e.c.l.r. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 page 1 e.c.l.r. 2012, 33(9...

27
E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 European Competition Law Review 2012 Software predatory pricing and competition law - assessing below-cost prices Qiang Yu © 2013 Sweet & Maxwell and its Contributors Subject: Competition law. Other Related Subject: Information technology Keywords: Abuse of dominant position; Predatory pricing; Software *413 Part I: Introduction Low prices are both a goal of competition laws and a symbol of healthy market competition. Through price competition, every competitor cuts the prices of its products to attract consumers. According to the perfect competition model, in a fully competitive market, the competitive price is close to cost, and consumer wel- fare is greatly enhanced by this low price. To attract more consumers, a supplier with cost advantages can offer a price close to the product's cost and lower than that of other suppliers. This “below-cost” price may eliminate other competitors and create a monopoly of the market. This process is a legitimate way of elimin- ating competitors and monopolising the market. Some suppliers may artificially offer below-cost prices to eliminate their competitors, even when they do not in fact have a cost advantage. However this type of Predatory Pricing (PP) practice is prohibited by competi- tion law. Under modern competition law, in order for a practice to constitute PP, the predator must (1) offer a price that is below a certain cost standard; and (2) maintain a monopoly position after eliminating its com- petitors. The first condition requires considerable market power to eliminate competitors and can generally be fulfilled by a dominant firm. The second condition requires a market barrier high enough to prevent the entry of other suppliers. These conditions are rarely satisfied simultaneously. Courts hold: “[by] a consensus among commentators … PP schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful”.1 Scholars argue that strong policy against PP will in fact discourage suppliers from offering low prices, which significantly af- fects vigorous price competition at the expense of the consumer. The software market is a unique market in that pricing strategies within the market often satisfy all the con- ditions of PP. In practice, extremely low prices are offered within the software market. Software is a net- work economy that offers a first-mover advantage, where large networks can easily form and where all com- petition aims to establish a dominant network. In most instances, the market is monopolised by a single firm (i.e. Microsoft's Windows computer operating system). The durable nature of software as a good and the presence of network effects in the market may lead to the establishment of a dominant firm and high entry barriers. Under such conditions, competing firms may have to offer software at extremely low prices to enter the market. For example, firms may offer free software to attract consumers and lock them into a competitor network. This article examines the characteristics of software and the software market and finds that software pricing practices challenge traditional competition rules with respect to PP. The software market offers an environ- E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 (Cite as: ) © 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Upload: others

Post on 16-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429

European Competition Law Review

2012

Software predatory pricing and competition law - assessing below-cost prices

Qiang Yu

© 2013 Sweet & Maxwell and its Contributors

Subject: Competition law. Other Related Subject: Information technology

Keywords: Abuse of dominant position; Predatory pricing; Software

*413 Part I: Introduction

Low prices are both a goal of competition laws and a symbol of healthy market competition. Through pricecompetition, every competitor cuts the prices of its products to attract consumers. According to the perfectcompetition model, in a fully competitive market, the competitive price is close to cost, and consumer wel-fare is greatly enhanced by this low price. To attract more consumers, a supplier with cost advantages canoffer a price close to the product's cost and lower than that of other suppliers. This “below-cost” price mayeliminate other competitors and create a monopoly of the market. This process is a legitimate way of elimin-ating competitors and monopolising the market.

Some suppliers may artificially offer below-cost prices to eliminate their competitors, even when they do notin fact have a cost advantage. However this type of Predatory Pricing (PP) practice is prohibited by competi-tion law. Under modern competition law, in order for a practice to constitute PP, the predator must (1) offera price that is below a certain cost standard; and (2) maintain a monopoly position after eliminating its com-petitors. The first condition requires considerable market power to eliminate competitors and can generallybe fulfilled by a dominant firm. The second condition requires a market barrier high enough to prevent theentry of other suppliers. These conditions are rarely satisfied simultaneously. Courts hold: “[by] a consensusamong commentators … PP schemes are rarely tried, and even more rarely successful”.1 Scholars argue thatstrong policy against PP will in fact discourage suppliers from offering low prices, which significantly af-fects vigorous price competition at the expense of the consumer.

The software market is a unique market in that pricing strategies within the market often satisfy all the con-ditions of PP. In practice, extremely low prices are offered within the software market. Software is a net-work economy that offers a first-mover advantage, where large networks can easily form and where all com-petition aims to establish a dominant network. In most instances, the market is monopolised by a single firm(i.e. Microsoft's Windows computer operating system). The durable nature of software as a good and thepresence of network effects in the market may lead to the establishment of a dominant firm and high entrybarriers. Under such conditions, competing firms may have to offer software at extremely low prices to enterthe market. For example, firms may offer free software to attract consumers and lock them into a competitornetwork.

This article examines the characteristics of software and the software market and finds that software pricingpractices challenge traditional competition rules with respect to PP. The software market offers an environ-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 2: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

ment that is susceptible to PP by market players. Moreover, in the software industry, the market conditionsand function of the PP strategy differ from those in the traditional market. As a consequence, competitionpolicies against PP may need to be re-evaluated. Furthermore, in real market operations, many below-costprices either are the result of efficiency or lead to efficiency. Distinguish efficiency-justified low prices fromPP is difficult. Analysing several below-cost pricing strategies, including both those found in software pack-ages and those in other product markets, this paper identifies some points that are useful in distinguishingjustified low pricing from PP and offers an approach for analysing possible PP in the software market.

Part 2 of this article reviews the general theoretical and legal background of PP. Part 3 describes the condi-tions of the software market that influenced pricing practices and that must be considered in competitionanalysis. Part 4 examines below-cost prices in software sales. In analysing PP, the paper suggests an ap-proach for analysing unreasonable below-cost pricing in the software market. Part 5 concludes the paper.

Part II: Predatory pricing and market competition: theoretical and legal fundamentals

PP is a market practice that differs depending on whether it is implemented as a merger or a conspiracy,which is the greatest competition concern among market operators. PP achieves competition aims not by dir-ectly affecting competitors but rather by influencing consumers. Thus, firms may affect competitors throughconsumer choice. The principles of these indirect effects on competition and the regulation of PP are offeredherein.

*414 Predatory pricing

Generally, PP refers to the practice of offering products at loss-generating prices to customers until the com-petitors either are driven out of the market or agree to cooperate. After successfully implementing the PPstrategy, the predator can then charge monopoly prices to maximise its profits. A loss-generating price isnormally a price that is below the product's certain test of cost. Normally, at this price, the predator will real-ise an increase in negative profit with the expanding allocation of its product.

As PP is similar to competitive low pricing or to competitive price cuts, it is difficult for scholars and judgesto distinguish between them:

“[T]he mechanism by which a firm engages in predatory pricing--lowering prices--is the same mechanismby which a firm stimulates competition; because ‘cutting prices in order to increase business often is thevery essence of competition ….”2

As competition is a mechanism for taking customers away from competitors, it is rational for market parti-cipants to lower their prices to drive competitors out of the market. Additionally, “price cutting, even by adominant firm, is frequently innocent and desirable”.3 Nevertheless, there are two established elements thatcan be used to distinguish PP from competitive low pricing: a loss-generating price and the consequentmonopoly pricing. With respect to monopoly pricing, it is insufficient to independently classify the pricingas predatory, as it can be experienced even if competitors are excluded from the profit-gaining price. Simil-arly, it is insufficient to label a pricing strategy as predatory only on the basis that the price is loss-generating. Furthermore, in practice, litigation often intervenes before monopoly pricing occurs. As a result,in order for pricing to be predatory, the price must be loss generating and the possibility of monopoly pri-cing must exists.

There are arguments regarding the occurrence of PP in the second half of the past century. Some economistshave examined PP with economic technology and determined that it is not rational for the predator to engagein price predation. Relying on some economic analyses and empirical observations, these economists haveconcluded that price predation is costly and is unlikely to succeed because if a firm attempts to gain or main-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 2

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 3: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

tain a monopoly position, it must suffer a greater loss than the targeted firms. In contrast, acquiring or con-spiring strategies may be less costly. Furthermore, even if the below-cost strategy succeeds, it may not suc-ceed in preventing new companies from entering the market during the loss recoup period. Therefore, it isunlikely that this strategy will be adopted in practice.4 Such arguments have influenced court decisions. Forexample, in Matsushita5 a predatory pricing conspiracy is by nature speculative. Any agreement to price be-low the competitive level requires the conspirators to forgo profits that free competition would offer them.The forgone profits may be considered an investment in the future. For the investment to be rational, theconspirators must have a reasonable expectation of recovering--in the form of later monopoly profits--morethan the losses suffered.6

After signaling theories were introduced to competition analysis, PP was considered a rational behaviour inthe context of economic analysis. According to the fame predation doctrine, in markets with asymmetric in-formation, signaling strategies may enable a predator to deliver negative information (e.g. the predator has afinancial or cost advantage) to frustrate competitors even if the information is artificial.7 For those whodoubted whether predation fame affects competitors, the deep pocket doctrine was convincing. Tesler, whoanalysed several economic theories, finds that firms that have substantial reserves can remove competitorseven if their acquisition or conspiracy negotiations were unsuccessful:

“The critical role of reserves in this argument should be noted. To present a credible threat the potentialmonopolist needs more reserves than the firm it seeks to remove from competition”.8

Additionally:

“[t]here is some evidence that young firms are more vulnerable to bankruptcy than are older, more estab-lished firms. With asymmetric information, however, an equilibrium strategy for the low-cost entrant is tofinance with debt and thereby separate himself from the high-cost type. This engenders a predatory responseby the incumbent”.9

*415 After these theoretical analyses, affirmative cases began to emerge both in the European Union and theUnited States,10 and most economists now accept that PP occurs if certain market conditions are satisfied.

Market conditions for a successful implementation

As previously discussed, combination of a dominant market power or the superior market position and ahigh barrier for entry make it rational for a market player to engage in PP practices. These two conditions to-gether constitute the necessary condition for a successful PP strategy.

Market power is a prerequisite for eliminating competitors. As an exclusionary practice, the aim of PP is totake consumers away from competitors. To successfully attract these consumers, the firm must offersomething the competitor cannot or does not offer. Low prices are usually sufficient for a consumer toswitch loyalties. However, this situation is quite different from another type of exclusivity practice called ty-ing, where consumer cooperation is not required because the consumer is forced to switch.11 PP involvesthe adoption of lower prices to persuade consumers to switch. Following this mechanism, a competitiveprice will not deter or be exclusive to competitors with equal or more efficiency. According to many studies,a competitive price is close to cost.12 Thus, an eliminating price must be below a competitive price (i.e. itmust be below cost). If suppliers supply products at a below-cost price, competitors may respond by exitingthe market or by offering a defensive below-cost price. However, if competitors compete with the below-cost price, they will eventually collapse. These circumstances lead to the deep pocket doctrine,13 whichstates that the competitor with the greatest market power will eventually witness the exit of its competitorsfrom the market, after which the standing competitor begins the process of recouping the losses incurredduring the below-cost battle.

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 3

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 4: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

Consistent with the above description, PP is considered as a practice that abuses a dominant market posi-tion,14 as only dominant market participants possess the deep pockets or the staying power needed to standuntil the competitors exit. It is noteworthy that market power is not limited to financial advantages, as it var-ies among different markets. For instance, in markets with network effects, market power can result fromowning a larger network. However, although market power varies in form, it can easily be observed via mar-ket share.

