emanuel_behavioral economics and physician incentives

Upload: ethansong

Post on 20-Feb-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    1/24

    1

    Using Behavioral Economics to Design Provider Incentives

    that Deliver Higher Quality and Lower Cost Care

    Ezekiel J. Emanuela,b, Peter A. Ubelc, Judd B. Kesslerd,e, Gregg Meyerf, Ralph W.

    Mullere,g, Amol S. Navathee,h, Pankaj Pateli, Robert Pearlj, Meredith B. Rosenthalk, Lee

    Sacksi, Aditi P. Senb,e, Paul Shermanl, Kevin G. Volppa,b,e,h,m

    aDepartment of Medical Ethics and Health Policy, Perelman School of Medicine, University of

    Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; bDepartment of Health Care Management, The

    Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; cFuqua Business

    School and Sanford School of Public Policy, Duke University, Durham, North Carolina;

    dDepartment of Business Economics and Public Policy, The Wharton School, University of

    Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; eLeonard Davis Institute Center for Health

    Incentives and Behavioral Economics, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; fPartners Healthcare

    System, Boston, Massachusetts; gUniversity of Pennsylvania Health System, Philadelphia,

    Pennsylvania; hDepartment of Medicine, Perelman School of Medicine of the University of

    Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; iAdvocate Physician Partners, Chicago, Illinois;

    jThe Permanente Medical Group, Oakland, California; kDepartment of Health Policy and

    Management, Harvard School of Public Health, Boston, Massachusetts; lGroup Health,

    Seattle, Washington; mCenter for Health Equity Research & Promotion, Philadelphia

    Veterans Affairs Medical Center, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania

    WORD COUNT: 3,481

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    2/24

    2

    Funding: This paper was partially supported by a grant from the Commonwealth Fund.

    Corresponding Author:

    Ezekiel J. Emanuel, M.D., Ph.D.Telephone: 215-573-9384Email:[email protected]

    Conflict of Interest: Dr. Volpp is a principal in the behavioral economics consulting firmVALhealth. The other authors do not have any financial conflicts of interest.

    Some of the ideas delineated here were originally developed for the Kimball Lecture at theAmerican Board of Internal Medicine Foundation meeting in August 2013.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    3/24

    3

    ABSTRACT

    Behavioral economics can provide insights into how to improve the effectiveness of

    physician incentives to deliver higher quality and lower cost care. Lessons from

    behavioral economics suggest that the way in which incentives are structured and

    delivered can shape behavior, as can thoughtful design of the choice environment

    and infrastructure. We discuss nine principles of behavioral economics that can

    inform the design of financial and nonfinancial incentives, including inertia, loss

    aversion, choice overload, immediacy, and relative social ranking. These well-

    accepted principles have been applied widely to improve incentives in areas

    including personal health decisions, retirement planning, and consumer savings

    behavior, but have been largely ignored in the design of physician incentive

    programs. We argue that applying these principles to physician incentives can

    improve their effectiveness by making them more salient to physicians and better

    aligned with performance goals, without increasing their costs. We offer examples of

    programs that apply lessons from behavioral economics and specific design

    interventions to boost the effectiveness of financial incentives. The application of

    insights from behavioral economics to the design of provider incentives is largely

    untested and many outstandingquestions of design exist. We argue that a

    systematic approach to assessing infrastructure changes, non-financial incentives,

    and financial provider incentives is needed to design effective payment systems that

    incentivize high-quality, cost-conscious care.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    4/24

    4

    The American health care system is undergoing tremendous transition. The

    objective of this revolution is to control total health care costs while improving or

    maintaining quality of care. A fundamental aspect of the transition is payment

    reform.

    While fee-for-service payment (FFS) remains the dominant form of payment,

    the last few years have seen a major shift away toward alternative payment

    methods as highlighted by Secretary Burwells recent announcement that Medicare

    and Medicaid will be rapidly moving away from FFS in the next few years. There

    now are hundreds of organizations, such as hospitals and large physician groups

    functioning as accountable care organizations (ACOs), which are participating in

    shared-savings payment programs, in which savings from a calculated baseline are

    shared between providers and payers. Still others, including Pioneer ACOs, have

    two-sided risk contractsincreasing potential for financial gains if they control

    costs, but also taking financial risk if they fail to reduce costs. At the opposite end of

    the payment spectrum from FFS are fully capitated delivery systems, of which there

    are relatively few.

