ec202 lectures xvii & xviii francesco navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/lecture_17_18.pdfnava (lse)...

24
Externalities EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Nava London School of Economics February 2011 Nava (LSE) EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 1 / 24

Upload: others

Post on 24-Jan-2021

10 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

ExternalitiesEC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII

Francesco Nava

London School of Economics

February 2011

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 1 / 24

Page 2: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Summary

A common cause of Market Failures are Externalities:

1 Production ExternalitiesEg: Pollution (negative) & Research (positive)

2 Consumption ExternalitiesEg: Tobacco (negative) & Deodorant (positive)

Competitive Outcome is not Pareto Optimal

Solutions to the Problem

Taxes & Subsidies

Private Solutions: Reorganization

Private Solutions: Pseudo-Markets

Coase Theorem (Take 1)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 2 / 24

Page 3: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Production & Consumption Externalities

Definition (Externality)There is an externality when an agent’s actions directly influence thechoice possibilities (production set or consumption set) of another agent.

Definition (Consumption Exernality)There is a consumption externality when an agent’s actions directlyinfluence the consumption set of another agent.

Definition (Production Exernality)There is a production externality when an agent’s actions directlyinfluence the production set of another agent.

Classical example by Meade: beekeeper and nearby orchard, both increasethe other agent’s productivity and production possibilities.

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 3 / 24

Page 4: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Positive & Negative Externalities

Definition (Positive Exernality)There is a positive externality when an agent’s actions increase thechoice possibilities of another agent.

Definition (Negative Exernality)There is a negative externality when an agent’s actions decrease thechoice possibilities of another agent.

Common causes of externalities are:

Networking Effects (investment in assets that facilitate cooperation)

Civic Action (good norms of behavior that benefit others)

Undefined Ownership of Resources (excessive use of resources)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 4 / 24

Page 5: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

A Simple Model with Externalities I

Topic is discussed with a simple example of production externalities:

Two goods {1, 2}, two firms {a, b} and one consumer cGood 1 is polluting while good 2 is not

Firm a is situated on river A

Consumer c is situated on river B

Firm b is situated after the confluence of the two rivers

Firm a Consumer

Firm b

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 5 / 24

Page 6: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

A Simple Model with Externalities II

Firm a produces good 1 using good 2:

y1 = f (xa2 )

Consumer c has preferences for the two goods defined by:

U(xc1 , xc2 )

Firm b produces good 2 using good 1:

y2 = g(xb1 , y1, xc1 )

its output decreases with river pollution which depends on thequantity of good 1 produced and consumed upstream

Let (e1, e2) denote the initial resources of the economy

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 6 / 24

Page 7: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Pareto Optimum I

The Pareto Optima of this economy are solutions of the following program:

maxx c1 ,x

c2 ,y1,y2,x

b1 ,x

a2

U(xc1 , xc2 ) subject to

xc1 + xb1 ≤ e1 + y1 (λ1)

xc2 + xa2 ≤ e2 + y2 (λ2)

y1 ≤ f (xa2 ) (µ1)y2 ≤ g(xb1 , y1, xc1 ) (µ2)

As production constraints bind this corresponds to:

maxx c1 ,x

c2 ,x

b1 ,x

a2

U(xc1 , xc2 ) subject to

xc1 + xb1 ≤ e1 + f (xa2 ) (λ1)

xc2 + xa2 ≤ e2 + g(xb1 , f (xa2 ), xc1 ) (λ2)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 7 / 24

Page 8: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Pareto Optimum II

The Pareto Optima of this economy are solutions of:

maxx c1 ,x

c2 ,x

b1 ,x

a2

U(xc1 , xc2 ) subject to

e1 + f (xa2 )− xc1 − xb1 ≥ 0 [λ1]

e2 + g(xb1 , f (xa2 ), x

c1 )− xc2 − xa2 ≥ 0 [λ2]

Taking first order conditions we get that:

U1 − λ1 + λ2g3 = 0 [xc1 ]

U2 − λ2 = 0 [xc2 ]

λ2g1 − λ1 = 0 [xb1 ]

λ1f1 − λ2 + λ2f1g2 = 0 [xa2 ]

Solving the system of FOC requires:

U1U2+ g3 = g1 =

1f1− g2

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 8 / 24

Page 9: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Pareto Optimum III

Thus effi ciency in this economy requires:

U1U2+ g3 = g1 =

1f1− g2 (PO)

What does the PO condition require?