A market entry barrier high enough to stop market entry is needed as a market condition to guarantee that apredator will recoup its losses and enjoy monopoly pricing. After successfully eliminating its competitors,the predator will offer its product at a price higher than the previous competitive price. The high price can,in turn, create a profit space for rational entrants. If the entry barrier is not high enough, new entrants willcompete with the predator, and the price will soon became a competitive one. This process will hinder thepredator's predatory behaviour, as the predator cannot recoup the losses and enjoy the monopoly price. Thus,only if the entry barriers are high enough to deter all entrants can the two-stage strategy succeed.

Laws targeting predatory pricing

In the first step of a PP strategy, the predator lowers its price, and competitors soon follow. This initial stepeliminates the less efficient competitors and benefits consumers in the short term. Eventually, however eventhe competitors with equal or more efficiency will be driven out of the relevant market. This outcome, inturn, is detrimental to competition and leads to long-term consumer loss. In the second step, the predator in-creases the price to a monopoly level, which results in consumer welfare loss. In light of these harms createdby illegally achieving and abusing monopoly power, laws are made to prevent PP efforts from reachingmonopoly power and reducing competition.

Passed in 1890, the Sherman Act condemns PP as both an abuse of monopoly power and an illegal means ofachieving monopoly power. If the intent is to achieve monopoly power, PP is prohibited and considered anoffense, which “Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize … shall be deemed guilty ofa felony”.15 Passed in 1914, the Clayton Act16 was designed to prohibit the selective reduction of prices toeliminate competitors. According to the Clayton Act, primary-line discrimination using predatory price-cutting to serve the purpose of elimination. In other words, discriminatory suppliers use selective below-costpricing to drive competitors away. In fact, the European Union directly *416 forbids PP as an abuse of dom-inant market position: “Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position … shall be prohib-ited”.17

As considerable market power is needed to implement a PP strategy, regulators face the problem of determ-ining the threshold of market power for PP practices. In preventing potential market participants fromachieving monopoly power through PP, most US courts agree that there is a minimum market sharethreshold required for market participants to achieve monopoly power18 :

“While the market share necessary to show an attempt to monopolize is difficult to quantify, a leading texthas offered a general scale that a court may cautiously apply taking into consideration the proof offered forthe other two elements: (1) claims of less than 30% market shares should presumptively be rejected; (2)claims involving between 30% and 50% shares should usually be rejected, except when conduct is verylikely to achieve monopoly or when conduct is invidious, but not so much so as to make the defendant per seliable; (3) claims involving greater than 50% share should be treated as attempts at monopolization when theother elements for attempted monopolization are also satisfied.”19

The European Union has adopted a similar market share-based standard:

“It is very likely that very high markets shares, which have been held for some time, indicate a dominant po-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 4

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 5: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

sition. This would be the case where an undertaking holds 50% or more of the market, provided that rivalshold a much smaller share of the market. In the case of lower market shares, dominance is more likely to befound in the market share range of 40% to 50% than below 40%, although also undertakings with marketshares below 40% could be considered to be in a dominant position. However, undertakings with marketshares of no more than 25% are not likely to enjoy a (single) dominant position on the market concerned.20But, A substantial market share as evidence of the existence of a dominant position is not a constant factorand its importance varies from market to market according to the structure of these markets, especially as faras production, supply and demand are concerned.”21

Although statutes generally prohibit PP, they do not provide specific guidelines on enforcement. Therefore,courts have great flexibility in determining that pricing is predatory, and a significant body of case law onPP exists.

The case law on standards for determining PP is characterised by three periods: the intent period, the costperiod and the recoup period. In the first period, which lasted from the passage of the Sherman Act to theyear 1975, courts relied on proof of intent to monopolise or exclude competitors when identifying PP. Thisstandard of intent is evident in the case law. In Standard Oil:

“[t]he combination of the stocks of the various corporations trading in petroleum and its products in thehands of a holding company, with the intent to exclude others from the trade, and thus centralise in the com-bination the perpetual control of the movement of these commodities in the channels of interstate and for-eign commerce, constitutes a violation of the prohibitions of Act July 2, 1890 (Sherman Antitrust Act)”.22

In Utah pie:

“a reasonable probability may be inferred that its willful misconduct may substantially lessen, injure, des-troy or prevent competition … the courts recognized the inferential value of sales below cost on the issue ofintent.”23

After Areeda and Tuner published an article defining the cost standards for determining predation in1975,24 intent was no longer an indispensable element in cases on PP.25 Courts believe:

“[a] monopolist to fall within section 2 of the Sherman Act must have the power and the intent to monopol-ise, but the section does not demand any ‘specific’ intent, since no monopolist monopolises unconscious ofwhat he is doing.”26

As a consequence, a certain measurement of cost was adopted as primary evidence for PP to prevail in court.In California computer27 in the absence of any showing that computer manufacturer priced its disk productsbelow marginal cost, there was no showing of predatory pricing as a means of obtaining or maintaining amonopoly.28 In the article, Areeda and Tuner introduced the average variable cost (AVC) standard as apractical cost *417 benchmark in determining PP, a factor that has carried great weight not only in UScourts but also in EU courts. In AKZO prices below average variable costs (that is to say, those which varydepending on the quantities produced) by means of which a dominant undertaking seeks to eliminate a com-petitor must be regarded as abusive. A dominant undertaking has no interest in applying such prices exceptthat of eliminating competitors so as to enable it subsequently to raise its prices by taking advantage of itsmonopolistic position, since each sale generates a loss, namely the total amount of the fixed costs (that is tosay, those which remain constant regardless of the quantities produced) and, at least, part of the variablecosts relating to the unit produced.29

In 1993, the Brooke group decision terminated the trend of courts using below-cost pricing as the mainstandard for deciding PP cases and added the recouping of previous losses as a pre-requisite for deciding a

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 5

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 6: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

PP case. This standard remains in effect today.

The Brooke group decision established a two-tier framework for analysing PP (i.e., the court requires “Aplaintiff must prove (1) that the prices complained of are below an appropriate measure of its rival's costsand (2) that the competitor had a reasonable prospect of recouping its investment in below-cost Prices”).30The importance of recouping losses was stressed:

“Without recoupment, even if predatory pricing causes the target painful losses, it produces lower aggregateprices in the market, and consumer welfare is enhanced”.31

Although the two-tier framework also includes some inherent type of cost-price analysis, the frameworkdoes not state that the price in the PP strategy must be below what specific standard of cost.

Cost test used

After the cost-price relationship was introduced into the price analysis, several cost benchmarks were adop-ted. Although the marginal cost appears to be theoretically appropriate, according to Areeda and Tuner, itlacks practical feasibility.32

The AVC test is introduced in Areeda and Tuner's paper: variable costs, as the name implies, are costs thatvary with changes in output. They typically include such items as materials, fuel, labour directly used to pro-duce the product, indirect labour such as foremen, clerks, and custodial help, utilities, repair and mainten-ance, and per unit royalties and licence fees. The average variable cost is the sum of all variable costs di-vided by output.33 It is the correct test on principle, since a firm that sells below its average variable cost isclearly not loss-minimising. At a price less than average variable cost the firm is earning no return and couldincur fewer losses by ceasing operations.34 The AVC test was widely used by courts from 1975 to 1993,35and because of the adoption of the AVC, fewer plaintiffs succeeded in litigation. A study of the reported PPdecisions from 1975, the year of the Areeda-Turner article, to 1982 found that plaintiffs prevailed in onlyfour out of 48 decided cases (or 8 per cent of the total).36 However, under the AVC test, it is difficult todefine variable cost, as some costs that are not variable in the short term may be variable over an extendedperiod of time. Furthermore, the AVC test was later proved to be only sufficient for ruling that a price belowthe AVC is abusive, as the court in AKZO held that a price above the AVC but below the average total cost(ATC) is abusive only if the price is part of a strategy to eliminate a competitor.

The ATC is a cost benchmark often used to analyse PP:

“Costs are divided into fixed costs, variable costs and total cost. Fixed costs do not vary with changes in out-put. Variable costs vary with changes in output. Total cost is the sum of fixed and variable costs. Averagetotal cost is obtained by dividing total cost by output”.37

Prices above the ATC are normally not predatory, as there will be no profit or cost loss, and selling aproduct below the ATC is normally a rational business strategy, as the ATC consists of variable costs andfixed costs. If prices are subject to demand decline, setting them below the ATC may recover variable costs(some scholars refer to these costs as overhead costs38 ) and part of the fixed costs, while the unrecoveredfixed costs can be recovered *418 through future sales of additional units. Therefore, there are problemswhen choosing long-term and short-term ATCs.39 Additionally, there is no precise point or price below theATC that is considered predatory. Therefore, the ATC cannot be used independently as a cost test in assess-ing price rationality. Thus, there is a need for a lower limit index. There are problems involved in measuringtotal costs, particularly in multiproduct operations where it is necessary to allocate common costs. In the realmarket, even in single-line business there is the problem of properly amortising costs with an investment as-pect like capital equipment and advertising.40

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 6

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 7: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

The ATC is used as an upper limit cost standard in both theoretical and case analyses.41 In AKZO, the ATCis used as a company standard with the AVC:

“prices below average total costs, that is to say, fixed costs plus variable costs, but above average variablecosts, must be regarded as abusive if they are determined as part of a plan for eliminating a competitor. Suchprices can drive from the market undertakings which are perhaps as efficient as the dominant undertakingbut which, because of their smaller financial resources, are incapable of withstanding the competition wagedagainst them.”42

Besides, this analysis is partly based on the evidence of predatory intent. For example, the court (FifthChamber) found that AKZO's selective below-ATC price apparently implied an exclusive intent: The pricescharged by AKZO to its own customers were above its average total costs, whereas those offered to custom-ers of ECS were below its average total costs.43

Average avoidable cost (AAC) is the average per unit cost that the predator would have avoided during theperiod of below-cost pricing had it not produced the predatory increment of sales.44 From the definition, wemay conclude that if market participants try not to avoid the avoidable costs, they are conveying two signals:1) a predatory intent and 2) a predatory investment in eliminating competitors. As a cost benchmark, theAAC avoids the insufficiency of marginal costs. In addition, the AAC test includes both fixed costs andvariable costs, and it determines whether a cost is variable in the long run. The AAC test is used as a stand-ard for enforcing exclusive practices in the European Union. Failure to cover AAC indicates that the domin-ant undertaking is sacrificing profits in the short term and that an equally efficient competitor cannot servethe targeted customers without incurring a loss.45

The long-run average incremental cost (LAIC) is a cost benchmark used in sectoral regulation and court costanalysis. Incremental cost is a generic concept that refers to the increase in the firm's total cost when it ex-pands its output of a particular product or products by some specified increment, holding constant theamount of other products that the firm produces. Often, the increment in question is the entire output of therelevant product. Average incremental cost is incremental cost per unit of the output in question.46 With re-spect to incremental cost and the character scale economy, which will expand cost into different markets inthe future and thus generate forward-looking costs, the long-run calculation can predict future costs and al-locate costs to current and future users. Thus, the calculation can provide a complete foundation for the cal-culation of average costs.47 The LAIC has an original relationship with the price regulation of the US tele-com sector. According to the US telecommunication regulation code,48 the LAIC is described as “Total ele-ment long-run incremental cost”(TELAIC). The total element long-run incremental cost of an element is“the forward-looking cost over the long run of the total quantity of the facilities and functions that are dir-ectly attributable to, or reasonably identifiable as incremental to, such element”.49 In the definition, TEL-AIC is the standard cost incurred by an individual firm to produce a given element, and the cost is exclus-ively the forward-looking cost of producing this element. Representative of the total elements, TELAICtakes all costs into account. Thus, this cost benchmark is often used with products that have complex cost al-location structures. The advantage of identifying the product-specific cost is especially appreciated by courtswhen adjudicating PP cases.

