ghosh and Ruland, 1998). Ghosh and Ruland find that the target firms

    managerial ownership is an even more important factor than the acquiring firms managerial

    ownership in explaining the method of payment in acquisitions. Faccio and Masulis (2005)

    indicate the role of managerial ownership may be non-linear and we control for this as well.

    Thus, we include the acquiring firm's percentage of insider ownership, Acquirer Insider

    Ownership, and the target firm's percentage of insider ownership, Target Insider Ownership,

    and their squares in our empirical models. The data on ownership is obtained from the TFN

    Insider Filing database. The more stake the management of the acquiring firm has in the

    firm, the more likely the acquiring firm will use cash as a means of payment for the

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    16/46

    14

    acquisition. So, we expect the coefficient ofAcquirer Insider Ownership to have a positive

    sign. On the contrary, the higher the percentage of target firm's insider ownership, the more

    likely the means of payment will be stock. Thus, we expect the coefficient ofTarget Insider

    Ownership to have a negative sign.8

    Baker, et al. (2007) show that if the proportion of passive shareholders who accept

    acquirer stock in a stock for stock deal decreases, acquirer returns to the acquisition decrease.

    They find that institutional shareholders are less likely to be passive than individual

    shareholders. Accordingly we control for the percentage of institutional target shareholders

    using Target Institutional Ownership. The larger this percentage, the less attractive a stock

    merger is for the acquirer and hence acquirers would be less likely to use stock and if they do

    so the merger is likely to have lower announcement returns.

    3.2.2. Relative Cost of Funds

    According to Myers (1984) pecking order theory, firms should fund their investment

    opportunities from internally generated cash flow whenever feasible. If cash flow is

    inadequate, debt should be the next financing option the firms should consider. Equity

    financing, being the most expensive, should be considered last, only when the firms have no

    other financing option. This implies that if the acquiring firm has a lot of free cash flow, the

    firm is more likely to use cash as a means of payment for the acquisition. Martin (1996), and

    Mayer and Walker (1996) find acquirers, who have an ample amount of cash on the balance

    sheet or who can generate a large amount of free cash flow and have a low level of leverage,

    tend to use cash and/or debt to finance their acquisitions. Our variable, Cash/Deal Value,

    8 Faccio and Masulis (2005) provide the tradeoff hypothesis between corporate control concerns and

    debt constraints. They argue that an acquirers payment decision is influenced by debt capacity and existingleverage and, simultaneously, by insiders desire to maintain their control of firms. We consider leverage below.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    17/46

    15

    measures the amount of acquirer cash plus marketable securities normalized by the value of

    the merger or acquisition.

    In the case where the acquirer does not have enough cash, but it is not already highly

    leveraged, the acquirer can issue new debt to fund the acquisition. The acquirer can also use

    the unused lending capacity from the target firm if the target firm is under-leveraged.

    Chaney, Lovata, and Philipich (1991) find that acquiring firms that use cash acquisitions tend

    to be highly levered small firms with high return on assets, while acquiring firms that use

    stock acquisitions tend to have large asset bases, low leverage, low return on assets, and high

    price-earnings ratios. Acquirer Leverage and Target Leverage measure the debt to assets

    ratio of acquirers and target firms, respectively. Faccio and Masulis (2005) control for the

    borrowing power of the acquirer using a variable related to the collateral capacity of the firm,

    which they measure using property, plant, and equipment (PPE) over the book value of total

    assets. We also includePPE/Bookto control for the collateral value of the acquiring firms

    assets.

    Yook (2003) suggests that the leverage effect plays an important role in payment

    decisions. An increase in leverage caused by cash payment reduces the free cash flow

    problem that self-interested managers invest money on less profitable (or negative NPV)

    projects. The benefits of this leverage effect should be stronger when a firm has lower growth

    opportunities and large free cash on hand. To address this, we include Change in Leverage,

    defined as the change in the acquirers leverage (total liabilities/total assets) from t-2 to t-1

    (where t is the deal announcement year).

    When the stock price runs up considerably, it makes equity financing relatively less

    expensive. Acquirers could take advantage of such an occurrence by using stock as a means

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    18/46

    16

    of payment when their stock prices have gone up prior to the merger or acquisition

    announcement. Conventional wisdom suggests that targets would recognize such overvalued

    stock offers and refuse them. However, research by Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004)

    suggests that stock price appreciation of bidders and targets may be positively correlated.

    Mutual overvaluation can lead bidders to make, and targets to accept, stock offers

    introducing a possible positive correlation between stock price appreciation, merger

    frequency, and use of stock as a method of payment. Shleifer and Vishny (2003) construct a

    model where mutual overvaluation can also lead to a positive correlation between stock price

    performance and the use of stock as a method of payment in acquisitions. We use a 90-

    trading-day market-adjusted cumulative return at the 30th

    trading day prior to the

    announcement date,Prereturns, to measure how much the stock price of each acquiring firm

    has run-up. We predict a negative sign on this coefficient. The higher the stock returns prior

    to mergers or acquisitions announcements, the higher the likelihood that acquirers will use

    stock.

    The growth opportunities of acquiring firms also affect the payment choice. An

    acquirer with a high growth rate may be able to use their high multiple stock to pay for

    acquisitions.Acquirer Market/Bookis defined as the sum of total assets and market value of

    equity minus book value of equity divided by total assets. We also include Target

    Market/Book. According to Carleton, Guilkey, Harris and Stewart (1983), a high target

    market to book ratio represents potentially high capital gains for target shareholders and non-

    deductible goodwill for acquirers, hence low market to book ratios of targets are associated

    with the use of cash.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    19/46

    17

    3.2.3. Asymmetric Information

    Payment for acquisitions in the form of stock can help alleviate an asymmetric

    information problem. Asymmetric information exists in acquisitions because acquirers may

    know more about the value of their own firms than do target firms, but may not be able to

    derive a correct estimate of the true value of target firms, and vice versa. Hansen (1987)

    regards a stock offer as a contingent pricing mechanism. He finds that when target firms

    know their values better than acquirers, the acquirers will prefer to use stock, which has

    desirable contingent-pricing characteristics, rather than cash. When asymmetric information

    exists on both acquirers and target firms sides, a signaling equilibrium develops whereby

    targets regard both the method of payment used and the size of the stock offer as signals of

    the value of the acquiring firms. However, he finds only minimal supportive evidence.

    Fishman (1988) and Eckbo, Giammarino, and Heinkel (1990) also provide adverse selection

    based models of the acquirers choice of payment.

    When stock is used as a payment in acquisitions, the risks of a miscalculated firm

    valuation are shared between acquirers and targets. This type of risk is likely to be small

    when an acquirer is a much larger firm than is a target firm. As the target firms size

    increases, the risks are larger. Following Martin (1996),Relative Size is our proxy variable

    for information asymmetry which measures the relative size of target firm to acquiring firm.

    Relative Size is a ratio of targets market value of equity to the sum of targets market value

    and acquirers market value as of the year-end prior to the deal announcement.9

    The larger

    the size of the target firm relative to the acquirer, the higher the risks of valuation

    9 In unreported regressions we substitute an alternative relative size measure, which is the ratio of target firms

    total assets to the sum of targets total assets and acquirers total assets. The results are essentially unchanged.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    20/46

    18

    miscalculation and, thus, the higher the probability of a use of stock as a payment

    consideration.10

    Target Return Volatility, an alternative proxy for information asymmetry that may be

    particularly relevant to announcement returns, is the standard deviation of daily stock returns

    during the one year prior to the bid announcement date. Officer, Poulsen, and Stegemoller

    (2009) find that acquirer announcement returns are greater in stock based acquisitions when

    target stock return volatility is greater, which implies that targets market value is difficult to

    estimate.