The LHS is the Social MRS of consumer cIt accounts for the externality of consuming xc1 units of good 1

The RHS is the Social MRT of firm a

It accounts for the externality of producing y1 units of good 1

The central term is simply the MRT of firm b

If externalities are present, PO requires MRS and MRT to be adjusted bytheir social value to account for the external effects of each agent’sdecisions have on the rest of the economy (Pigou 1920)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 9 / 24

Page 10: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Competitive Equilibrium I

Optimality in a competitive equilibrium agents requires:

U1U2= g1 =

1f1

(CE)

What does the CE condition require?

The LHS is the Private MRS of consumer cIt doesn’t account for the externality of consuming xc1(over-consumption)

The RHS is the Private MRT of firm a

It doesn’t account for the externality of producing y1(over-production)

The central term is the Private MRT of firm b

If externalities are present, CE is not PO because agents only consider fortheir private MRS and MRT and neglect the social consequences of theirbehavior

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 10 / 24

Page 11: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Competitive Equilibrium II

CE condition can be derived by solving the problems of the 3 players:

maxx b1

p2g(xb1 , y1, xc1 )− p1xb1

⇒ p2g1 = p1

maxx a2

p1f (xa2 )− p2xa2⇒ p1f1 = p2

maxx c1 ,x

c2

U(xc1 , xc2 ) st p1x

c1 + p2x

c2 < y

⇒ U1U2=p1p2

Collecting the three FOC, one gets the desired condition:U1U2= g1 =

1f1

(CE)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 11 / 24

Page 12: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Externalities: Remedies

Several remedies have been proposed to fix Market Failures (CE 6= PO)due to to externalities:

Quotas

Subsidies for Depollution

Rights to Pollute

Pigovian Taxes

Integration of Firms

Compensation Mechanisms

We say that a mechanism internalizes an externality if it implements thePareto Optimum in the economy (ie if CE = PO)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 12 / 24

Page 13: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Quotas

Quotas are the simplest way to implement PO consumption of good 1:

Compute PO consumption levels of good 1 (xc1 , y1)

Forbid firm a from producing more than y1

Forbid consumer c from consuming more than xc1

Problems with quotas are:

Computing PO requires a detailed knowledge of the economy

It’s an authoritarian solution

It’s a commonly used solution (though in a less brutal form), eg:

Limiting quantities of pollutants emitted by firms and consumers

Limits in CO2 emissions of automobiles

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 13 / 24

Page 14: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Subsidies for Depollution I

Another way to relax the externality is to subsidize firm for depollution:

Assume that firm a can invest z2 units of good 2 in depollution

If so, its pollution drops from y1 to y1 − d(z2)The resource constraint for good 2 consumption becomes:

xc2 + xa2 + z2 ≤ e2 + y2

The production constraint for firm b becomes:

y2 ≤ g(xb1 , y1 − d(z2), xc1 )

In which case the PO conditions become

U1U2+ g3 = g1 =

1f1− g2 =

1f1+1d1

(PO)

since FOC with respect to PO z2 imply that −g2d1(z2) = 1Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 14 / 24

Page 15: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Subsidies for Depollution II

Consider the CE of this economy if the government subsidizes depollution:

Let s(z2) denote the subsidy of the government

With the subsidies in place the program of firm a becomes:

maxx a2 ,z2

p1f (xa2 ) + s(z2)− p2(xa2 + z2)

While the problem of firm b becomes:

maxx b1p2g(xb1 , y1 − d(z2), xc1 )− p1xb1

Government induces the socially optimal level of depollution bychoosing s(·) so that s1(z2) = p2However, the CE for this economy still requires:

U1U2= g1 =

1f1

and is therefore not PONava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24

Page 16: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Rights to Pollute I

This is the preferred solution by economist (but not by policy makers):

In particular consider the following remedy:

Firm b (pollutee) sells rights to polluteto firm a and consumer c (the polluters)

It receives a price r for any pollution right it sells to consumer c

It receives a price q for any pollution right it sells to firm a

If so, the solution to consumer c’s problem becomes:

U1U2=p1p2+rp2

While the solution to firm a’s problem becomes:

1f1=p1p2− qp2

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 16 / 24

Page 17: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Rights to Pollute II

The problem of firm b is more complex as it needs to decide:

on how much output to produce

on how many pollution rights to sell to the polluter

In particular firm b solves the following program:

maxx b1 ,y1,x

c1

p2g(xb1 , y1, xc1 )− p1xb1 + rxc1 + qy1

Optimality conditions for this program require:

g1 =p1p2

& − g2 =qp2

& − g3 =rp2

Solving FOC for all three players implies effi ciency since:

U1U2+ g3 = g1 =

1f1− g2

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 17 / 24

Page 18: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Rights to Pollute III

The creation of markets for rights to pollute therefore:

implements the Pareto Optimum

requires less information than quotas as the government does notneed to know preferences and technologies of all individuals and firms

Further consideration:

Not all individuals pay the same price for the same right to polluteIn our example q = r only if g(xb1 , y1, x

c1 ) = G (x

b1 , y1 + x

c1 )

In our example there is only one supplier and buyer in each openpollution market. To avoid strategic considerations it would be betterif there were more.