The LAIC has been used in cases involving the telecom industry as a tool to determine a competitive price.In AT&T Communications of Southern States, Inc v BellSouth Telecommunications, Inc, Competitor localexchange carrier sought judicial review of state public service commission's resolution of dispute with in-cumbent local exchange carrier over terms of interconnection agreement. The District Court, Hinkle, J., heldthat: (1) the commission did not abuse its *419 discretion by employing Total Service Long Run Increment-al Cost method when calculating forward-looking costs”.50 The LAIC test has also been used in EU cases tocalculate an accurate cost for specific services. In Deutsche Post AG (DPAG), for example, the European

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 7

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 8: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

Commission (Commission) found that the DPAG operated in more than three services, including the com-mercial parcel service, the mail-order parcel service and the “reserved area”.51 The applicant's alleged thatDPAG offers its commercial parcel service at below-cost prices with the aim of ousting competitors fromthe market. DPAG covers the resultant losses with the aid of the profits made in the reserved area services-let-ter post.52 The Commission reviewed the economic status and found that firms can withstand a loss fromthe below-cost selling of certain products because the loss can be balanced by revenues from other products.To justify the standalone cost of certain products, firms use the incremental cost as a cost benchmark.53

Part III: Software market conditions

Because of the differences in market conditions, the elements for competition that must be considered maydiffer. As the software market is a rather new economy, it differs from the traditional market. Thus, identify-ing certain characteristics of the software market is important for competition analysis, as both the analysesand the regulation rules are based on traditional markets.

Software is a network economy

Under a network effect, as the number of current users for a product or service increases, the number ofusers for the complementary products or services increases accordingly. As this phenomenon is caused byconsumers, and as a large network can attract a large group of consumers, suppliers can utilise network ef-fects to achieve economies of scale.54 There are two types of network effects. One affects a product that iscompatible with its complementary products: These effects can arise when a system consists of two distinctcomponents, A and B, both of which are purchased by a single user. For example, A may be the operatingsystem needed to make word processing program B work. Positive feedback arises when an increase in thenumber of users who adopt component A leads to an increase in the benefits that consumers can enjoy fromthe purchase of component B.55 The other affects competing products. If an increasing number of con-sumers use one product, these existing users can attract other consumers that have not yet purchased thisproduct. These buyers appreciate the extra value that they can receive from the current user of a product.Such value is abundant; for example, new consumers will have access to communication with current users,they can obtain help with using the product from current users, and they can obtain advice if they do notknow which product is best suited for them. Additionally, they can also share their experiences with the cur-rent users of the product. Subject to these benefits, consumers will choose a product that has a large group ofusers. As an increasing number of consumers join the network and as this network increases in size, moreconsumers are encouraged to join this network. Network effects are especially apparent in innovation mar-kets where a first-mover advantage is manifest. The first mover to a new market usually captures most of theusers of a new market and creates a winner-takes-all or winner-takes-most phenomenon. Because of con-sumer concentration, the market begins to tip towards the larger network, and the current consumers becomelocked in.

Following the consumer concentration in one network, not only the consumers but also the dominant suppli-er benefit from a larger network, as the dominant supplier can easily scale its output and achieve a profit.This advantage intensifies the market competition among the players in network economies to compete orinvest in obtaining a dominant market position. The competition for a dominant market position, as de-scribed in market leader theory,56 positively affects the competition in the market because of network ex-ternalities. Specifically, the benefits generated by the network market leader attract competitors and in-centivise competitors to invest in efforts to become the market leader.

Network competition is more complex if there is a dominant network present in the market because in themarketplace, competitor networks may attempt to be compatible with the dominant leader. With respect tocompetition, the dominant network may use certain standards to attract more consumers. For example, web

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 8

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 9: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

browsers and programming languages are driven to standardisation for the same reasons that PC-based oper-ating systems are. That is, developers and consumers are both likely to gravitate towards the system thatthey think will come to dominate the market, and by doing so, they ensure that the system does, in fact, be-come dominant. Economists refer to this phenomenon as the *420 “tipping” effect,57 where network com-petition involves gaining consumers from the dominant network, and greater network standards are used toprevent competitors from entering the market:

“… consumers could not switch from PC systems to server systems without incurring substantial costs, PCsystems that were not compatible with leading chips were more expensive, there were fewer applicationswritten to run on OS (operating system) developed non-compatible systems, and switching to non-compatible systems required purchase of new peripherals and transfer of files, user of compatible PC systemwas unlikely to abandon investment in that system by switching to thin-client network system merely be-cause monopoly price was being charged for OS, and, since majority of software developers wrote andwould continue to write applications for defendant's OS, there were significant barriers to entry for de-velopers of competing OSs.”58

The scale economy of the demand side has a significant impact on the market structure, which is of greatconcern for the competition. Consumer concentration tends to cause those consumers who have not made apurchase to join the dominant network. This effect causes the dominant network to become even strongerand more stable. The number of market players begins to decline. Finally, the market power is accumulatesin a single dominant firm, and the market structure becomes highly concentrated. In turn, the network be-comes a switching cost that any competitor must forego.

The corresponding effects of a dominant market power and a concentrated market structure on the networkrenders pricing abuses, such as PP, more feasible. Because of the benefits created by network effects, a dom-inant market player that sets competitive prices will have an advantage over any competitors of equal effi-ciency. PP is more exclusive in network markets, as it appears to be less necessary to be adopted againstcompetitors with the same efficiency. PP becomes necessary if the dominant network is facing a more effi-cient competitor, as a more efficient competitor may either bring a homogeneous product at a reduced costor offer an advanced/superior product. When facing a firm with an advanced or superior product, a dominantfirm may utilise PP as its final option for maintaining its market position.

The software market is a typical network market.59 If new software is introduced to the marketplace, a newmarket opens, and the first mover is bound to attract the majority of the users. If a dominant softwareproduct is presented to the market, consumers will choose a network with the most users because of its com-patibility with the dominant software. Thus, software markets are often viewed as monopolies. For example,the internet browser market was first dominated by Netscape,60 but Netscape was soon followed by Mi-crosoft's Internet Explorer.61 The same scenario occurred in the video game software market. Nintendoserved as the market leader in 1985 but lost its position to Sony in 1995. Ten years ago, however, Nintendoearned its way to the forefront of the market once again.62

Software is a durable good

Durable goods are goods that have long life cycles such that consumers can use these goods for a long timewithout having to replace them. When researching the durability phenomenon, economists find that durabil-ity plays a major role in market management.

Since the 1970s, the durable goods phenomenon has gradually developed into microeconomic theories.Swan found that competitors will make their products only as durable as those of their competitors and thatthis level of durability, called optimal durability, is efficient.63 Coase noted that a durable good supplier

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 9

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 10: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

with a monopoly on the market may confront a declining demand for its products, as its consumers will be-lieve that the supplier will charge a higher price for early buyers and therefore opt to wait and make theirpurchases later.64 Hendel and Lizzeri analysed the adverse selection of consumers with different deservingprices. Such consumers will compare a new product with a second-hand product before making their pur-chase.65 The durability has important implications *421 for price competition. First, if a product is durableand faces demand elasticity, the supplier may, to some extent, be forced to set different prices for differentbuyers with different deserving prices. This phenomenon is similar to price discrimination, which is prohib-ited by competition law. Thus, it will require effort to distinguish between the two phenomena. Additionally,the durability of the product can form a second-hand market. The used product may compete with both thesuppliers and the competitors' products, whereas the second-hand product is not controlled by either of them.

Software is a durable product, “Software “wears out” only due to technological change or planned obsoles-cence, not based on normal wear and tear such as applies for durable equipment”.66 However, unlike mostdurable goods, software has no second-hand market, as the software trade is controlled by licenses, underwhich the targeted user is confirmed after the purchasing deal is made. The inability to resell nearly preventscurrent users from switching to other substitute software, and consumers are locked in from secondary mar-kets, such as upgrading markets. Current consumers must discard their current software and pay for newsoftware. Thus, they incur a value loss whenever they abandon their current software and adjust to the newworking environment. Such value loss hardens the competition from competitor software suppliers. As innormal price competition, competitors offer lower prices to attract competitor clients. Thus, the high switch-ing cost in the software market may outweigh any competitive price cut. At the same time, large price cuts,even those that are below cost and that may be considered predatory, will not be effective in attracting com-petitors' consumers.

Software has high fixed costs and low marginal costs

Software is a product that “is often expensive to create but once created the cost of making additional copiesusually is low.”67 The initial investment for entry, which is also called the developing cost, is high for thesoftware market. Thus, the developing cost imposes a limit on the number of market players. As the devel-oping cost adds a high entry barrier that deters most investors, a software market with a concentrated marketstructure naturally developed.

The low marginal cost of software is negligible. Given this characteristic, competition theory, which statesthat a competitive price68 is close to a marginal cost, is not applicable in software. In response to competi-tion, the software supplier that sets a price close to the marginal cost with the intention of competing withothers is not rational, as it will not be able to recover its fixed cost.

The high fixed cost and low marginal cost of software make it difficult to identify the per unit cost of a soft-ware product, which is important in analysing pricing abuse practices. A product does not often have a coststructure if most of the cost is fixed and the variable part of the cost is minimal. In analysing the cost-pricerelationship, cost benchmarks that rely on marginal costs are useless in the software sector. Perhaps a newtechnology that can identify the per-unit cost of software is needed.

Software suppliers compete with innovative products

The software market is an innovative market, a factor that is significant for market competition. As innova-tion markets are high-tech markets, they involve investment in research and development (R&D). It must beacknowledged that most markets involve R&D practices. However, innovation markets are called such be-cause innovation is the main activity of that market and the decisive factor in market competition, while thesame is not true for traditional markets. In market competition, new products are introduced to the market

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 10

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 11: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

after the innovation research is conducted. Because the new products are superior to the current product,competitors must invest in the new product if they wish to remain competitive. As investment is risky andcostly, investors will not invest in homogeneous products because whether the homogeneous product willgenerate a competitive advantage is uncertain.

When facing competition, current suppliers may favour introducing advanced products to the market ratherthan engaging in price competition. As in markets where innovation and investment are particularly import-ant, advanced products or relevant technologies have wide effects on technology-sensitive consumers, com-plementary products or service suppliers and competitor suppliers. In such a market, a dominant player ag-gressively invests in R&D to obtain a technology advantage over its competitors. The technology improve-ment is more likely to attract the technology-sensitive consumers away from low innovative competitors.This part of the consumer market will enlarge the current network of the dominant player. This market struc-ture change may cause supplementary product suppliers to invest more in products that are compatible withthe advanced technology. As technology and product changes affect the technological environment by ren-dering competitors' product technologies obsolete, these changes serves as a means of eliminating competit-ors from the market because competitors must also invest in R&D to compete with the technical advantageof the dominant player, and the capital and *422 technical investments may be too great or unaffordable forthe weaker competitors. Therefore, fragile competitors may leave the market, an expected return from innov-ation competition.69 The predictable outcome of the innovation strategy has advantages over price preda-tion, as price competition attacks the solvency of competitors, whereas innovation competition attacks com-petitors both technologically and financially. Furthermore, from a predator's perspective, price predationcauses a loss in capital, whereas innovation predation offers innovation fame and technological advance-ment. Thus, innovation replaces price as the main form of competition in an innovation market and distin-guishes the innovation market from the traditional market. Another advantage is that product innovation hasa more significant impact on social welfare than a simple price cut. Competition law views innovation andcost reduction as parallel defences for anti-competitive practices.