    3.2.4. Deal Characteristics and Acquirer Size

    We examine several variables that capture deal characteristics. Deal Premium is

    defined as an acquirers offer value for the target over the pre-offer market value of the target

    minus one. We follow the approach of Officer (2003) to calculate deal premium. Ln(Deal

    Value) is the natural logarithm of deal value.Related Dealis a dummy variable equal to 1 if

    an acquirer and target share the same primary 2-digit SIC code and 0, otherwise. Hostile is a

    dummy variable equal to 1 if deal attitude is hostile and 0 if friendly or unsolicited as

    classified by the SDC. Tender Offeris a dummy variable equal to 1 if an acquirer involves a

    tender offer as reported in SDC and 0, otherwise.

    In the announcement return regressions we include a number of the variables

    previously discussed. We also include the natural log of the acquirers market value,

    ln(Market Value) in the announcement return regressions. Our control variables in the

    10 Mayer and Walker (1996) use both the interaction between earnings predictability and the market to book

    ratio of acquirers, and the ratio of market value of equity for target firms to that of acquirers to proxy for theinformation asymmetry. However, they find that these variables have only minimal impact on the method of

    payment.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    21/46

    19

    announcement returns regressions follow previous literature such as Moeller, Schlingemann,

    and Stulz (2004) and Officer, Poulsen, and Stegemoller (2009).

    3.2.5. Instrumental Variables for Equation (4)

    The set of instrumental variables for the percentage stock financing, %Stock PMT, in

    the first stage estimation associated with Equation (4) includes two variables. Average

    Acquirer Industry %Stock PMTis the acquirer industry-average (based on the 1-digit

    acquirer SIC code) proportion of stock financing during the quarter prior to the bid

    announcement. Average Target Industry %Stock PMTis the target industry-average %Stock

    PMT, computed in the same manner. We construct instrumental variables for an interaction

    variable of the proportion of stock financing and our three measures of differences in

    dividend policies, %Stock PMTMeasures of Dividend Differences, by interacting the

    instrumental variables for%Stock PMTand the measures of differences in dividend policies.

    3.3. Descriptive Statistics

    [Table 1 about here]

    Table 1 presents the summary statistics when deals are classified by the payment

    method and dividend policy. There are 379 deals (37.1% of total sample) financed only with

    cash, while 271 deals (26.5%) are financed only with stock. The frequency of stock-based

    deals is the highest in the year 2001 (87 out of 208 deals), and is then generally decreasing

    over the sample years. The average of the cash portion of consideration is about 50%, while

    that of the stock portion is about 43%. During the sample period, 355 target and 535

    acquiring firms pay dividends. The average quarterly dividend yield of target and acquiring

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    22/46

    20

    firms are 0.802% and 0.956%, respectively.11

    The average dividend to book value ratio is

    1.233% for targets and 1.555% for acquiring firms. In 303 mergers, only one firm (either a

    target or an acquirer) pays a positive dividend during last 4 quarters prior to the deal

    agreement. In 312 merger deals, both firms pay dividends, while no firm pays a dividend in

    407 deals. The mean and median of the absolute differences in dividend yields,Diff.DivYield,

    are 0.404% and 0.077%, respectively, while those ofDiff.Div/Bookare 1.157% and 0.00%,

    respectively.

    4. Effects of Differences in Dividend Policies on the Payment Method

    [Table 2 about here]

    Table 2 presents the mean and median differences in dividend policies for the three

    sub-groups in terms of the payment method. Tests for statistically significant differences

    between the Stock Only group and other groups are from t-tests and Wilcoxon rank-sum tests

    for each of the three measures of dividend differences: One is Payer, Diff.DivYield, and

    Diff.Div/Book. The overall results in Table 2 support the hypothesis that acquirers are more

    likely to pay with stock when dividend policies are similar. All 1,022 deals are examined in

    Panel A. Thirty-nine percent of the merger deals in the Cash Only group have a single

    dividend payer (i.e. are part of the One is Payerclassification). In the Mixed Paymentgroup,

    24% of the deals have only one dividend payer. The percentages ofOne is Payer in both

    Cash Only and Mixed Paymentgroups are significantly higher than that in the Stock Only

    group, 19%. The mean and median Diff.DivYieldof the Cash Only group are 0.495% and

    11 Note that this is average quarterly dividend yield. One may calculate annual dividend yield by multiplying by

    4.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    23/46

    21

    0.122%, respectively, which are (weakly) significantly greater than those of the Stock Only

    group, 0.391% and 0%. The mean and median ofDiff.Div/Bookare also significantly higher

    for the Cash Only group (1.467% and 0.155%, respectively) than for the Stock Only group

    (0.472% and 0%). The Mixed Payment group also has greater dividend policy differences

    than the Stock Only group, while lower than the Cash Only group (these test results are not

    reported). In Panel B, we drop the deals where both targets and acquires do not pay any

    dividend in the previous quarters. As a result, the values of the percentage ofOne is Payer,

    Diff.DivYieldand Diff.Div/Bookare greater than those in Panel A. However, the results of

    univariate tests remain consistent withPanel A.

    [Table 3 about here]

    Table 3 reports estimates of multinomial logit models on the acquirers financing

    decisions as a function of the measures for dividend differences and the control variables.

    The table makes pair-wise comparisons between three categories of payment methods: Cash

    Only, Mixed Paymentand Stock Only. Note that in a multinomial logit analysis, a regression

    coefficient indicates the effects on the log-odds between each of the groups and the reference

    group. In the first regression, where the reference choice is the Stock Only group, the

    coefficients ofOne is Payer,Diff.DivYieldandDiff.Div/Bookare all positive and statistically

    significant in the Cash Only group. Thus, if dividend differences between the target and

    acquirer are greater, the acquisition is more likely to be financed by cash than stock, which is

    consistent with our first hypothesis.

    In the second and third regressions, whenDiff.DivYield(Diff.Div/Book) is used as the

    independent variable, we control for the DivYield (Div/Book) of acquiring firms. The

    negative coefficients onAcquirer DivYieldandAcquirer Div/Booksuggest that the higher the

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    24/46

    22

    acquirers dividend level, the more likely the acquisition is to be stock based. While we had

    no prior expectation regarding the sign of this variable, the empirical results are consistent

    with the proposition that dividend paying stock is more likely to be used as an acquisition

    vehicle.

    In each of our regressions, where the dependent variable is Mixed Paymentand the

    reference group is Stock Only, the coefficients of our dividend difference measures are

    positive but not statistically significant. Also, in the third regression, where the dependent

    variable is Cash Only and reference group is Mixed Payment, the coefficients of the dividend

    difference measures are positive, but again insignificant. Therefore, the results suggest that

    even if the degree of dividend differences leads an acquirer to choose a cash deal rather than

    stock deal, it does not significantly affect a choice between mixed payment and stock only or

    a cash deal versus a mixed deal.

    Note that most of the coefficients of the control variables are signed in accordance

    with our expectations and prior literature. We find that tender offers are usually financed

    with cash (Jensen and Ruback, 1983). The positive coefficient ofCash/Deal Value implies

    that an acquirer maintaining more cash has a greater ability of cash financing and, therefore,

    is more likely to use cash as a mean of payment. Consistent with Faccio and Masulis (2005),

    the negative coefficient ofPrereturns suggests that when acquirers stock price is overvalued

    at the announcement date the acquirer is more likely to use stock financing. Acquirer

    Leverage displays a positive sign, which suggests that acquirers may borrow early in

    anticipation of future cash acquisitions. The coefficient ofTarget Insider Ownership displays

    a significant quadratic relationship, first falling and then rising, implying higher managerial

    ownership in target firms at first decreases, but ultimately increases, the likelihood of the

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    25/46

    23

    method of payment being cash. Ghosh and Ruland (1998) have previously documented a

    negative relationship (i.e. a positive relationship between target inside ownership and stock

    payments).Relative Size is negatively correlated with the probability of cash payment and is

    weakly significant, implying a larger target size, which increases the risk of valuation

    miscalculation, results in the lower chance of cash financing rather than stock financing. The

    results support the asymmetric information hypothesis (Hansen, 1987; Martin, 1996). Target

    Institutional Ownership is positively related to the probability of a cash payment, consistent

    with the arguments of Baker, et al. (2007). TargetLeverage is negatively related to the

    probability of a cash payment.