We have discussed a "polluters pays" scheme.Similar arguments work if "depollution rights" markets are openedwhere pollutees buy from polluters. Of course the distribution ofequilibrium utilities would differ.

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 18 / 24

Page 19: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Pigovian Taxes

A different way to solve the externality problem is through taxes:

One could tax production of good 1 at rate T

One could tax consumption of good 1 at rate t

Where T = q and t = r (from the previous remedy)

Such tax rates would:

solve the externality problem since PO = CE

require a lot of information to be computed exactly

These tax levels are often called Pigovian taxes in honor of Pigou who firstwrote about them in 1928.

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 19 / 24

Page 20: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Integration of Firms

For convenience assume that consumer c does not pollute: g3 = 0.

Another remedy to the externality problem is to have both firms merge.

In which case the merged firm solves the following problem:

maxx b1 ,x

a2

p1f (xa2 ) + p2g(xb1 , f (x

a2 ))− p1xb1 − p2xa2

The solution to this problem implies PO since FOC require:

p1p2= g1 =

1f1− g2

This is not the preferred solution since:

It disregards considerations of market powerBig firms usually extract higher rents

It disregards property rightsFirms may prefer not to merge

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 20 / 24

Page 21: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

A Compensation Mechanism

Compensating Mechanisms have been designed to internalize externalitieswhenever:

the firms and consumers know all fundamentals of the economy

while the government does not

Such mechanism guarantee that the government can:

elicit the Pigovian tax rates from producers and consumers

set such effective tax rates so that PO = CE

The limitations to this approach (suggested in Varian 1994) are that:

it requires a lot of knowledge on the part of consumers and producers

it does no better than markets for pollution rights

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 21 / 24

Page 22: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Coase Theorem I

In a seminal paper of 1960, Coase doubted the necessity of anygovernment intervention in presence of externalities.

His argument proceeded as follows:

Let b(q) denote the benefit to the polluter of q units of pollution

Let c(q) denote the cost to the pollutee of q units of pollution

Assume that b′ > 0, b′′ < 0, c ′ > 0, c ′′ > 0

Effi cient pollution q∗ would require b′(q∗) = c ′(q∗)

If pollution q0 is ineffi cient it must be that b′(q0) < c ′(q0)

If so, the pollutee can ask the polluter:1 to reduce pollution by some small number ε to q0 − ε2 in exchange of a transfer tε where t ∈ (b′(q0), c ′(q0))

Such trade benefits the polluter since t > b′(q0)

Such trade also benefits the pollutee since t < c ′(q0)

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 22 / 24

Page 23: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Coase Theorem II

The previous argument can be repeated so long as b′ < c ′

Moreover a similar argument works for the case in which b′ > c ′

Thus Coase concluded that the following result had to hold:

TheoremIf property rights are clearly defined and transaction costs are negligible,the parties affected by an externality succeed in eliminating anyineffi ciency through the simple recourse of negotiation.

The two essential ingredients for his claim are:

1 Negligible transaction costs

2 Well defined property rights

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 23 / 24

Page 24: EC202 Lectures XVII & XVIII Francesco Navadarp.lse.ac.uk/pdf/ec202/Lecture_17_18.pdfNava (LSE) EC202 ŒLectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 15 / 24. Rights to Pollute I This is the preferred

Coase Theorem III

Limitations of the Coase Theorem are due:

1 Non-negligible transaction costsIn fact the result fails:

1 If a lawyer is needed and if he charges more than ε(c ′ − b′)2 If information about costs and benefits is private [Myerson et al 1983]

2 Well defined property rightsIn fact the result fails when rights are not well defined:

1 As with open water fishing2 As for pollution

But several examples have been reported in which such bargaining occurs

Cheung 1973 shows that in US arrangement with side payments betweenbeekeepers and orchards are common.

Nava (LSE) EC202 — Lectures XVII & XVIII Feb 2011 24 / 24