The innovation character implies more than simple competition. Investing in software is costly, and softwareinvestors face the risks associated with the R&D involved in software production and the risk of not recover-ing their investments. Thus, a large capital investment is one condition that causes entry barriers to the soft-ware market to remain high. Subject to this requirement, a number of competitors may not be large, andlarge capital investments create fixed or sunk costs that must be considered when calculating per unit cost.

In addition, a first-mover advantage and winner-take-all/most phenomenon are manifest in the software mar-ket. These phenomena render the software market more of a monopolised market. If one company introducesnew software, as the first mover, it is likely to take all or most of the market share. For example, in the caseof the internet browsers, as soon as Netscape released Navigator on December 15, 1994, the product beganto enjoy dramatic acceptance by the public; shortly after its release, consumers were already using Navigatorfar more than any other browser product.70 Nintendo's video game software and Microsoft's personal com-puter operating system also experienced this phenomenon after their early entry into the relevant market.71Thus, the innovation competition caused the software market to become a naturally concentrated one, asmarket leaders can easily form without or before the competition process. Thus, market competition oftenoccurs between the dominant and non-dominant firms.

As a high-technology product, software involves certain technology standards in its development, mainten-ance and operating procedures. This characteristic can lead to high entry barriers. If one software programbecomes popular, its technology standard may easily become the standard for the market, as in the case ofthe computer software realm: the Microsoft Windows operating system; the MPEG standard for compressingvideo data; Adobe PostScript, a page description language; and Adobe Acrobat, a standard for making docu-ments “portable”.72 These standards may form one type of market barrier for new entrants and introduce

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 11

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 12: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

compatibility problems, as these technology standards often facilitate network effects. Moreover, certaintechnological standards are more easily associated with IP rights, which makes it more difficult to conductcompetition analysis.

Part IV: Predatory pricing of software

This part assesses below-cost prices in the software market on the basis of the background knowledge intro-duced previously.

Loss leader price

Loss leader selling is: An item is offered for sale below “cost” to attract customers; any loss from this bar-gain is recouped by raising prices of other items; thus the customers attracted are deceived. Then competi-tion in loss leaders grows so severe that no recoupment through deception is possible; and the merchant, hisemployees, and his producers suffer from chaos in the market.73 In its earlier stages, this strategy was de-ceptive, as the seller would increase the prices of its other products to compensate for the loss generated bythe low-price selling, a practice that led to its reputation as a low-price seller.

Modern economists find that loss leader selling is economically rational without deception. McDaniel andDarden defined the loss-leader strategy as

*423 “Leader pricing (sometimes called loss leader pricing) is an attempt by marketing manager to inducestore patronage through selling a product near cost or even below cost to attract customers”,74

and loss-leader pricing has been deemed a legitimate practice by modern EU case law. In Re Autodesk S.A. vE.C.C.75 Autodesk S.A. is a subsidiary of the American Autodesk group and it markets in France softwarefor computer-aided design and manufacturing, which covers computer-aided design and computer-assisteddrafting.76 Autodesk introduced a selective distribution agreement called “Autocad authorized dealer”. Theagreement included a clause that read

“an offer of software programs with the aim of attracting customers likely to purchaser other products or ser-vices or to promote your business, and not with the aim of making a profit”.77

The Competition Council ruled against Autodesk S.A in response to the profits of a firm called Techno Dir-ect, that Autodesk had contravened of the E.C. Treaty art.85(1) and Ordinance 86-1243 on December 1,1986 (s.7) by reason of practices in the sector of software for computer aided design and computer-assisteddrafting, ordered it to amend the terms of the Autodesk authorised dealer agreement and to pay a pecuniarysanction of FRF 200,000.78 The Paris Court of Appeal ruled on the application lodged by Autodesk S.A. forthe annulment and quashing of the Competition Council's decision, as the court found the use of the lossleaders to be lawful The clause prohibiting the sale of software programs as loss leaders, went beyond thescope of this term as defined by the circular of December 22, 1980, upon which the applicant (s.7) seeks torely.79

Contrary to EU case law, loss-leader pricing (LLP is prohibited by the Unlawful Practices Act art.1074.80This clause addresses an extreme phenomenon where LLP is used as a strategy that exclusively targets com-petitors. Although a similar clause appeared in a smaller scope (Alicia,81 California), it shows that underLLP, competitors that only supply the loss-leader product would not withstand the profit loss and would bedriven out of the market.

Although LLP always appears to introduce low prices, which can benefit the consumer and be pro-competitive, it can also be abused as a PP strategy. However, LLP is more difficult to scrutinise than normal

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 12

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 13: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

PP. In Wal-Mart Stores, Inc, v American Drugs, Inc,82 the Supreme Court approved Wal-Mart Stores' loss-leader practices”, judge Brown, J., held that:

1. violation of Unfair Practices Act section prohibiting below-cost sales required showing that below-costsales were made with intent to destroy competition;

2. use of loss leader strategy could not be inferred to show intent to destroy competition; and

3. Arkansas Unfair Practices Act did not provide sufficient statutory basis for inference of specific intent todestroy competition based solely on showing of some below-cost pricing”.83

We can infer the following from this case. First, the intent of eliminating competitors is an important factorin finding LLP to be predatory. However, proving this intent is difficult for a plaintiff. Second, even if thereis an exclusion effect of LLP, this effect must be considered under the legislative purpose of competitionlaw, which aims to foster competition and allow consumers to enjoy competition welfare (low price) ratherthan protect a certain competitor.

As LLP easily induces competition law concerns, market participants use this strategy carefully. Such cau-tion is especially warranted in the software market, as below-cost marketing is often needed in softwaresales. After the judgment in Microsoft II,84 scholars argued whether Microsoft's practice of giving away itsIE product was predatory,85 as some believed that Microsoft's free offering of IE had the predatory intent ofterminating Netscape's profit gain, and such termination could bar a potential entrant from the computer op-erating system market.86 Although Netscape was close to introducing its *424 own computer operating sys-tem, Microsoft remained the dominant firm in this market. Microsoft responded that giving away its browserproduct for free was a valid business model, one followed by many software companies, because it wouldgenerate future revenues. For example, a free browser could help Microsoft establish an internet portal onwhich it could sell advertising.87 Although Microsoft left some evidence that proved its intent was to quashNetscape88 and Microsoft did eliminate Netscape as a competitor, the court did not find Microsoft to be inviolation of antitrust law. What made Microsoft exempt from predatory condemnation was its free-forever-and-for-everyone strategy because, although Microsoft met the below-cost elimination condition, itfailed to recoup its losses by later charging for the product.89

Penetration price

Penetration pricing (PeP) is a strategy that:

“… the technique of offering low prices to early customers so as to build up an installed base and influencethe choices of later adopters”.90

As it easily and commonly occurs in network economies, some scholars define it within a network back-ground91 : a strategy called “penetration pricing.” in order to build an installed base of users and thus makeits technology more attractive to later users.92 As a market expansion strategy, PeP is similar to price pro-moting in traditional industries. Professors Bolton, Brodley, and Riordan analysed price promotion with ahypothetical pizza case. When introducing a new type of pizza, the supplier set a below-cost price to attractcustomers and introduce them to the advantages of the new pizza. After the promotion period, the supplierincreased the price of the new pizza and recouped the below-cost investment from the improved price of thenew pizza.93

The PeP phenomenon has the same function as PP in eliminating competitors, but the difference is that thebelow-cost pricing is necessary in the network economy. The network economy enables market operators tocompete with one another under network effects. Network effects add extra value for customers other than

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 13

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 14: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

the product cost, which becomes a barrier to market expansion and entry.94 The current network is a majorobstacle for competitors hoping to enlarge their market share or for firms planning to enter a network mar-ket. Thus, a price that can penetrate the current network is needed for market expansion and entry. Softwaremarket promotion with PeP is common:

“Netscape, the current leader in the browser market, built up an 80 per cent market share by giving awaymore than six million copies of its browser over the course of six months. After the introductory period,however, Netscape began to charge for its browser. Today, Netscape relies on browser sales for more thanhalf its revenue”95

the “carpet-bombing” of America with AOL software--some 250 million free copies were distributed byAOL through 1996--was another classic campaign to surge past rivals and create critical mass. AOL rose,somewhat incredibly, from just five million subscribers in 1994 to over seventeen million in 1999, to domin-ate, by a large margin, the country's Internet Service Provider (ISP) sector.96

PeP is widely accepted and used if there is vigorous competition in the network market. The software marketis a typical network market. In a software network, once a customer is locked in, it is usually difficult for thecustomer to switch because software is a durable good, and switching to new software means extra purchas-ing and extra costs to adjust to the new network. Thus, penetration pricing that is below cost is no longersufficient to induce software consumers to switch products. Instead, symbolic pricing, selective giveawaysor even minus pricing is commonly used by companies aiming to expand into and enter the software market.These penetration strategies aim to use low prices to expand market share. Expanding market share is espe-cially important for software vendors during the market entry stage if alternative software systems alreadyhave a large installed base. As it allows new entrant gain enough customers to form a network. “At a laterstage--after reaching a critical mass--it may be possible *425 for the vendor to increase prices”.97 Typicalsoftware penetration price practices were adopted by Netscape and Microsoft:

“Netscape led the way in making software available free of charge over the internet … it can serve as an ex-tremely efficient, low-cost means of distributing … software”.98

Additionally:

“Netscape also pioneered the idea of plug-ins, software written by third parties that enhance the functional-ity of the basic Navigator program … Making quality enhancements available free is a variant on penetra-tion pricing”.99

Although PeP prevails in the network economy, concerns over the abuse of below-cost selling procedures bythe dominant firm exist. After all, any firm has the freedom to expand its market share through PeP. Suchabuse is plausible because PeP and PP share the same procedure for below-cost selling periods. In otherwords, if a dominant firm is brought to the courtroom for its exploration of PP in a market, it will cite PeP asa defence. This concern is not unfounded, as PeP must be distinguished from PP both theoretically and prac-tically.

PeP and PP both have market expansion effects, as both offer prices low enough to attract consumers, andthe low prices succeed in gaining consumer cooperation. Although some apparent elements separate the two(e.g. PeP is a temporary characteristic or the result of introducing a new product), these elements are not themost important distinguishing factors. PeP and PP differ in that the latter can recoup losses. There are in-vestments in profit loss for both PeP and PP, but as an abuse of market power, PP has distinct factors. Aftersuccessfully adopting PP, competitors with either equal or advanced efficiency will be eliminated, and thepredator can charge any price above competition level, regardless of whether its product bears efficiency. Apredator can only recoup its losses by imposing monopoly pricing after eliminating its competitors. In con-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 14

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 15: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

trast, a PeP practitioner poses either the same efficiency or superior efficiency. A product of the same effi-ciency may survive in the market, as the consumer favours more choice at the same price level. Therefore, amore efficient supplier can recoup its losses through later selling. For cost reduction efficiency, a firm canrecoup its losses by selling at a competitive price, while for innovation efficiency, a firm can recoup itslosses by selling an advanced product.

The effects of the penetration strategy in the software market are slightly different from those in the tradi-tional market. As the marginal cost of software is extremely low, the market penetration cost is low. Thus,PeP is more plausible. As locked-in effects and high switching costs exist, software users are often unable toswitch. Thus, companies inevitably offer free software to gain customers from a competitor network. Withthe presence of vigorous competition, even negative pricing is a reserved choice for market penetration.Moreover, the penetration mainly targets the existing customers of competitors, and PP is less likely to beeffective among this group of customers. A detailed analysis will be provided later in part D of the chapter.