    [Table 4 about here]

    In Table 4, we alternatively employ a two-limit Tobit approach to examine the effect

    of dividend differences on the fraction of cash financing, %Cash PMT. The Q-MLE is used

    to maximize a log-likelihood function, in cases where that function is possibly misspecified

    due to the specification of the wrong density. The proxies for a difference in dividend

    policies (One is Payer, Diff.DivYield and Diff.Div/Book) have positive and significant

    coefficients, implying that the proportion of cash financing is increasing in these variables.

    The result is consistent with the first hypothesis that with a greater difference in the dividend

    policies between an acquirer and target, acquirer management is more likely to choose cash

    as the payment form. The effect of the level of the dividend yield or dividend to book ratio of

    an acquirer in the second and third regressions is negative and significant, consistent with the

    findings in the first regression in Table 3. As expected, other important determinants of the

    percentage of cash payment include Deal Premium, Tender Offer, Cash/Deal Value,

    Prereturns, Target Insider Ownership, Target Institutional Ownership, and Target Leverage.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    26/46

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    27/46

    25

    24.60%, respectively. In contrast, takeovers are possibly wealth destroying for acquiring

    firms where average CARs are -1.45% and -1.41% in the three-day and five-day windows,

    respectively. The table also shows that the average CARs of the Cash Only group are

    significantly higher than the Stock Only group. The average CARs of acquiring firms are

    0.41% in the three-day window and 0.57% in the five-day window for a cash deal, while they

    have negative values for a stock deal. Also, cash based takeovers are associated with greater

    target CARs. As widely documented in the literature, the lower announcement returns

    associated with stock deals are consistent with the adverse selection argument initially

    suggested by Myers and Majluf (1984). The mergers and acquisitions literature applies the

    adverse selection argument to suggest that acquiring firms pay with stock only when their

    shares are overvalued (Travlos, 1987; Amihud, Lev and Travlos, 1990).

    [Table 6 about here]

    Table 6 presents the results of OLS regressions that analyze the determinants of

    takeover announcement returns for both target and acquiring firms. The variable of interest in

    the regressions is the interaction variable of a dummy for a stock deal and the difference in

    dividend policies. As discussed above, our second hypothesis states that abnormal

    announcement returns are lower for a stock based deal with a greater difference in dividend

    policies. Whether this negative announcement effect is greater for target firms or acquiring

    firms depends upon whether merger arbitragers anticipate the extent of dividend related

    selling and the speed with which they shift its effects to acquirers. In Panel A, consistent with

    our hypothesis, the coefficients of the interaction variables between a stock deal dummy and

    the degree of the dividend differences are negatively correlated with target returns for all

    three measures and are statistically significant when One is PayerandDiff.DivYieldare used

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    28/46

    26

    to measure the dividend differential. In stock based mergers target CARs decrease by, on

    average, 2.6% during the three-day window around the deal announcement and 5.9% during

    the five-day window if only one firm pays a dividend.12

    Also, target CARs drop by 2.9% or

    4.5% during the three-day or five-day windows, respectively, when the difference in

    dividend yield increases by one unit. In the acquirer CARs regressions in Panel B, the

    interaction terms again have negative coefficients for the three measures of dividend

    differences but are significant only when One is Payerand Diff.Div/Book(and the latter at

    the 10% level) are used as the dividend difference measure. In stock based takeovers, CARs

    of acquiring firms decrease by 0.6% (that is, -0.015 + 0.009) or 0.3% during the three-day or

    five-day windows, respectively, when only one firm pays a dividend. The evidence suggests

    that the market does not fully immediately shift the dividend effect in the acquirer stock price,

    but that some arbitrage activity does occur. In both panels, the coefficients of a dummy for a

    pure stock deal, Stock Only, are negative and significant at the 1% level in 11 of the 12

    specifications (and at the 5% level in the other), supporting the adverse selection hypothesis.

    We include several control variables in both the target and acquirer CARs regressions

    as suggested by previous literature. Target and acquirer announcement returns are

    significantly higher if the ln(Market Value) of an acquirer is larger, while they are lower if

    the targetsRelative Size is bigger. The positive coefficient on target Stock Return Volatility

    suggests that target firms with greater stock return volatility are more likely to benefit from

    takeovers. HigherTarget Institutional Ownership depresses announcement returns for both

    targets and acquirers consistent with Baker, et al.s (2007) passive shareholder arguments.

    12 Note that the coefficient ofOne is Payeris not statistically different from 0 in both the three-day and five-

    day CARs regressions. Therefore, the marginal effect of One is Payer in stock based deals is -0.0261+0=-

    0.026.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    29/46

    27

    Finally, we find that Target Leverage is negatively associated with target announcement

    returns.

    [Table 7 about here]

    A potential concern in Table 6 is that a decision on a pure stock payment would not

    be randomly assigned, resulting in endogeneity bias. As discussed in Section I.C, we employ

    the two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach to control for the endogeneity of payment

    decisions in takeovers. Table 7 reports the results of both first and second stage 2SLS

    regressions. In Panel A , One is Payeris used for the measure of dividend difference, while

    Diff.DivYieldandDiff.Div/Bookare used in Panel B and Panel C, respectively. In the reduced

    form regressions in each panel, we estimate the determinants of the endogenous

    variables, %Stock PMTand %Stock PMTMeasure of Dividend Differences. In each panel,

    the instrumental variables, described in Section 3.2.5, are significantly and positively

    correlated with each of the endogenous variables they are intended to instrument, confirming

    that there is no weak instrument problem.

    The results of 2SLS in Table 7 are generally consistent with our findings from the

    OLS regressions in Table 6. In Panel A, the predicted value of the interaction variable

    between %Stock and One is Payer is negatively and significantly correlated with target

    CARs, confirming that our results in Table 6 are robust after controlling for endogeneity. For

    acquiring firms, it is negative and weakly significant when three-day CARs are used, but not

    significant when five-day CARs are used. In Panel B Diff.DivYield, is used for the measure

    of the dividend differential. Consistent with our previous findings, target CARs are

    negatively correlated with the predicted value of the interaction variable, %Stock

    Diff.DivYield. The coefficient of the interaction variable, however, is negative but not

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    30/46

    28

    significant for acquirer CARs. In Panel C Diff.Div/Book, is used for the measure of dividend

    differential. The effect of the predicted value of %StockDiff.Div/Book is negative but not

    significant on both target and acquirer abnormal announcement returns. The results are thus

    similar to the OLS results for target CARs but somewhat weaker, in terms of statistical

    significance, for acquirer CARs. In addition, the predicted values of the percentage of stock

    payment in each panel are negatively correlated with both target and acquirer announcement

    returns, consistent with adverse selection explanations.

    Overall, the results of the announcement returns analysis support our second

    hypothesis. In stock based takeovers, the difference in dividend policies has a negative effect

    on target returns, reflecting the possibility of selling activities by target shareholders who will

    experience a change in dividend policy from that of the target firm to that of the acquirer.

    The effect, however, is less significant in the acquirer CARs regressions, suggesting that the

    market does not immediately fully arbitrage the dividend related effect.

    6. Conclusions

    The dividend clientele hypothesis suggests that shareholders are different in their

    preferences for payouts from the firms they invest in. Some shareholders prefer to receive a

    regular stream of income in the form of cash dividends, while others may prefer to forgo cash

    dividends in order to get a possibly better payout from a firm in the form of capital gains.

    Hence, different dividend policies attract different types of shareholders.

    Changes in dividend policies resulting from mergers of firms with dissimilar policies

    may result in portfolio rebalancing from target shareholders. Shareholders may reduce or

    totally liquidate their positions from the firms whose dividend policies have changed in a

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    31/46

    29

    way that is unfavorable to them. In anticipation of such a consequence, acquirers may at the

    margin select a method of payment based on how different the dividend policies are between

    the acquirers and the target firms.