    Optimal provider payments will vary not only with an organizations position

    along the payment spectrum but also based on its particular mission, culture, local

    competitive environment, patient population, and contractual and financial

    relationship with providers. Each mode of payment incentivizes different provider

    behavior. Fee-for-service encourages overutilization of treatments, while capitation,

    in theory, rewards underutilization. To promote appropriate high-quality

    utilization informed by evidence-based guidelines, payers in FFS environments have

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    5/24

    5

    often supplemented their payment mechanisms with pay-for-performance. But to

    date, pay-for-performance has demonstrated little effect on physician behavior.1,2

    This result likely reflects at least in part the relatively small size of the financial

    incentives employed in most pay-for-performance programs to date.

    But it may also reflect that most provider payment programs have been

    exercising trial-and-error, uninformed by the best science of human motivation.

    Generally, efforts to reform provider payment have been built on the assumption

    that providers are largely rational and have not utilized insights from behavioral

    economics, which has documented many ways that people's behavior does not

    conform to rational norms..3,4The principles of behavioral economics have been

    successfully used in the design of patient incentives for smoking, substance abuse,

    obesity, and drug compliance.5-14Behavioral economics has also emphasized

    thoughtfully structuring the choice environment and the use of non-financial

    rewards and penalties to shape behavior.3,4,15,16

    To facilitate consideration of how behavioral economics could improve

    providers economic and non-economic incentives and as well as the practice

    environment, we describe selected behavioral economics principles and elucidate

    how they could inform the design of provider incentives. This guidance is

    inherently preliminary and speculative because there has been little use and

    evaluation of behavioral economics in provider payment schemes. We offer a

    tentative framework to stimulate more systematic use and testing of behavioral

    economics in the design of provider incentives.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    6/24

    6

    Behavioral Economics Principles: Nine Examples

    The scientific understanding of human motivation has evolved over the last

    30 years. Previously, much of economic theory was based on the assumption that

    providing information to rational actors would usually lead to optimal behavior. In

    this framework, the main driver of behavior is the size of the bonus or penalty

    relative to the effort required to achieve the goal. More recently, behavioral

    economics has revealed systematic ways in which human behavior is shaped not

    merely by the size of incentives, but also by their design and how they are delivered.

    For example, the same size incentive could have a significantly different impact on

    behavior depending on whether it is constant or intermittent, framed as a gain or

    loss, presented to people privately or in front of a group, and is perceived as fair or

    unfair.15,16Because humans often make decisions that seem inconsistent with

    getting the most from a fixed incentive, they often appear irrational from the

    perspective of standard economic theory.3,4,17

    Another important consideration is that people respond differently

    depending on what type of tasks are incented. For pro-social activities, like

    charitable giving, providing small incentives is likely to be worse than providing no

    incentive at all because this displaces intrinsic motivation without supplying much

    extrinsic motivation. In the realm of provider payment we are generally not

    discussing small incentives, but this highlights why programs like P4P that are

    grafted onto the FFS system may not work well and why alternative designs for

    provider payment and the embedded incentives are needed.18

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    7/24

    7

    To illustrate how behavioral economic concepts could be relevant in

    influencing provider performance, consider the following nine principles of

    behavioral economics (Table 1).

    1. Limitations of Information Provision:Although information is necessary

    for people to understand their options and to communicate social norms, it is

    rarely sufficient to induce behavior change. Smokers know that smoking

    causes illness. In fact, smokers may overestimate these risks.19But simply

    informing smokers rarely induces smoking cessation. Similarly, menu

    labeling is not always sufficient to lead people to significantly reduce the

    calories purchased.20Merely telling providers the goal of changes is unlikely

    to get them to change.

    2. Inertia:When making choices, people often demonstrate a status quo bias,

    following habits and settled practices which are typically the paths of least

    resistance.21It usually requires explicit efforts and policies, such as

    implementing new defaults, to change these habits and settled practices. For

    instance, physicians with an order entry system that defaults to generics

    rather than brand medications tend to order generics at higher rates.22

    Similarly, in the Netherlands, where people must take an explicit action to

    register as an organ donor, 27.5% of population does so. In neighboring

    Belgium, where people are automatically registered unless they actively

    refuse, 98% of Belgians are donors.23

    Inertia highlights the importance of setting up providers choice

    environments to make it easy to provide high quality, cost-effective care.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    8/24

    8

    Defaults on electronic health records, physician orders, or office flows should

    facilitate achieving performance metrics. For instance, when a systems

    oncologists agree to a preferred care pathway, a specific first-line

    chemotherapy regimen, and laboratory tests for metastatic lung cancer, it

    should be installed as the default in the physician order set within the

    electronic health record (EHR); thereby simultaneously reducing the need

    for providers to manually input orders and maximizing the likelihood

    patients will receive the best care. Changing the choice environment often

    requires some initial effort; in fee for service environments there has been a

    disincentive to change the choice environment toward high-quality, cost-

    effective care. Shifts in payments toward bundles or episode-based payments

    and population health will accelerate the use of defaults that can change

    settled practice to make it more cost effective.