Learning by doing

According to the theory of learning by doing (LBD), learning occurs from practice, and applying the learnedexperience to the next practice is beneficial. With the adoption of cumulated experience, later practices willcost less or present with improved quality. LBD has been regarded as an important theory by economicscholars since the 1930s.100 These scholars observed airplane assembly procedures and found that thegreatest number of labour hours was required for the assembly of the first airplane, compared with the num-ber of hours required for the assembly of subsequent airplanes using the same procedure. Furthermore, thefollowing labour hours spent on subsequent airplanes with same working conditions declined according tothe production and time order:

“that the number of labor-hours expended in the production of an airframe (airplane body without engines)is a decreasing function of the total number of airframes of the same type previously produced. Indeed, therelation is remarkably precise; to produce the Nth airframe of a given type, counting from the inception ofproduction, the amount of labor required is proportional to N-1/3.”101

This direct relationship between learning effects and cost reduction and product improvement has importantimplications for market competition practices.

*426 LBD can notably reduce production costs. The lessons learned from past manufacturing experiencesare adopted and implemented by suppliers when producing subsequent units of a product, significantly redu-cing the cost of manufacturing. This principle has great influence on pricing practices because it is rationalfor operators to set prices below the cost of the current or previous products without any predatory intent. Asproducers balance the cost between current products and future products, even prices below the current costmay generate profit from future production and sales.

In addition to the significant reduction of cost, economic scholars have demonstrated that LBD also im-proves product quality vis-à-vis the introduction of new products102 and innovation leadership.103 For theinnovation outcome, cumulated technology improvements can lead to the leapfrogging effect. According tothis phenomenon, learning by doing is an innovation approach that gradually results in technical change.After a technique has evolved to a certain extent, the technique will catch up and leapfrog the current ad-vanced technology.104 This phenomenon highlights the importance of cumulated technology improvementsand their adoption in innovation.

The improved product quality or innovation induced by LBD also enables market participants to set pricesbelow cost to engage in market competition because the losses incurred via current below-cost selling can berecouped by future production and sales of an advanced product. Thus LBD helps explain why below-cost

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 15

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 16: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

pricing often occurs in an innovation market. For example, this effect appeared in the semiconductor sectorduring the 1970s and 1980s, when there was a dispute over the low prices in the market for memory chipsbetween Japan and the United States. As the production of chips spread globally and the international com-petition in the US chip market expanded, the market introduced competitors from Europe and Japan. Untilthe beginning of 1980, Japanese suppliers monopolised this market with low prices that were consideredpredatory by US suppliers. As a result, the practices of the Japanese suppliers were investigated by theDOJ.105 Finally, the two countries negotiated and decided to set prices according to foreign market val-ues.”106

To examine whether the solution is fair, Kenneth Flamm developed a model of pricing and production overthe life-cycle of a high-technology industry107 :

“In IM DRAMs (and in other industries with significant learning and scale economies, capacity constraints,and short product life cycles), prices over some time interval will fall below common measures of averagecost and marginal cost, even with no strategic behavior (like predation) assumed on the part of producers.Therefore, antidumping trade laws that forbid pricing below some measure of average cost will snare‘normal’ competitive behavior in the net they cast. Moreover, consumer welfare losses from successful car-telization of a market like that for DRAMs can greatly exceed the monopoly rents collected by produ-cers.”108

This finding illustrates that the semiconductor sector is subject to the learning effect and that the Japaneselow prices have a relationship with cost reduction. Aggressive regulation on these efficiency-enhanced lowprices can hinder price competition and result in profit loss for the consumer.

Although LBD pricing is enhanced by efficiency, even a dominant firm can adopt it safely without invitingscrutiny over predatory practices. However, this below-cost pricing does not eliminate competition concernsentirely, as it can lead to the elimination of competitors.

As below-cost selling may drive competitors out of the market, help a company form a market monopolyand lead to monopoly pricing, a predator may claim that it is engaging in LBD to defend its PP. Hence, thereis a need to distinguish LBD from PP. According to the theoretical literature, losses from LBD below-costprice selling can be recouped from future cost reductions or innovative products. Thus, the below-cost priceis only below the cost of the current or previous products, as it is above the average cost in the long run. Atthe same time, losses from predatory below-cost price selling can only be recouped during the monopoly-pri-cing period that occurs after eliminating competitors. If a defendant is engaged in predatory litigation andcan offer evidence that the below-cost selling is related to cost savings or the *427 possibility of introducinginnovative products, then it is on a learning curve, and this explanation is sufficient to justify its below-costpricing. If such evidence is not available, then it probably will be subject to an investigation for predatorypractices.

The software market is characterised by innovation, and product upgrades and new products continually re-place old products in the market. Therefore, LBD effects are more likely to accompany with software devel-opment and marketing. Applying experiences in innovation and technology accumulation usually leads toadvanced technology and advanced software, as well as cost reductions in R&D. It is reasonable for a soft-ware supplier to set its price below cost if the above situation is reasonably expected.

The unjustified below-cost price

The software market is an innovation-based economy where the supplier wins by developing advanced soft-ware products and price is generally ineffective as a strategy against competition. However, price still playsa significant role in the market, as it is necessary to convince consumers to purchase the innovative software.

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 16

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 17: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

Given the differences in customer preferences, technology-sensitive consumers will be attracted to advancedsoftware, whereas consumer groups that are price sensitive are less likely to be attracted to advanced soft-ware. Moreover, if a firm has no technology advantage over its market competition, it is more likely to useprice as part of a competitive strategy.109 This price competition provides an environment vulnerable to pri-cing abuse.

In market competition, firms must gain consumers from their competitors. The same is also true in the soft-ware market, but different groups of software customers have different consumer preferences. Because ofnetwork effects, a considerable portion of the customers will be locked into a network. As there is a largeswitching cost posed to these consumers, they will be unwilling to switch unless the firm's competitors giveaway their software or bring revolutionary software products to the market. Thus, this group of consumers isnot likely to bring profits to the competitors, and the competitors may only be able to derive value if the cus-tomers can enlarge the scope of the competitors' network by switching. Therefore, a giveaway price isneeded for the switch. A profitable competition may occur among consumers who have not yet made a pur-chase. These consumers are more sensitive to price, and firms are more likely to use PP to compete for them.This group of customers will compare the price, quality and network value of a software product. Their pur-chase can both ensure a firm's profit gain and enlarge its existing network. Suppliers with software productsof basically the same value may inevitably engage in a price war. Below-cost pricing within this group ofconsumers is likely to be PP. Giveaway prices or negative pricing within these networks would be con-sidered PP, as the companies would invest in profit loss by engaging in these practices.

When competing with a dominant network, competitors of equal efficiency will not be a threat. The threatstems from competitors of superior efficiency. In the software market, network effects and durability factorsmake switching to an equal software product expensive. Furthermore, the practice of market tipping compelsconsumers to tend to choose the larger network. Thus, a software supplier of equal efficiency will be disad-vantaged when competing with a supplier of a larger network, even if it sets its prices at a competitive level.A firm of superior efficiency may have the following two conditions: similar products with lower costs andsimilar costs with advanced products. The first situation encourages price competition, and the cost advant-age can be, to some extent, offset by the network advantages from a dominant network. Under the secondsituation, a dominant supplier with no technology advantage will lose market power if it does not invest inimproving its technology or lowering its price. As discussed above, technology competition may take a longtime to catch up to and eliminate a competitor, while price is a relatively quick way of doing so, as it can bechanged as needed. However, whether a low price is effective in eliminating a superior software productmust be determined.

Given that Microsoft eliminated Netscape by giving away IE, one may argue that a low price can eliminate asuperior product if certain criteria are satisfied. In a market that exhibits significant network effects and highswitching costs, a firm with intellectual property protection in the incumbent product may gain monopolycontrol without having a superior product.110 In Beyond Telex v IBM, the court held that aggressive pricecompetition by IBM might have the effect of driving out competitors that had become a powerful force instimulating innovation. Thus, the court may have sought to favour innovation over price competition be-cause of a perception that aggressive price competition would lead to less innovation and that in the com-puter industry the long-term value to society of technical innovation exceeds the short term cost to con-sumers of high prices and *428 reduced present output.111 Thus, low pricing can eliminate all types of com-petitors, and advanced technology is equally fragile in front of low prices. PP law must also consider theharm that predation causes by frustrating innovation and lowering the incentive to innovate.

A suggested approach for analysing predatory pricing in the software market

If a firm chooses pricing as the path to exclude its competitors, the correspondent predatory assessment must

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 17

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 18: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

be based on the cost-price relationship principle. As the players in the software market are operating in aninnovation market, they can still use price to eliminate their competitors and then impose monopoly pricingon their consumers. PP in the software market will also adhere to the following procedure: first, a companyinvests in profit loss pricing, and second, it recoups its losses through monopoly pricing. Thus, the tradition-al standards for identifying PP should generally be applicable in the software market.

However, when applying the traditional standards, adjustments should be made because there are sector-specific characteristics in the software market. For instance, the cost structure of the software product, thenetwork competition in the software market and innovation competition are all sector-specific factors. Tradi-tional standards use the cost-price relationship to infer predatory intent and the possibility and legality of ex-clusion. The AVC, ATC, AAC and LAIC are all used as benchmarks. They all help to identify whether thecost of a product can be recovered by the current price. For the software market, these benchmarks are onlypartially applicable. According to the cost structure of software, fixed costs constitute most of the total costof a software product, and this cost structure does not change. The fixed costs or total cost can be fully re-covered through a certain amount of sales when or before it is confronted by competition. Once the cost hasbeen recovered, the courts cannot treat below-cost pricing as PP simply because they cannot recover thecost. Thus, the above-cost benchmark is inapplicable, as any non-negative price is a pure profit gain for afirm with zero cost.

Under the above consideration, assessing PP in the software market should require two steps. The first stepis identifying whether a software firm has recovered its cost. If a firm has not recovered its cost using be-low-cost pricing, it may be suspected of having predatory intent and the potential to exclude its competitors.In this case, further investigation is justified. However, there is a problem with choosing cost benchmarks,as marginal costs, such as the AVC test, have two problems. One problem concerns the identification ofmarginal costs in the long run. The other problem is that fixed costs are not included in the calculations;therefore, these cost tests are apparently not suitable for software price assessment. The ATC, which is thetotal cost divided by the number sold, has two inadequacies. The ATC is generally a price upper limit usedto justify a price that is not predatory. Additionally, the ATC does not explicitly calculate the per-unit costof an extra output. The LAIC is a cost suited for determining whether the price of a software product is aloss-generating price. As an unbalanced cost structure, a certain part of the cost, such as the variable cost, isno more comprehensive, and the total element of the LAIC can include all needed costs. Additionally, soft-ware firms tend to engage in more than one product.112 There is a potential danger in operating only onsingle products, as a company may easily be eliminated by an efficient loss-leader price (e.g. Netscape113 ).This strategy will generate common costs that are shared by all products. In turn, these common costs inevit-ably lead to the use of an increasing cost standard (LAIC) to make a precise calculation of the standalonecost of certain products.

If a software firm has recovered its product cost through previous customers, a software operator is likely tofavour adopting PP to eliminate its competitors. In this situation, it is difficult to find legal reasons for the il-legality of PP. TFEU art.102(a) explicitly states that PP will not be applicable in this situation because allabove zero prices are profitable. Thus, the firm cannot be considered to be engaged in unfair price prohibi-tion.