    We offer two hypotheses. First, similar dividend policies between acquirers and

    targets increase the likelihood of the use of stock as a method of payment in acquisitions.

    Second, in stock based acquisitions abnormal announcement returns are lower if the level of

    difference in dividend policies is larger.

    Our empirical results generally support the hypothesis that the likelihood of acquirers

    using stock as the payment method in takeovers increases with the degree of similarity in

    dividend policies. To arrive at this conclusion, first we consider the case where acquirer

    management faces the qualitative decision to pay in the form of stock, cash, or a mix of the

    two. The results of our multinomial analysis show that the degree of difference in dividend

    policies is significantly higher for pure cash deals than pure stock deals. We, then, examine

    the determinants of the proportion of cash payment using a two-limit Tobit approach. The

    results show that a larger difference in dividend policies significantly increases the

    percentage of cash payment. We also find that the higher the dividend on the acquirer stock,

    the more likely it is to be used as an acquisition currency.

    To test our second hypothesis related to announcement returns, we conduct OLS and

    a 2-step procedure in order to control for endogeneity of payment decisions. Our results show

    that, for stock deals, target cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) around the takeover

    announcement date significantly decrease if only one firm pays a dividend and the other does

    not or if the difference in dividend yields between target and acquiring firms becomes larger.

    The negative effect for acquirer CARs, however, is only weakly significant and only when

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    32/46

    30

    one firm pays a dividend and the other does not. These results suggest that the market does

    not fully immediately incorporate the dividend effect in the acquirer stock price. In addition,

    our results are largely consistent with adverse selection explanations of the method of

    payment, which suggest that stock based acquisitions produce lower announcement returns

    because acquirers may use their stock to pay for acquisitions only when their stocks are

    overvalued.

    In sum, this study provides a new perspective regarding the takeover method of

    payment choice. We show that, in addition to factors related to traditional explanations of

    the method of payment, the dividend policies of target and acquiring firms are a key

    determinant of the payment choice.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    33/46

    31

    References

    Allen, F., Bernardo, A., Welch, I., 2000. A theory of dividends based on tax clienteles.

    Journal of Finance 55, 24992536.

    Amihud, Y., Lev, B., Travlos, N.G., 1990. Corporate control and the choice of investment

    financing: The case of corporate acquisitions. Journal of Finance 45, 603-616.

    Bagwell, L., 1992. Dutch auction repurchases: An analysis of shareholders heterogeneity.

    Journal of Finance 47, 71-105.

    Baker, M., Coval, J., Stein, J.C., 2007. Corporate financing decisions when investors take the

    path of least resistance. Journal of Financial Economics 84, 266-298.

    Carleton, W., Guilkey, D., Harris, R., Stewart, J., 1983. An empirical analysis of the role of

    the medium of exchange in mergers. Journal of Finance 38, 813-826.

    Cameron, A. C., P.K. Trivedi, P.K., 2005. Microeconometrics. Cambridge University Press,New York.

    Chaney, P. K., Lovata, L.M., Philipich, K.L., 1991. Acquiring firm characteristics and themedium of exchange. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics 30, 55-69.

    Eckbo, B. E., Giammarino, R.M., Heinkel, R.L., 1990. Asymmetric information and themedium of exchange in takeovers: Theory and tests. Review of Financial Studies 3, 651-

    675.

    Elton, E. J., Gruber, M.J., 1970. Marginal stockholder tax rates and the clientele effect.

    Review of Economics and Statistics 52, 68-74.

    Faccio, M., Masulis, R., 2005. The choice of payment method in European mergers and

    acquisitions. Journal of Finance 60, 13451388.

    Fishman, M. J., 1988. Preemptive bidding and the role of the medium of exchange in

    acquisitions. Journal of Finance 44, 41-57.

    Ghosh, A., Ruland, W., 1998. Managerial ownership, the method of payment for acquisitions

    and executive job retention. Journal of Finance 53, 785-798.

    Greenwood, R., 2005. Short- and long-term demand curves for stocks: Theory and evidence

    on the dynamics of arbitrage. Journal of Financial Economics 75, 607-649.

    Grinstein, Y., Michaely, R., 2005. Institutional holdings and payout policy. Journal of

    Finance 60, 1389-1426.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    34/46

    32

    Hansen, R. G., 1987. A theory for the choice of exchange medium in mergers andacquisitions. Journal of Business 60, 75-95.

    Harris, L., Gurel, E., 1986. Price and volume effects associated with changes in the S&P500

    list: New evidence for the existence of price pressures. Journal of Finance 41, 815-829.

    Harris, M., Raviv, A., 1988. Corporate control contests and capital structure. Journal of

    Financial Economics 20, 55-86.

    Heron, R., Lie, E., 2002. Operating performance and the method of payment in takeovers.

    Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 37, 137-155.

    Hodrick, L., 1999. Does stock price elasticity affect corporate financial decisions? Journal of

    Financial Economics 52, 225-256.

    Jensen, M. C., Ruback, R.S., 1983. The market for corporate control. The scientific evidence.Journal of Financial Economics 11, 5-50

    Kalay, A., 1982. The ex-dividend day behavior of stock prices: A re-examination of the

    clientele effect. Journal of Finance 37, 1059-1070.

    Kaul, A., Mehrotra, V., Morck, R., 2000. Demand curves for stocks do slope down: New

    evidence from an index weights adjustment. Journal of Finance 55, 893-912.

    Li, K., Zhao, X., 2008. Asymmetric information and dividend policy. Financial Management

    37, 673-694.

    Martin, K. J., 1996. The method of payment in corporate acquisitions, investment

    opportunities and management ownership. Journal of Finance 51, 1227-1246.

    Mayer, W. J., Walker, M.M. 1996. An empirical analysis of the choice of payment method in

    corporate acquisitions during 1980 to 1990. Quarterly Journal of Business and

    Economics 35, 48-65.

    Miller, E., 1977. Risk, uncertainty and divergence of opinion. Journal of Finance 32, 1151-

    1168.

    Mitchell, M, Pulvino, T., Stafford, E., 2004. Price pressure around mergers. Journal ofFinance 59, 31-63.

    Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F., Stulz, R., 2004. Firm size and the gains from acquisitions.

    Journal of Financial Economics 73, 201228.

    Myers, S. C., 1984. The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance 39, 575-592.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    35/46

    33

    Myers, S., Majluf, N., 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms haveinformation that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187221.

    Officer, M. S., 2003. Termination fees in mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Financial

    Economics 69, 43167.

    Officer, M. S., Poulsen, A.B., Stegemoller, M., 2009. Target-firm information asymmetry

    and acquirer returns. Review of Finance 13, 467-493.

    Rhodes-Kropf, M., Viswanathan, S., 2004. Market valuation and merger waves. Journal of

    Finance 59, 2685-2718.

    Scholz, J. K., 1992. A direct examination of the dividend clientele hypothesis. Journal of

    Public Economics 49, 261-285.

    Shleifer, A., 1986. Do demand curves for stocks slope down? Journal of Finance 41, 579-590.

    Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 2003. Stock market driven acquisitions. Journal of Financial

    Economics 70, 295-311.

    Stulz, R. M., 1988. Managerial control of voting rights: Financing policies and the market for

    corporate control. Journal of Financial Economics 20, 25-54.

    Travlos, N., 1987. Corporate takeover bids, methods of payment, and bidding firms stock

    returns. Journal of Finance 42, 943963.

    Wooldridge, J. M., 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. The MIT

    Press, Cambridge, MA.

    Wurgler, J., Zhuravskaya, E., 2002. Does arbitrage flatten demand curves for stocks? Journal

    of Business 75, 583-608.

    Yook, K. C., 2003. Larger return to cash acquisitions: Signaling effect or leverage effect?

    Journal of Business 76, 477-498.

    Yook, K. C., Gangopadhyay, P., McCabe, G.M., 1999. Information asymmetry, management

    control, and method of payment in acquisitions. Journal of Financial Research 22, 413-427.

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    36/46

    34

    Table 1. Descriptive Statistics

    This table provides summary statistics regarding the method of payment and dividend policies of target andacquiring firms. The sample includes 1,022 merger agreements during the period January, 2001 to December,

    2007. Cash Only includes deals where at least 90% of consideration is paid with cash. Stock Only includes deals

    where at least 90% of consideration is paid with acquirer stocks. Mixed Paymentincludes deals financed with

    both stock and cash. One is Payer,Diff.DivYield and Diff.Div/Book, based on quarterly dividends, are ourmeasures of the degree of difference in dividend policies and are discussed in Section 2.2.

    Year 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 Total

    Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Mean Median

    N 208 110 150 149 148 143 114 1,022 [100%]

    Payment Method

    Cash Only (N) 48 41 50 52 53 76 59 379 [37.1%]

    Stock Only (N) 87 33 40 39 29 25 18 271 [26.5%]

    Mixed Payment (N) 73 36 60 58 66 42 37 372 [36.4%]

    % Cash Financing 34.708 46.248 47.950 48.824 52.799 63.543 64.574 49.937 46.135

    % Stock Financing 55.101 45.040 45.578 45.564 40.402 30.090 31.282 42.945 43.725

    Target Dividends

    Dividend Payer (N) 57 34 54 52 53 56 49 355

    DivYield (%) 0.881 0.838 0.812 0.694 0.814 0.849 0.716 0.802 0.570

    Div/Book (%) 0.895 0.790 0.269 0.601 1.692 2.623 1.579 1.233 0.270

    Acquirer Dividends

    Dividend Payer (N) 79 53 75 93 82 90 63 535

    DivYield (%) 0.779 0.858 1.576 0.827 0.983 0.878 0.798 0.956 0.652

    Div/Book (%) 1.191 1.313 1.163 1.003 2.752 1.735 1.740 1.555 0.569

    Dividend Differential

    One is Payer (N) 59 27 31 51 49 50 36 303

    Both are Payers (N) 57 30 49 47 43 48 38 312

    Neither is Payer (N) 92 53 70 51 56 45 40 407

    Diff.DivYield (%) 0.195 0.246 0.736 0.264 0.510 0.564 0.348 0.404 0.077

    Diff.Div/Book (%) 0.754 0.517 0.563 0.667 1.845 1.796 2.240 1.157 0.000

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    37/46

    35

    Table 2. Univariate Tests

    The sample is divided into three groups based on their payment methods. Cash Only includes deals where atleast 90% of the consideration is paid with cash. Stock Only includes deals where at least 90% of the

    consideration is paid with acquirer stock. Mixed Payment includes deals financed with both stock and cash.

    Tests for statistically significant differences between the Stock Only group and other groups are from t-tests (for

    means) and Wilcoxon rank-sum (i.e. Mann-Whitney-Wilcoxon) tests for each of the three measures ofdifferences in dividend policies, One is Payer,Diff.DivYieldandDiff.Div/Book, which are discussed in Section

    2.2. The Wilcoxon tests are technically for the equality of the distributions rather than medians per se. The

    symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

    Panel A. Full Sample

    Cash Only Mixed Payment Stock Only

    N = 1022 379 372 271

    Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

    One is Payer (%) 38.522 *** 0 *** 23.656 ** 0 *** 19.188 0

    Diff.DivYield (%) 0.495 * 0.122 *** 0.423 0.106 *** 0.391 0

    Diff.Div/Book (%) 1.467 *** 0.155 *** 1.341 ** 0.006 *** 0.472 0

    Panel B. Subsample (When both targets and acquirers are dividend payers)

    Cash Only Mixed Payment Stock Only

    N = 588 225 231 132

    Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

    One is Payer (%) 64.889 *** 1 *** 40.125 * 0 * 38.393 0

    Diff.DivYield (%) 0.966 ** 0.345 ** 0.682 0.326 * 0.602 0.295

    Diff.Div/Book (%) 2.242 *** 1.062 *** 1.474 * 0.324 *** 0.662 0.165

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    38/46

    36

    Table 3. Determinants of the Payment Choice

    Cash Only includes deals where at least 90% of consideration is paid with cash. Stock Only includes dealswhere at least 90% of consideration is paid with acquirer stock. Mixed Payment includes deals financed with

    both stock and cash. Multinomial logit regressions are estimated for the payment method categories. The

    measures of differences in dividend policies include One is Payer,Diff.DivYield, andDiff.Div/Book, which are

    discussed in Section 2.2. All tests use the QML robust standard errors and z statistics which are reported in brackets. The symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level,

    respectively. Coefficients onRelative Size have been multiplied by 10,000 for presentation purposes. All of

    the control variables are discussed in Section 3.2.

    Cash Only Mixed Payment Cash Only

    Reference group : Stock Only Stock Only Mixed Payment

    Dividend Differential

    One is Payer 0.614**

    0.227 0.387

    [2.23] [0.96] [1.44]

    Diff.DivYield 33.308**

    17.753 15.555

    [2.15] [1.05] [1.01]

    Acquirer DivYield -30.697**

    -15.562 -15.135

    [-2.05] [-0.95] [-0.96]

    Diff.Div/Book 11.042**

    10.363 0.679

    [2.32] [0.87] [0.23]

    Acquirer Div/Book -6.152* 7.635 -1.483

    [-1.91] [0.72] [-0.46]

    Deal Characteristics

    Deal Premium 0.592** 0.538 0.546 0.066 0.042 0.075 0.526** 0.495 0.470

    [2.16] [1.25] [1.34] [0.25] [0.16] [0.29] [2.07] [1.35] [1.56]

    Ln (Deal Value) -0.296*** 0.249* 0.277* 0.198** 0.216** 0.200** -0.494*** -0.465 -0.477

    [-2.89] [1.76] [1.71] [2.13] [2.34] [2.15] [-5.00] [-1.48] [-1.49]

    Related Deal -0.112 -0.075 -0.105 0.471** 0.495*** 0.464** -0.583*** -0.570*** -0.569*

    [-0.54] [-0.36] [-0.51] [2.58] [2.69] [2.50] [-3.09] [-3.03] [-3.03]

    Hostile -0.158 -0.076 -0.131 0.131 0.153 0.105 -0.289 -0.228 -0.236

    [-0.18] [-0.09] [-0.15] [0.15] [0.18] [0.12] [-0.45] [-0.35] [-0.36]

    Tender Offer 1.752*** 1.706*** 1.712*** 0.346 0.337 0.333 1.406*** 1.369*** 1.378*

    [4.96] [4.95] [4.96] [0.96] [0.93] [0.91] [4.13] [4.11] [4.13]

    Acquirer Characteristics

    Insider Ownership -0.374 -0.478 -0.304 0.173 0.141 0.311 -0.546 -0.620 -0.615

    [-0.42] [-0.53] [-0.34] [0.21] [0.18] [0.37] [-0.62] [-0.70] [-0.70]

    Insider Ownership

    2

    -0.010 0.009 -0.060 -0.441 -0.440 -0.510 0.431 0.449 0.449[-0.03] [0.03] [-0.18] [-1.05] [-1.04] [-1.18] [1.13] [1.16] [1.15]

    Leverage 1.355*** 1.605*** 1.444*** 0.253 0.391 0.249 1.102** 1.214** 1.194*

    [2.71] [3.22] [2.84] [0.52] [0.81] [0.49] [2.13] [2.41] [2.35]

    Leverage -1.082 -1.258 -1.290 -1.456 -1.626 -1.708 0.374 0.368 0.418

    [-1.08] [-1.23] [-1.26] [-1.43] [-1.58] [-1.58] [0.41] [0.41] [0.46]