In the above situation, a software supplier has great pricing freedom. Against competitors of equal efficien-cies, an eliminative price will be below the competitor's cost. Against competitors of superior efficiency, thecompetition is between a low price and a superior product. The low price will inevitably cover price-sensitive customers. As discussed in the previous section, a price that is low enough to eliminate a competit-or with a superior product raises the question of whether the elimination is a violation of competition law.

As all market suppliers aim to maximise their profits, elimination may not be a rational strategy even if the

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 18

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 19: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

supplier has recovered its investment cost. For a software supplier that has recovered its cost, the mostthreatening competitor is not the competitor that has equal efficiency or a cost advantage but the competitorthat offers an advanced product. If a dominant software product competes with an advanced product in themarket and the company producing the former does not want to improve its product quality, the most ration-al strategy is not to eliminate the advanced product but to cover all price-sensitive customers. As the marketpower for the monopolist is its zero cost and dominant network, it has no technology advantage over itscompetitors; therefore, eliminating the superior product with a below-cost price will be an abuse of marketpower.114 Moreover, *429 quality-sensitive customers pose an obstacle, as they are unlikely to be attractedto the low price. Thus, covering all price-sensitive customers is the way to maximise profit, and prices thatcan cover price-sensitive consumers offers a competitive advantage (and prices at this level are a competit-ive price). At this price level, even competitors of the same efficiency are eliminated, and the elimination ofsuch competitors should not be considered a predatory practice. If the competitive below-cost price is notadopted, the market will gradually be covered by the advanced product, and the monopolist will obtain noth-ing. This outcome is not fair for a monopolist that is in a profit-collecting stage.

If the monopolist still wants to eliminate the superior product, it can do so if the price of its product is un-reasonably low. There are cases where low-price products have eliminated advanced products. In the inter-net browser market, after Netscape's success, Microsoft quickly developed IE and soon gave it away. Nets-cape was eliminated. This outcome suggests that only a price close to a giveaway price can win over techno-logy-sensitive customers and hence eliminate a superior software product. Although this giveaway pricedoes not deliver profits, if this price is the first step of a PP strategy, it could eventually generate profits ifmonopoly pricing is adopted after the advanced product is eliminated.

Part V: Conclusion

The software market is a typical new economy where competitors compete with innovative software. At thesame time, the high innovation costs act as high barriers for market entry. Thus, the network effects have thefunction of both tipping the market toward a single dominant network and imposing high switching costs onconsumers. As a result, there is a greater danger of PP in this new economy than in the old industries.115

Because the software market is a complex market competition environment, PP is a temptation for the dom-inant supplier to adopt when targeting more efficient suppliers, as a more efficient supplier can easily formits own network by adopting a selective giveaway or market penetration strategy that targets the customersfrom a dominant network. Once such a competitor gains the minimum mass for a network, it will be difficultfor the dominant supplier to maintain its dominant position. To lose a dominant network means the loss of adominant position, although the supplier may have recovered its costs or gained profits from previous cus-tomers. Thus, PP is favoured as a strategy for preventing small competitor networks from competing withthe predator in the future.

At the same time, below-cost pricing is common in software sales, as most of these below cost pricing is theresult of efficiency or an important step towards efficiency. Therefore, competition law should allow theseefficiency-related low prices, as they help to achieve both a low price for consumers and accelerate competi-tion. Additionally, because price competition is a secondary choice in software market competition, compet-ition law would benefit from adopting more lenient policies towards these low prices.

In identifying PP in the software market, competition enforcement will have difficulty distinguishing PPfrom reasonable below-cost pricing. As the marginal cost of software is negligible, a zero price or negativeprice for market promotion may appear to be risky. However, in fact, such prices are reasonable. For in-stance, without these prices, it is nearly impossible to establish a network in a market with a competingdominant network.116 It is also difficult to assess the cost-price relationship of a software product, as this

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 19

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 20: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

relationship is subject to the demand elasticity and common costs generated in multi-product operating.Thus far, the LAIC is a suitable cost benchmark for assessing the cost-price relationship of a softwareproduct because it can both reflect the substantial part of the innovation cost and specify the per unit costs.

E-mail: [email protected]. The author is thankful to Prof. Dr. Yuwen Li for her helpful comments.

1. Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co v Zenith Radio Corp 475 U.S. 574, 589-90 (1986).2. Brooke Group Ltd v Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp 509 U.S. 209 (1993 at II A [9][10][11]. As Pro-fessor Hovenkamp points out, “[i]ntent to ‘exclude’ is consistent with both efficient practices (research anddevelopment) and inefficient ones (predatory pricing).” See Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy(West Publishing Co., 1994), p.252.3. Gorge A. Hay, “The economists of predatory pricing” (1982) 51 Antitrust L.J. 361-374.4. The author writes this description generally based on the following literature: Roland H. Koller, “TheMyth of Predatory Pricing: An Empirical Study” (1971) 4 Antitrust L. & Econ. Rev.; McGee, “PredatoryPrice Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case” (1958) I J.L. & ECON. 137; McGee, “Predatory Pricing Revis-ited” (1980) 23 J.L. & ECON. 289; R. Bork, “The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself” (2001) 20Management science; Brodley & Hay, “Predatory Pricing: Competing Economic Theories and the Evolutionof Legal Standards” (1981) 66 Cornell L.Rev. 738; George A. Hay, A Confused Lawyer's Guide to the Pred-atory Pricing Literature, in Strategy, Predation, and Antitrust Analysis (1981), p.155; Easterbrook,“Predatory Strategies and Counterstrategies” (1981) 48 U Chi L Rev 263, 268.5. Matsushita 475 U.S. 574, 589-90 (1986).6. Matsushita Electric Industrial Co v Zenith Radio 475 U.S. 590, Supreme Court Reporter, 1357 (1986).7. David M. Kreps and Robert Wilson, “Reputation and Imperfect Information” (1982) 27 J. Econ. Theory253, 256; Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, “Predation, Reputation, and Entry Deterrence” (1982) 27 J. Econ.Theory 280.8. L. G. Telser, “Cutthroat Competition and the Long Purse” (1966) 9 J.L. & Econ. 267; see also J.S.McGee,“Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (NJ.) Case” (1958) 1 Journal of Law and Economics 137.9. Michel Poitevin, “Financial signaling and the ‘deep-pocket’ argument” (1989) 20 RAND Journal of Eco-nomics 26.10. US case, Utah Pie Co v Continental Baking Co 386 U.S. 685 (1967) and 23 cases were adjudged to haveengaged in predation that Roland H. Koller II statisticed in article “The Myth of Predatory Pricing: An Em-pirical Study” (1971) 4 Antitrust L. & Econ. Rev. 105. EU: Hoffman-La Roche v Commission (85/76) [1979]E.C.R. 461; AKZO Chemie v Commission (C-62/86) [1991] E.C.R. I-3359.11. Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd edn (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p.207. “Predatory pri-cing depends on the purchaser's willingness to buy from the predator (or the intended victim) at the predat-ory price”.12. J.B. Baker and T.F. Bresnahan, “Empirical Methods of Identifying and Measuring Market Power”(1993) 61 Antitrust Law Journal. Competition will keep the price at the competitive level, close to cost. Seealso Richard S. Markovits, “Oligopolistic Pricing Suits, the Sherman Act, and Economic Welfare A Re-sponse To Professor Posner”, (1976) 26 Stanford Law Review 493. Their competitive advantages wouldmake such behaviour profitable even if they assumed that he would set his price equal to his marginal costs.For economic analysis see Agnar Sandmo, “On the Theory of the Competitive Firm Under Price Uncer-tainty” (1971) 61 The American Economic Review 66-68.13. Guido Calabresi, “The Cost of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis” (1966) 9 Journal of Law andEconomics 259. Michel Poitevin, “Financial Signalling and the ‘Deep-Pocket’ Argument” (1989) 20 TheRAND Journal of Economics 26.14. Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union art.102. “Any abuse by one or more undertakings of adominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 20

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 21: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States … ”15. 15 U.S.C.A. § 2.16. 15 U.S.C. §§ 12, 14-27, 44 (1970).17. The Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union art.102.18. Most other courts use numbers in the same range, with a few indicating that a rising market share is astronger indicator of sufficient power. Herbert Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competi-tion and Its Practice, 3rd edn (Thomson/West, 2005), p.287.19. United States Court of Appeals, Fourth Circuit 981 F.2d 160 (1992).20. DG Competition discussion paper on the application of Article 82 of the Treaty to exclusionary abuses,p.31 (2005).21. Hoffmann-La Roche v Commission (85/76) [1979] E.C.R. 461 at 40.22. Standard Oil Co of New Jersey v U.S. 221 U.S. 1 (1911).23. Utah Pie v Continental Baking Co 386 U.S. 685 (1967).24. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review 697.25. A.A. Poultry Farms, Inc v Rose Acre Farms, Inc 881 F.2d 1396, 1401 (7th Cir.1989); Morgan v Ponder892 F.2d 1355 (8th Cir. 1989); AKZO [1991] E.C.R. I-3359, para. 65: The exclusionary consequences of aprice-cutting campaign by a dominant producer might be so self-evident that no evidence of intention toeliminate a competitor is necessary.26. U.S. v Aluminum Co of America 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945).27. California Computer Products Inc v International Business Machines Corp 613 F. 2d 727 (1979).28. California Computer Products Inc v International Business Machines Corp 613 F. 2d 727 (1979) at 31.29. AKZO [1991] E.C.R. I-3359, para.71.30. Brooke Group Ltd v Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp 509 U.S. 209 (1993).31. Brooke Group Ltd v Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp 509 U.S. 209 (1993).32. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review.33. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review 700.34. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review 717. If, however, price is below average variable cost at alllevels of output, the firm can minimise losses only by ceasing operations. Since the average cost of produc-tion of each unit is greater than the revenue realized from its sale, any output greater than zero increases thefirm's losses. At price P1 on the diagram in fn.14 supra, the loss-minimising firm will shut down.35. According to the Westlaw US case search, there are approximately 70 US federal and state cases usedvariable cost as a price floor between 1975 and 1993.36. D. Hurwitz and William E. Kovacic, “Judicial Analysis of Predation: The Emerging Trends” (1982) 35Vand. L. Rev. 140, 145 fn. 295 (success rate fell to 8%); see also Stephen C. Salop and Lawrence J. White,Private Antitrust Litigation: An Introduction and Framework in Private Antitrust Litigation: New Evidence,New Learning, 3, 42 (Lawrence J. White ed., 1988) (over roughly comparable period plaintiffs obtained fa-vourable judgments in 7 per cent of cases filed with predatory pricing claim, as compared with success rateof 11 per cent for all antitrust claims).37. Caller-Times Pub. Co Inc v Triad Communications, Inc 791 S.W.2d 163, 58 BNA USLW 2649, TradeCases P 69,004. FN3(1990).38. Cento Veljanovski, “Deterrence, Recidivism and European Cartel Fines” (2011) 7 Journal of competi-tion law & economics 871-915; Cento Veljanovski, “The Genesis of Cartel Investigations: Some Insightsfrom Examining the Dynamic Interrelationships between US Civil and Criminal Antitrust Investigations”(2007) 4 Journal of competition law & economics 61; Brian Coner Levin, “Killing Life Partners: Why Viat-ical Settlements Are Securities in Light of SEC v Mutual Benefits Corporation and Other Recent Cases That

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 21

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 22: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