    PPE/Book 0.544 0.362 0.213 0.693** 0.613** 0.449 -0.149 -0.251 -0.236

    [1.59] [1.07] [0.62] [2.26] [2.03] [1.49] [-0.53] [-0.90] [-0.84]

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    39/46

    37

    Market/Book -0.029 -0.032 -0.056 0.069 0.068 0.046 -0.098 -0.100 -0.102

    [-0.31] [-0.34] [-0.58] [0.74] [0.72] [0.47] [-1.20] [-1.24] [-1.22]

    Cash/Deal value 0.022** 0.022** 0.020** 0.002 0.002 0.000 0.020 0.020 0.020

    [2.14] [2.19] [2.14] [0.11] [0.09] [0.00] [1.15] [1.17] [1.15]

    Prereturns -1.502***

    -1.587***

    -1.535***

    -0.582 -0.629 -0.580 -0.920**

    -0.958**

    -0.955*

    [-2.59] [-2.73] [-2.70] [-1.04] [-1.12] [-1.03] [-2.04] [-2.11] [-2.09]

    Target Characteristics

    Relative Size -0.923*

    -0.895*

    -0.858*

    -0.615***

    -0.611***

    -0.606***

    -0.308 -0.284 -0.252

    [-1.69] [-1.69] [-1.66] [-2.70] [-2.72] [-2.71] [-0.55] [-0.52] [-0.48]

    Insider Ownership -4.121**

    -0.004**

    -0.005***

    1.939 1.938 2.026 2.182 2.089 2.081

    [-2.58] [-2.55] [-2.60] [1.22] [1.21] [1.26] [1.48] [1.43] [1.43]

    Insider Ownership2

    4.769***

    0.047***

    0.049***

    -2.182 -2.227 -2.384 -2.587 -2.508 -2.507

    [2.69] [2.72] [-2.81] [-1.27] [-1.29] [-1.37] [-1.55] [-1.53] [-1.53]

    Institutional Ownership 2.835***

    2.631***

    2.658***

    0.314 0.241 0.232 2.522***

    2.390***

    2.426*

    [5.49] [5.14] [5.17] [0.66] [0.51] [0.48] [5.34] [5.17] [5.23]

    Leverage -1.886

    ***

    -1.630

    ***

    -1.610

    ***

    0.501 0.585 0.611 -2.388

    ***

    -2.215

    ***

    -2.221

    *

    [-3.97] [-3.55] [-3.50] [1.20] [1.38] [1.37] [-5.17] [-5.01] [-5.07]

    Market/Book 0.059 0.038 0.037 -0.173 -0.180 -0.188 0.232*

    0.219*

    0.225*

    [0.63] [0.44] [0.44] [-1.54] [-1.62] [-1.60] [1.84] [1.81] [1.83]

    Intercept 4.033** -3.205* -3.769** -4.553*** -4.890*** -4.568*** 8.586*** 8.095*** 8.336*

    [2.24] [-1.79] [-2.10] [-2.73] [-2.95] [-2.72] [5.02] [4.81] [4.97]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022

    Wald test 199.34 201.64 201.64

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Pseudo R2 0.1449 0.1443 0.1443

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    40/46

    38

    Table 4. Determinants of the Proportion of Cash Payment

    Two-limit Tobit regressions are estimated where the dependent variable is the proportion of cash

    payment, %Cash PMT. The measures of differences in dividend policies include One is Payer,Diff.DivYield, andDiff.Div/Book, which are discussed in Section 2.2. All tests use the QML robust standard

    errors and t statistics which are reported in brackets. The symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical

    significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively. Coefficients onRelative Size have been multipliedby 10,000 for presentation purposes. All of the control variables are discussed in Section 3.2.

    Dependent variable: %Cash PMT

    Dividend Differential

    One is Payer 0.298 [3.29]***

    Diff.DivYield 13.432 [2.32]**

    Acquirer DivYield -11.387 [-2.11]**

    Diff.Div/Book 1.668 [2.70]***

    Acquirer Div/Book -1.221 [-2.48]**

    Deal Characteristics

    Deal Premium 0.212 [2.01]** 0.232 [2.19]** 0.230 [2.16]**

    ln (Deal Value) 0.115 [1.97]** 0.056 [1.45] 0.049 [1.50]

    Related Deal -0.006 [-0.08] -0.028 [-0.35] -0.041 [-0.50]

    Hostile -0.332 [-1.10] -0.318 [-1.04] -0.319 [-1.04]

    Tender Offer 0.874 [6.37]*** 0.876 [6.36]*** 0.878 [6.36]***

    Acquirer Characteristics

    Insider Ownership -0.212 [-0.58] -0.319 [-0.87] -0.268 [-0.73]

    Insider Ownership2 -0.029 [-0.16] 0.024 [0.13] 0.007 [0.04]

    Leverage 0.714 [3.45]*** 0.820 [3.97]*** 0.794 [3.81]***

    Leverage -0.427 [-1.00] -0.492 [-1.14] -0.440 [-1.03]

    PPE/Book 0.053 [0.45] 0.078 [0.65] 0.089 [0.74]

    Market/Book -0.038 [-1.10] -0.037 [-1.07] -0.039 [-1.12]Cash/Deal value 0.008 [3.03]*** 0.009 [3.08]*** 0.009 [3.11]***

    Prereturns -0.679 [-3.13]*** -0.701 [-3.22]*** -0.690 [-3.16]***

    Target Characteristics

    Relative Size -0.144 [-1.18] -0.157 [-1.27] -0.151 [-1.23]

    Insider Ownership -1.557 [-2.53]** -0.016 [-2.59]*** -0.016 [-2.61]***

    Insider Ownership2 1.723 [2.55]** 0.171 [2.53]** 0.175 [2.59]***

    Institutional Ownership 1.112 [5.62]*** 1.168 [5.87]*** 1.172 [5.90]***

    Leverage -0.727 [-3.96]*** -0.758 [-4.12]*** -0.757 [-4.10]***

    Market/Book 0.047 [1.32] 0.051 [1.42] 0.051 [1.42]

    Intercept 1.896 [2.76]*** 1.833 [2.64]*** 1.902 [2.75]***

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022

    Wald test 199.99 193.44 190.29

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Pseudo R2 0.145 0.100 0.099

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    41/46

    39

    Table 5. Univariate Tests for Announcement Returns

    Announcement returns are measured as the cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) relative to the CRSP

    value-weighted market index over three day [-1, 1] and five day [-2, 2] horizons. The sample is divided intothree groups based on the method of payment. Tests for statistically significant differences are from t-tests

    between the Stock Only group and other groups. The symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical

    significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

    Cash Only Mixed Payment Stock Only Overall

    Acquirer CARs (%) [-1, 1] 0.41 *** -2.08 ** -3.06 -1.45

    [-2, 2] 0.57 *** -1.74 *** -3.59 -1.41

    Target CARs (%) [-1, 1] 30.71 *** 19.93 19.46 23.81

    [-2, 2] 31.37 *** 20.86 20.25 24.60

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    42/46

    40

    Table 6. Determinants of Announcement Returns

    This table reports the results of OLS regressions that test the determinants of takeover announcement returns, definedas the cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) over the three-day [-1, +1] and five-day [-2, +2] windows. The dependentvariable in Panel A is target CARs, while it is acquirer CARs in Panel B. The measures of differences in dividend

    policies include One is Payer,Diff.DivYield, andDiff.Div/Book, which are discussed in Section 2.2. The t-statistics arebased on White robust standard errors. The symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and

    10% level, respectively. Coefficients onRelative Size have been multiplied by 10,000 for presentation purposes. Allof the control variables are discussed in Section 3.2.

    Panel A. Target Announcement Returns

    Dependent Variables Target CAR [-1,1] Target CAR [-2,2]

    Dividend Differential

    Stock OnlyOne is Payer -0.026** -0.059**

    [-2.27] [-2.16]

    One is Payer -0.011 -0.003[-0.51] [-0.12]

    Stock OnlyDiff.DivYield -0.029** -0.045**

    [-2.02] [-2.35]

    Diff.DivYield -0.242

    -0.322[-0.84] [-1.08]

    Stock OnlyDiff.Div/Book -0.079 -0.509

    [-1.08] [-0.85]

    Diff.Div/Book -0.049 -0.041

    [-0.52] [-0.44]

    Stock Only -0.058*** -0.059*** -0.059*** -0.059*** -0.060*** -0.062***

    [-3.55] [-3.70] [-3.71] [-3.50] [-3.73] [-3.85]

    Acquirer Characteristicsln(Market Value) 0.019*** 0.019*** 0.019*** 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021***

    [4.08] [3.82] [3.85] [4.35] [4.20] [4.22]

    Market/Book 0.008 0.008 0.008 0.007 0.007 0.007

    [1.25] [1.25] [1.27] [1.15] [1.13] [1.13]

    Leverage -0.071 -0.073* -0.072* -0.086* -0.086* -0.086*

    [-1.64] [-1.67] [-1.65] [-1.96] [-1.95] [-1.94]

    PPE/Book -0.018 -0.020 -0.019 -0.018 -0.018 -0.018

    [-0.96] [-1.06] [-1.02] [-0.92] [-0.94] [-0.95]

    Target CharacteristicsRelative Size -0.044*** -0.043*** -0.043*** -0.044*** -0.044*** -0.045***

    [-3.19] [-3.12] [-3.14] [-3.16] [-3.15] [-3.23]

    Institutional Ownership -0.120*** -0.123*** -0.122*** -0.136*** -0.138*** -0.137***

    [-3.50] [-3.60] [-3.57] [-3.92] [-4.00] [-3.96]

    Leverage -0.140*** -0.137*** -0.138*** -0.134*** -0.133*** -0.134***

    [-4.14] [-4.10] [-4.12] [-3.95] [-3.96] [-3.99]

    Stock Return Volatility 0.150*** 0.146*** 0.146*** 0.149*** 0.147*** 0.148***

    [4.55] [4.51] [4.52] [4.56] [4.57] [4.59]

    Market/Book -0.009 -0.009 -0.009 -0.007 -0.007 -0.007

    [-1.47] [-1.50] [-1.49] [-1.15] [-1.16] [-1.15]Intercept 0.258*** 0.263*** 0.261*** 0.264*** 0.268*** 0.267***

    [5.87] [5.87] [5.90] [5.77] [5.74] [5.80]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022

    F test 8.34 11.57 8.42 8.95 12.37 9.11P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Adj. R2 0.117 0.116 0.116 0.123 0.123 0.228

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    43/46

    41

    Panel B. Acquirer Announcement Returns

    Dependent Variables Acquirer CAR [-1,1] Acquirer CAR [-2,2]

    Dividend Differential

    Stock OnlyOne is Payer -0.015** -0.019 *

    [-2.23] [-1.68]

    One is Payer 0.009 *** 0.016 **

    [2.66] [2.20]

    Stock OnlyDiff.DivYield -0.113 -0.168

    [-0.98] [-1.51]

    Diff.DivYield 0.126 0.041

    [1.22] [0.43]

    Stock OnlyDiff.Div/Book -0.008* -0.237 *

    [-1.73] [-1.81]

    Diff.Div/Book 0.060 0.045

    [1.70] * [1.32]

    Stock Only -0.015 ** -0.020 *** -0.019 *** -0.024 *** -0.029 *** -0.029 ***

    [-2.41] [-3.53] [-3.30] [-3.64] [-4.67] [-4.59]

    Acquirer Characteristics

    ln(Market Value) 0.002 * 0.003 ** 0.003 * 0.002 0.003 * 0.003 *

    [1.74] [1.97] [1.90] [1.07] [1.83] [1.73]

    Market/Book -0.003 -0.004 -0.004 * -0.005 ** -0.005 ** -0.005 **

    [-1.46] [-1.63] [-1.78] [-2.07] [-2.21] [-2.36]

    Leverage 0.009 0.010 0.009 0.007 0.008 0.007

    [0.65] [0.71] [0.62] [0.47] [0.55] [0.46]

    PPE/Book 0.009 * 0.011 * 0.010 * 0.012 * 0.014 ** 0.012 *

    [1.88] [1.93] [1.70] [1.77] [2.13] [1.91]

    Target Characteristics

    Relative Size -0.011 ** -0.013 *** -0.013 *** -0.010 * -0.012 ** -0.012 **

    [-2.54] [-3.07] [-3.00] [-1.91] [-2.23] [-2.28]

    Institutional Ownership -0.016 ** -0.015 ** -0.016 ** -0.020 * -0.019 * -0.019 *

    [1.98] [-2.47] [-2.49] [-1.81] [-1.75] [-1.73]

    Leverage 0.010 0.006 0.007 0.010 0.007 0.008

    [0.96] [0.60] [0.65] [0.92] [0.67] [0.70]

    Stock Return Volatility 0.011 * 0.014 ** 0.013 * 0.006 0.008 * 0.008

    [1.77] [2.34] [1.68] [1.24] [1.86] [1.45]

    Market/Book 0.002 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.003

    [0.96] [1.15] [1.14] [1.38] [1.58] [1.57]

    Intercept -0.035 * -0.041 ** -0.038 ** -0.026 -0.031 * -0.028

    [-1.90] [-2.21] [-2.11] [-1.42] [-1.67] [-1.56]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022

    F test 5.57 5.95 4.92 4.96 4.34 4.09

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Adj. R2 0.056 0.051 0.049 0.063 0.059 0.059

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    44/46

    42

    Table 7. Two-Stage Analysis of Announcement Returns

    This table reports the results of two-stage least squares (2SLS) regressions that test the determinants of takeover announcement returns

    of both target and acquiring firms. The two-step approach when the interaction term is an endogenous variable is discussed in Section2.3. In Panel A, One is Payeris used as the measure of dividend differential, whileDiff.DivYieldandDiff.Div/Bookare used in Panel

    B and Panel C, respectively. These measures are discussed in Section 2.2. The t-statistics based on robust standard errors are reported

    in parentheses below coefficient values. The symbols ***, **, and * represent statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level,

    respectively. Coefficients onRelative Size have been multiplied by 10,000 for presentation purposes. All of the control variables arediscussed in Section 3.2.

    Panel A. One is Payeras a Measure of Dividend Differential

    1st stage regressions 2nd stage regressions

    %Stock* Target CARs Acquirer CARsDependent Variables %Stock One is Payer [-1,1] [-2,2] [-1,1] [-2,2]

    Dividend Differential

    %StockOne is Payer -0.012** -0.033* -0.008* -0.007

    [-2.02] [-1.78] [-1.88] [-1.65]

    %Stock -0.133*** -0.138*** -0.060*** -0.070***

    [-3.20] [-3.26] [-3.96] [-4.45]One is Payer (1) -0.062* -0.084*** -0.020 -0.020 0.005 0.002

    [-1.71] [-3.35] [-0.57] [-0.59] [0.53] [0.19]

    Acquirer Characteristicsln(Market Value) -0.038*** -0.018*** 0.015*** 0.017*** 0.000 0.000

    [-5.42] [-4.41] [3.00] [3.34] [0.12] [-0.09]

    Market/Book -0.001 0.004 0.009 0.008 -0.003 -0.004*

    [-0.13] [0.76] [1.46] [1.31] [-1.28] [-1.82]Leverage -0.014 0.010 -0.064 -0.080* 0.011 0.010

    [-0.25] [0.43] [-1.49] [-1.83] [0.78] [0.65]

    PPE/Book -0.040 -0.011 -0.026 -0.025 0.005 0.008

    [-1.30] [-0.65] [-1.36] [-1.29] [0.85] [1.18]Target Characteristics

    Relative Size 0.135*** 0.042*** -0.025* -0.026* -0.002 -0.001

    [5.72] [3.25] [-1.67] [-1.68] [-0.45] [-0.14]Institutional Ownership -0.029 0.044* -0.129