Explicitly Reject SEC v Life Partners” (2006) 6 J. Bus. & Sec. L. 71.39. Williamson, “Predatory Pricing: A Strategic and Welfare Analysis” (1977) 87 YALE L.J. 311.40. Gorge A. Hay, “The economists of predatory pricing” (1982) 51 Antitrust L.J. 369.41. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review 697, 705. “… pricing behavior should be deemed non-predatory so long as the prices equal or exceed average total cost.”42. AKZO [1991] E.C.R. I-3359, para.72.43. AKZO [1991] E.C.R. I-3359, para.114.44. Richard Craswell and Mark R. Fratrik, “Predatory Pricing Theory Applied: The Case of Supermarkets vWarehouse Stores” (1985) 36 Case W. Res. L. Rev. 26.45. Guidance on its enforcement priorities in applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to abusive exclusionaryconduct by dominant undertakings [2009] OJ C 45, p.7-20, para.26.46. Sappington, David E.M & Sidak, J. Gregory, “Competition Law for State-Owned Enterprises” (2003) 71Antitrust L.J. 479.47. Average-incremental cost generally is the long-run figure obtained after plant and equipment are adjus-ted so as to minimise the average cost of the pertinent output. It is therefore often called long-run average in-cremental cost. David E.M Sappington and J. Gregory Sidak, “Competition Law for State-Owned Enter-prises” (2003) 71 Antitrust L.J. 479.48. 47 C. F. R. § 51.505.49. Forward-looking economic cost. (a) In general. The forward-looking economic cost of an element equalsthe sum of: (1) The total element long-run incremental cost of the element, as described in paragraph (b);and (2) A reasonable allocation of forward-looking common costs, as described in paragraph (c) … stan-dalone costs are the total forward-looking costs, including corporate costs, that would be incurred to producea given element if that element were provided by an efficient firm that produced nothing but the given ele-ment.50. AT&T Communications of Southern States, Inc v BellSouth Telecommunications, Inc 122 F.Supp.2d1305, N.D.Fla. (2000). See also Michigan Bell Telephone Co v Lark (NO. 06-11982) (2007); Bellsouth Tele-comm., Inc v Kentucky Pub. Serv. Comm'n 613 F.Supp.2d 903, E.D.Ky. (NO. CIV.A. 3:08-33-DCR) (2009).51. (COMP/35.141-Deutsche Post AG) [2001] OJ (L 125) 27, para.4.5.52. (COMP/35.141-Deutsche Post AG) [2001] OJ (L 125) 27, A.53. (COMP/35.141-Deutsche Post AG) [2001] OJ (L 125) 27, para.6.7.54. Joseph Farrell and Garth Saloner, “Standardization, compatibility and innovation” (1985) 16 RANDJournal of Economics 70; M. Katz and C. Shapiro, “Network externalities, competition and compatibility”(1985) 75 American Economic Review 424; Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd edn (University of Chica-go Press, 2003).55. Michael L. Katz and Carl Shapiro, “Antitrust in software markets” available at ht-tp://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/SHAPIRO/software.pdf, p.32 [Accessed July 5, 2012].56. J Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York, Harper & Row, Publishers, Inc, 1942);F Modigliani, “New Developments on the Oligopoly Front” (1958) 66 Journal of Political Economy 215.See F.Etro, “Innovation by Leaders” (2004) 114 The Economic Journal 281; F.Etro, “Stackelberg Competi-tion with Endogenous Entry” (2002) mimeo, Harvard University, available at http://www.intertic.org[Accessed July 5,2012]; F.Etro, “Aggressive Leaders” (2006) 37 The Rand Journal of Economics.57. Joseph Forrell and Garth Solaner, “Competition, Compatibility and Standards: The Economics ofHorses, Penguins and Lemmings” (1986) UC Berkeley: Department of Economics, UCB. Retrieved from:http://escholarship.org/uc/item/48v4g4q1 [Accessed July 5, 2012]; David McGowan, “Regulating Competi-tion in the Information Age: Computer Software as an Essential Facility under the Sherman Act” (1995) 18Hastings Comm. & Ent. L.J. 771.58. U.S. v Microsoft Corp. 84 F.Supp.2d 9.(D.D.C. 1999).59. Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, Information Rules: a strategic guide to the network economy (Harvard

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 22

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 23: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

Business School Press, 1999), pp. 173-225. See also Mark A. Lemley and David McGowan, “Legal Implica-tions of Network Economic Effects” (1998) 86 Calif. L. Rev. 479. Erik Brynjolfsson and Chris F. Kemerer,“Network Externalities in Microcomputer Software: An Econometric Analysis of the Spreadsheet Market”(1996) 42 Management Science 1627. Neil Gandal, “Competing Compatibility Standards and Network Ex-ternalities in the PC Software Market” (1995) 77 The Review of Economics and Statistics. Mark Shurmer,“An investigation into sources of network externalities in the packaged PC software market” (1993) 5 In-formation Economics and Policy. Roman Beck, The Network(ed) Economy: The Nature, Adoption and Diffu-sion of Communication Standards (2006). A prominent example of a stable oligopoly is the operating sys-tem software market for computers with Microsoft Windows as the dominant standard and Linux, as well asMac OS for Apple Macintosh as sturdy clusters. Although Microsoft extended the positive feedback effectsof its standards by adding complementary applications (e.g., by integrating Windows Internet Explorer), itwas not able to displace its competitors completely. The former example indicates that standards on networkeffect markets can tend to lead to natural monopolies.60. U.S. v Microsoft Corp. 84 F.Supp.2d 9.(D.D.C. 1999) 72.61. U.S. v Microsoft Corp. 84 F.Supp.2d 9.(D.D.C. 1999) at 372, 373. Judge Jackson found that the actualmarket share of Internet Explorer was greater than 60 per cent, and likely to continue to increase.62. Hongju Liu, “Dynamics of Pricing in the Video Game Console Market: Skimming or Penetration?”(2010) 47 Journal of Marketing Research 429, see table one.63. Peter Lawrence Swan, “Durability of Consumption Goods” (1970) 60 The American Economic Review891,892; Peter Lawrence Swan, “The Durability of Goods and Regulation of Monopoly” (1971) 2 The BellJournal of Economics and Management Science 356, 357; Peter Lawrence Swan, “Optimum Durability,Second-Hand Markets, and Planned Obsolescence” (1972) 80 Journal of Political Economy 582.64. R. H. Coase, “Durability and Monopoly” (1972) 15 Journal of Law and Economics 144, 148.65. Igal Hendel and Alessandro Lizzeri, “Alessandro, Interfering with Secondary Markets” 30 RAND Journ-al of Economics 3-10; Igal Hendel and Alessandro Lizzeri, “Adverse Selection in Durable Goods Markets”(1999) 89 The American Economic Review; Igal Hendel and Alessandro Lizzeri, “The Role of Leasing Un-der Adverse Selection” (2002) 110 Journal of Political Economy.66. Michael L. Katz and Carl Shapiro, “Antitrust in software markets” available at ht-tp://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/SHAPIRO/software.pdf, p.32 [Accessed July 5, 2012]; Jeffrey A. Eisenachand Thomas M. Lenard eds, Competition, Innovation and the Microsoft Monopoly: Antitrust, in The DigitalMarketplace (1999). See also Klaus M. Schmidt and Monika Schnitzer, “Public Subsidies for Open Source?Some Economic Policy Issues of the Software Market” (2003) 16 Harv. J. Law & Tec 473. Software is adurable good. Once installed, it could in principle run forever, and it “wears out” only due to technologicalchange.67. Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd edn (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p.246.68. Phillip Areeda and Donald F. Turner, “Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of theSherman Act” (1975) 88 Harvard Law Review 697, 711. Pricing at marginal cost is the competitive and so-cially optimal result.69. The innovation competition greatly resembles the innovation predation, which was introduced by JamesD.Hurwitz and William E. Kovacic, “Judicial Analysis of Predation: The Emerging Trends” (1982) 35Vand. L. Rev. 63. In the paper, they indicated that price predation works as a fake efficient cost reduction,while innovation predation works as a fake welfare enhancing innovation.70. U.S. v Microsoft Corp. 84 F.Supp.2d 9 (D.D.C. 1999).72.71. Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, Information Rules: a strategic guide to the network economy (HarvardBusiness School Press, 1999), p.178. Nintendo entered the US market for home video games in 1985, themarket was considered saturated, and Atari, the dominant firm in the previous generation, had shown littleinterest in rejuvenating the market. Yet by Christmas 1986, the Nintendo Entertainment System NES wasthe hottest toy on the market.72. Carl Shapiro, “Setting Compatibility Standards: Cooperation or Collusion?” available at ht-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 23

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 24: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

tp://haas.berkeley.edu/%EBshapiro/standards.pdf, p. 3 [Accessed July 5, 2012]. Similiar effects see:Douglas D. Leeds, “Raising the Standard: Antitrust Scrutiny of Standard-Setting Consortia in High Techno-logy Industries” (1997) 7 Fordham Intellectual Property, Media and Entertainment Law Journal 6; JeffreyChurch and Neil Gandal, “Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization” (1992) 40 The Journalof Industrial Economics 85; McKenzie and Melonie L, “How Should Competing Software Programs Marry -The Antitrust Ramifications of Private Standard-Setting Consortia in the Software Industry” (2002) 52 Syra-cuse L. Rev. 139. Mark A.Lemley, (2002) 90 “Intellectual Property Rights and Standard-Setting Organiza-tions”, available at http://escholarship.org/uc/item/776358p2 [Accessed July 5, 2012]; James J. Anton, andDennis A. Yao, “Standard-Setting Consortia, Antitrust, and High-Technology Industries” (1995) 64 Anti-trust L.J. 247.73. Note and legislation, “State Legislation Prohibiting Sales below Cost” (1939) 52 Harvard Law Review1143. See also Carl D. McDaniel and William R. Darden, Marketing (Allyn & Bacon, 1987), p.370. Loss-leader pricing “is an attempt … to induce store patronage through selling a product near cost or even belowcost to attract customers” who presumably will also purchase other goods at a profit.74. Carl D. McDaniel and William R. Darden, Marketing (Allyn & Bacon, 1987), p.370.75. Re Autodesk S.A. v E.C.C. (1999).76. Re Autodesk S.A. v E.C.C. (1999) at 1.77. Re Autodesk S.A. v E.C.C. (1999) 1, 14.78. Re Autodesk S.A. v E.C.C. (1999) 1.79. Re Autodesk S.A. v E.C.C. (1999) 1, 14.80. See California Unlawful Practices Act , Business and Professions Code § 1704. It is unlawful for anyperson engaged in business within this State to sell or use any article or product as a “loss leader” as definedin Section 17030 of this chapter. Section 17030: “Loss leader” means any article or product sold at less thancost: (a) Where the purpose is to induce, promote or encourage the purchase of other merchandise; or (b)Where the effect is a tendency or capacity to mislead or deceive purchasers or prospective purchasers; or (c)Where the effect is to divert trade from or otherwise injure competitors.81. Oklahoma Unfair Sales Act, Okla. Stat. Ann. tit. 15, § 598.3: It is hereby declared that any advertising,offer to sell, or sale of any merchandise, either by retailers or wholesalers, at less than cost as defined in thisact with the intent and purpose of inducing the purchase of other merchandise or of unfairly diverting tradefrom a competitor or otherwise injuring a competitor, impair and prevent fair competition, injure public wel-fare, are unfair competition and contrary to public policy and the policy of this act, where the result of suchadvertising, offer or sale is to tend to deceive any purchaser or prospective purchaser, or to substantiallylessen competition, or to unreasonably restrain trade, or to tend to create a monopoly in any line of com-merce.82. Wal-Mart Stores, Inc, v American Drugs, Inc, 319 Ark. 214, 891 S.W.2d 30 (1995).83. Wal-Mart Stores, Inc, v American Drugs, Inc, 319 Ark. 214, 891 S.W.2d 30 (1995).84. U.S. v Microsoft Corp 84 F.Supp.2d 9.(D.D.C. 1999).85. Andrew Watson, “Predatory Pricing in the Software Industry” (1998) Rutgers L. Rec - litigation-essen-tials.lexisnexis.com; Thomas W. Hazlett, “Microsoft's Internet Exploration: Predatory or Competitive”(1999) 9 Cornell J. L. & Pub. Pol'y. 29.86. Max Schanzenbach, “Network Effects and Antitrust Law: Predation, Affirmative Defenses, and the Caseof U.S. v Microsoft” (2002) Stanford Technology Law Review 4.87. Richard J.Gilbert and Michael L,Katz, “An Economist's Guide to U.S. v Microsoft” (2001)15 Journal ofEconomic Perspectives 35.88. Richard J.Gilbert and Michael L,Katz, “An Economist's Guide to U.S. v Microsoft” (2001)15 Journal ofEconomic Perspectives 37-40.89. 253 F.3d 34, 346 U.S.App.D.C. 330, Trade Cases P 73,321. at 32(2001). The rare case of price predationaside, the antitrust laws do not condemn even a monopolist for offering its product at an attractive price, andwe therefore have no warrant to condemn Microsoft for offering either IE or the IEAK free of charge or