    *** -0.146*** -0.023** -0.026**

    [-0.62] [1.68] [-3.71] [-4.17] [-2.18] [-2.39]Leverage 0.147*** 0.064*** -0.113*** -0.108*** 0.021* 0.023*

    [3.00] [2.70] [-3.27] [-3.12] [1.93] [1.92]

    Stock Return Volatility -0.159*** -0.014 0.135*** 0.134*** 0.003 -0.002[-3.25] [-0.59] [3.98] [3.99] [0.29] [-0.22]

    Market/Book 0.024*** -0.001 -0.008 -0.006 0.003 0.004

    [3.18] [-0.17] [-1.25] [-0.93] [1.18] [1.53]

    Instrumental VariablesAverage Acquirer 0.502*** 0.004

    Industry %Stock (2) [5.69] [0.40]

    Average Target 0.499*** -0.028**Industry %Stock (3) [5.66] [-2.19]

    (1) (2) -0.016 0.447***[-0.10] [3.40]

    (1) (3) 0.073 0.672***

    [0.50] [5.87]Intercept 0.260*** 0.082** 0.326*** 0.334*** -0.001 0.010

    [3.62] [2.56] [6.52] [6.47] [-0.04] [0.53]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022

    F test 88.34 29.29 8.50 9.13 5.80 5.52

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000Adj. R2 0.372 0.561 11.890 12.420 0.069 0.071

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    45/46

    43

    Panel B.Diff.DivYieldas a Measure of Dividend Differential

    1st stage regressions 2nd stage regressions

    %Stock* Target CARs Acquirer CARs

    Dependent Variables %Stock Diff.DivYield [-1,1] [-2,2] [-1,1] [-2,2]

    Dividends Differences

    %StockDiff.DivYield -0.327** -0.260** -0.007 -0.016

    [-2.31] [-2.08] [-1.32] [-1.07]

    %Stock -0.129*** -0.130*** -0.062*** -0.071***

    [-3.42] [-3.40] [-4.94] [-5.47]

    Diff.DivYield (1) -0.514 -0.157*** -0.126 -0.205 0.092 -0.024

    [-0.69] [-4.58] [-0.36] [-0.56] [0.90] [-0.21]

    Acquirer Characteristics

    ln(Market Value) -0.041*** 0.000** 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.001 0.000

    [-6.03] [-2.15] [2.71] [3.06] [0.29] [-0.02]

    Market/Book -0.001 0.000 0.009 0.008 -0.003 -0.004*

    [-0.11] [1.11] [1.45] [1.32] [-1.27] [-1.81]

    Leverage -0.019 -0.001 -0.069 -0.082* 0.012 0.010

    [-0.32] [-0.63] [-1.59] [-1.86] [0.84] [0.71]

    PPE/Book -0.044 0.000 -0.030 -0.028 0.006 0.008

    [-1.45] [0.10] [-1.53] [-1.40] [1.01] [1.30]

    Target Characteristics

    Relative Size 0.140*** 0.001*** -0.023 -0.024 -0.003 -0.001

    [5.80] [2.72] [-1.57] [-1.61] [-0.52] [-0.16]

    Institutional Ownership -0.035*** -0.001 -0.133*** -0.148*** -0.022** -0.026**

    [-2.75] [-1.32] [-3.84] [-4.24] [-2.12] [-2.36]

    Leverage 0.154*** 0.000 -0.110*** -0.106*** 0.020* 0.022*

    [3.12] [-0.41] [-3.18] [-3.05] [1.85] [1.90]

    Stock Return Volatility -0.171*** 0.000 0.129*** 0.130*** 0.004 -0.001

    [-3.56] [-0.18] [3.82] [3.90] [0.42] [-0.15]

    Market/Book 0.024*** 0.000 -0.008 -0.007 0.003 0.004

    [3.08] [-0.69] [-1.33] [-1.01] [1.25] [1.59]

    Instrumental Variables

    Average Acquirer 0.516*** -0.001

    Industry %Stock (2) [6.80] [-0.61]

    Average Target 0.511*** -0.001

    Industry %Stock (3) [6.78] [-1.48]

    (1) (2) -2.623 0.466**

    [-0.98] [2.56]

    (1) (3) 2.525 1.044***

    [1.02] [3.18]

    Intercept 0.266*** 0.002** 0.333*** 0.338*** -0.002 0.009

    [3.71] [2.54] [6.51] [6.42] [-0.12] [0.46]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022

    F test 84.17 19.74 9.02 9.70 6.48 5.57

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Adj. R2 0.371 0.857 0.118 0.125 0.069 0.070

  • 8/3/2019 Dividend Policy and the Method of Payment

    46/46

    Panel C.Diff.Div/Bookas a Measure of Dividend Differential

    1st stage regressions 2nd stage regressions

    %Stock* Target CARs Acquirer CARs

    Dependent Variables %Stock Diff.Div/Book [-1,1] [-2,2] [-1,1] [-2,2]Dividend Differential

    %StockDiff.Div/Book -0.365 -0.286 -0.001 -0.006

    [-1.40] [-1.22] [-1.01] [-1.35]

    %Stock -0.128*** -0.130*** -0.061*** -0.070***

    [-3.42] [-3.42] [-4.79] [-5.34]

    Diff.Div/Book (1) 0.015 0.028 0.020 0.016 0.033 0.003

    [0.05] [0.28] [0.07] [0.06] [0.50] [0.04]

    Acquirer Characteristics

    ln(Market Value) -0.041*** 0.000*** 0.014*** 0.016*** 0.000 0.000

    [-5.96] [-2.62] [2.76] [3.11] [0.25] [-0.04]

    Market/Book 0.000 0.000 0.009 0.009 -0.003 -0.004*

    [0.06] [-0.90] [1.51] [1.37] [-1.35] [-1.86]

    Leverage -0.017 -0.002 -0.068 -0.082* 0.011 0.010

    [-0.30] [-1.10] [-1.55] [-1.83] [0.79] [0.66]

    PPE/Book -0.042 0.000 -0.028 -0.027 0.005 0.008

    [-1.33] [-0.25] [-1.43] [-1.33] [0.90] [1.21]

    Target Characteristics

    Relative Size 0.139*** 0.002*** -0.023 -0.024 -0.002 -0.001

    [5.84] [3.33] [-1.55] [-1.59] [-0.50] [-0.17]

    Institutional Ownership -0.033 0.000 -0.132*** -0.147*** -0.022** -0.026**

    [-0.72] [-0.08] [-3.82] [-4.22] [-2.14] [-2.36]

    Leverage 0.153*** 0.003** -0.110*** -0.106*** 0.020* 0.022*

    [3.11] [2.08] [-3.18] [-3.05] [1.88] [1.91]

    Stock Return Volatility -0.169*** -0.002** 0.129*** 0.130*** 0.004 -0.001

    [-3.51] [-2.05] [3.83] [3.91] [0.40] [-0.15]Market/Book 0.024*** 0.000 -0.008 -0.007 0.003 0.004

    [3.07] [-0.45] [-1.34] [-1.01] [1.24] [1.59]

    Instrumental Variables

    Average Acquirer 0.542*** 0.006**

    Industry %Stock (2) [6.62] [2.01]

    Average Target 0.490*** -0.005*

    Industry %Stock (3) [5.96] [-1.78]

    (1) (2) -3.144 0.226***

    [-1.24] [2.67]

    (1) (3) 2.488 1.016***

    [1.08] [3.63]

    Intercept 0.255*** 0.003 0.330*** 0.334*** -0.001 0.010

    [3.59] [1.10] [6.50] [6.42] [-0.05] [0.50]

    No. observations 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022 1,022

    F test 88.41 106.26 8.60 9.27 5.61 5.26

    P-value 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

    Adj. R2 0.372 0.819 0.119 0.124 0.068 0.070