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 24

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 25: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

even at a negative price.90. Stanley M. Besen & Joseph Farrell, “Choosing How to Compete: Strategies and Tactics in Standardiza-tion” (1994) 8 The Journal of Economic Perspectives 122.91. Michael L Katz and Carl Shapiro, “Technology Adoption in the Presence of Network Externalities”(1986) Journal of Political Economy. Penetration pricing seems a natural strategy in network industries, andappears prominently in the theory.92. Joseph Farrell, “Standardization and Intellectual Property” (1989) 30 Jurimetrics Journal 43.93. Patrick Bolton, Joseph F. Brodley and Michael H. Riordan, “Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory andLegal Policy” (2000) 88 The Georgetown law journal. Tasty-Frozen, a leading manufacturer of frozen piz-zas, develops a new kind of cheese that retains its flavor and texture much better than that of other frozenpizzas … To convince consumers that the new pizza tastes better, Tasty-Frozen considers in-store sampling… At the end of the three months of promotion, Tasty-Frozen raises its price. Consumers remain loyal, hav-ing come to appreciate the new pizza's improved taste. While the manufacturer sustained large losses duringthe three-month promotional period, after that time, the firm earns substantial profits from both its higherprices and economies of scale.94. A. Douglas Melamed, “Network Industries and Antitrust” (1999) 23 Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'y. Networkindustry entry barriers make predatory strategies for excluding or weakening marketplace rivals more feas-ible. See also U. Johansson and U. Elg, “Relationships as entry barriers: a network perspective” (2002) 18Scandinavian Journal of Management 395. The use of a network perspective can bring new insights to bearon entry barriers to markets at the level of the firm and can complement and enhance Porter's view of entrybarriers in important aspects.95. Robert D. Hof, “Netspeed At Netscape” (1997) Business Week 38.96. Hazlett and W.Thomas “Microsoft's Internet Exploration: Predatory or Competitive” (1999) 9 Cornell J.L. & Pub. Pol'y. 42.97. S. Lehmann and P. Buxmann, “Pricing Strategies of Software Vendors” (2009) 1(6) Bus Inf Sys Eng458.98. Carl Shapiro and Hal R. Varian, Information Rules: a strategic guide to the network economy (HarvardBusiness School Press, 1999), pp.292-293.99. Microsoft penetration pricing practices are: Microsoft's first step was to make Internet Explorer availablefree on-line. This tactic made a lot of sense as part of Microsoft's catch-up strategy. In fact, Microsoft hasgone even further, actually paying OEM's and ISPs to give preference to Internet Explorer over Navigator,by making Internet Explorer the “default” browser. The company has also publicly stated that explorer willbe free “now and in the future,” an obvious attempt at expectations management. Carl Shapiro and Hal R.Varian, Information Rules: a strategic guide to the network economy (Harvard Business School Press,1999), pp.292-293. Case study please Ie Storis, Inc v GERS Retail Systems, Inc 1995 WL 337100 (D.N.J.).Defendants GERS Retail Systems Inc, distributed retail stores aids computer software by mail, to PlaintiffStoris' customers only, a brochure which stated: “If you're looking for the most advanced retail system andyou don't think your Storis system is it, then do we have a great deal for you! … Trade-in your Storis soft-ware for free Sequel system software … and if you'd like one of our optional modules that you don't alreadyhave--we'll give it to you for 50% off!”100. T. P. Wright, “Factors Affecting the Cost of Airplanes” (1936) 3 Journal of Aeronautical Sciences,quoting Kenneth J. Arrow, “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing” (1962) 29 The Review ofEconomic Studies 156; H.Asher, Cost-Quantity Relationships in the Airframe Industry (Santa Monica: TheRand Corporation, 1956); A.Alchian, “Reliability of Progress Curves in Airframe Production” (1963) 31Econometrica 679.101. T. P. Wright, “Factors Affecting the Cost of Airplanes” (1936) 3 Journal of Aeronautical Sciences,quoting Kenneth J. Arrow, “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing” (1962) 29 The Review ofEconomic Studies 156.102. Nancy L. Stokey, “Learning by Doing and the Introduction of New Goods” (1988) 96 Journal of Polit-

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 25

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 26: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

ical Economy 701. A dynamic general equilibrium model is developed in which goods are valued accordingto the characteristics they contain, the set of goods produced in any period is endogenously determined, andlearning by doing is the force behind sustained growth. It is shown that the set of produced goods changes ina systematic way over time, with goods of higher quality entering each period and those of lower qualitydropping out; Wesley M. Cohen and A.Daniel “Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R & D” (1989)99 The Economic Journal 596. The ease and character of learning within an industry will both affect R&Dspending and condition the influence of appropriability and technological opportunity conditions on R&D.Ricardo Cabral and J.Michael, “Adoption of a Process Innovation with Learning-by-Doing: Evidence fromthe Semiconductor Industry” (2001) 49 The Journal of Industrial Economics 278. Different types of know-ledge may be accumulated with experience in each given generation of semiconductor technology.103. Alwyn Young, “Invention and Bounded Learning by Doing” (1993) 101 Journal of Political Economy443. Models of endogenous technical change fall into two broad, and yet surprisingly disjoint, categories.On the one hand, there are models of “invention” (e.g. Romer 1990; Segerstrom, Anant and Dinopoulous,1990; Grossman and Helpman, 1991), in which technical change is the outcome of costly and deliberativeresearch aimed at the develop-ment of new technologies. On the other hand, there are models of “learning bydoing” (e.g. Arrow, 1962; Lucas, 1988) in which technical change is the serendipitous by-product of experi-ence gained in the production of goods.104. E.S.Brezis, “Economic growth, leadership and capital flows: the leapfrogging effect” (1998) 7 Thejournal of international trade & economic development 26; Elise S. Brezis, Paul R. Krugman and DanielTsiddon, “Leapfrogging in International Competition: A Theory of Cycles in National Technological Lead-ership” (1993) 83 The American Economic Review 1211.105. US Department of Justice.106. Kenneth Flamm, Mismanaged trade: Strategic policy in the semiconductor industry (Washington:Brookings Institution, 1996), Chs one and two.107. In which learning economies and scale economies, as well as capacity constraints, are important. I ap-ply this model using empirical parameters relevant to the production of 1-megabit dynamic random accessmemories (lM DRAMs) … The resulting simulations produce more realistic outcomes than have earlier at-tempts to model semiconductor production. Precise specification of how learning economies operate is acrucial issue.108. Kenneth Flamm and Peter C. Reiss, “Semiconductor dependency and strategic trade policy” (1993)Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 252, 253.109. There are a lot of webpage reflecting Microsoft engaged in predatory pricing when selling its antivirussoftware. In which Microsoft were not considered have technique advantage among other suppliers. Justname a few: http://www.guardian.co.uk/technology/blog/2006/jun/21/microsoftaccus [Accessed July 5,2012]; http://www.zdnet.com/blog/spyware/microsofts-predatory-pricing-of-security-software/830[Accessed July 5, 2012]; http://www.gfi.com/blog/microsoft-practices-predatory-pricing/ [Accessed July 5,2012].110. H. Maura Lendon, “The Linux Revolution” (2000) 15 Intellectual Property Journal (part 7 b (i) Com-petitive Concerns in a Network Economy). See also Krina Griva and Nikolaos Vettas, “Price competition ina differentiated products duopoly under network effects” (2011) 23 Information Economics and Policy 86.When, in addition to horizontal characteristics, the products differ with respect to their qualities, we findthat, if the network effect is relatively weak, the high-quality firm captures a larger share of the market andthe low-quality firm a smaller one, depending on the quality difference. If the network effect is relativelystrong, either the low-quality firm or the high-quality firm may capture the entire market; however, for thelow-quality firm to capture the entire market, the quality difference cannot be too large relative to the net-work effect. A. Douglas Melamed, “Network Industries and Antitrust” (1999) 23 Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'y,The same demand-side economies of scale that induce the formation of a network in the first place can serveas barriers to competition against the network, even by those who might offer a superior alternative.111. Robert E. Bartkus, “Innovation Competition: Beyond Telex v IBM” (1976) 28 Stanford Law Review

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 26

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.

Page 27: E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 1 E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9 ...awa2013.concurrences.com/IMG/pdf/software_predatory_pricing_an… · The software market is a unique market in that pricing

285.112. Despite of both operating computer operating system and other utility software, Microsoft also engagedin antivirus software, mobile phone operating system software etc. Besides, its recent mergers for instanceSkype, Motorola and 3Com also indicate this trend.113. Max Schanzenbach, “Network Effects and Antitrust Law: Predation, Affirmative Defenses, and theCase of U.S. v Microsoft” (2002) Stanford Technology Law Review 4.114. Robert E. Bartkus, “Innovation Competition: Beyond Telex v IBM” (1976) 28 Stanford Law Review285.115. Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law, 2nd edn (University of Chicago Press, 2003), p.255; Michael L. Katzand Carl Shapiro, Antitrust in software markets, available at ht-tp://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/SHAPIRO/software.pdf [Accessed July 5, 2012]; A.Douglas Melamed,“Network Industries and Antitrust” (1999) 23 Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'y 151.116. Max Schanzenbach, “Network Effects and Antitrust Law: Predation, Affirmative Defenses, and theCase of U.S. v Microsoft” (2002) Stanford Technology Law Review 4, available at ht-tp://stlr.stanford.edu/2002/11/network-effects-and-antitrust-law/ [Accessed July 5, 2012]. Indeed, as de-scribed above, without penetration pricing it may be impossible for networks to form at all. George L Priest,“Rethinking Antitrust Law in an Age of Network Industries” Yale Law & Economics Research Paper No.352 (2007), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1031166 [Accessed July 5, 2012]. Thus, apparent belowcost pricing--that is, setting price below the cost of joining to the individual consumer--is essential in orderto create optimal network size.

END OF DOCUMENT

E.C.L.R. 2012, 33(9), 413-429 Page 27

(Cite as: )

© 2013 Thomson Reuters.