    3. Choice Overload:More choice is not necessarily better. When confronted

    with too many selectionsor overly complicated optionspeople often

    avoid making choices.24,25 For instance, too many performance metrics, or

    too many patient alerts in the electronic medical record, can induce less

    rather than more behavior change.26 Choice overload suggests a challenge in

    determining the right number of metrics used to determine provider

    incentives. Too few can induce providers to focus only on those evaluated

    while too many can trigger inertia. Similarly, if clinicians face one set of

    metrics from one payer, and another set from another payer, they could face

    metric overload that causes them to ignore both sets of metrics.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    9/24

    9

    4. Immediacy:Immediacy enhances response and delayed gratification dulls

    impact. People tend to over-weight the immediate costs and benefits of their

    actions while discounting delayed benefits.27Consequently, when providing

    the same incentive, delayed gratification is usually less effective than

    immediate gratification.28 Similarly, when providing performance feedback,

    immediate information is more effective than delayed feedback in inducing

    behavior change. The optimal feedback frequency is unknown. Obviously,

    the value of immediacy needs to be balanced by the need for sufficient

    numbers of cases for statistical precision. Nevertheless, giving clinicians

    interim feedback monthly or quarterly, rather than annually, provides them

    an opportunity to modify their behavior and get quicker feedback on

    whether their modifications improve their performance measurement.

    5. Loss Aversion:How people feel about options can be strongly influenced by

    whether the options are framed as gains or losses. For example, people feel

    more positively about medical interventions described as providing 90%

    survival rates than ones described as having 10% mortality rates. Closely

    related is the endowment effect. Simply owning somethinga sports ticket

    or a mug increases its value to the person above its monetary value. Due to

    loss aversion and the endowment effect, people work harder to retain a

    provisionally awarded bonus than they do to receive a yet-to-be-awarded

    bonus. For instance, teacher performance in Chicago schools improved when

    they were awarded bonuses at the beginning of the year that were at-risk

    compared to teachers given year-end bonuses.29Similarly, the Massachusetts

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    10/24

    10

    General Hospital used loss aversion by giving an incentive to everyone in one

    year so that in the subsequent year it would feel like a loss not to get the

    incentive.30,31

    6. Relative Social Ranking:People are heavily influenced by their perception

    of how their performance compares to those around them. This influence

    has been shown in contexts ranging from giving people feedback on how

    their energy consumption compares to their neighbors to giving providers

    feedback on their relative performance to their peers.32-34Physicians highly

    value personal competitive success. This competitiveness can be deployed by

    using anonymous rankings or by distributing identified rankings to providers

    within ones group, or even to the general public. For example, Dean Clinic

    in Wisconsin found that releasing anonymous rankings had little impact on

    physician behavior while the release of monthly performance data by name,

    visible to every other Dean physician in their division, was much more

    effective (Allison Mooney, Dean Health System, personal communication). In

    addition, organizational awards, conferred publicly, for outstanding

    performance and ranking, emphasize the organizations norms and priorities

    while providing status and social recognition for physicians.

    7. Goal Gradients:As people approach a goal they try harder to achieve it. This

    has been observed with frequent flyer miles, rewards cards, and bonus cards

    for free coffee.35 Closely related is the threshold effect in which human

    behavior changes after a threshold is reached. For instance, people dont

    typically try as hard once they are above the threshold.36 One consequence is

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    11/24

    11

    that incentives may have to increase over time to encourage continued effort.

    Thus it can be important to recognize both achievement of absolute ranking

    and improvement in the rankings. Otherwise, poorer performers, concluding

    they cannot reach the targeted threshold, may become demoralized and stop

    trying to improve. Recognition of significant improvement in performance

    can mitigate this demoralization.

    8. Limits of Willpower:Exerting willpower tires people out and makes them

    less likely to exert effort on subsequent tasks.37 Thus, relying on providers

    vigilance to achieve optimal performance is unlikely to produce sustained

    improvement; providers tire from having to constantly focus and exert

    energy. Infrastructure that uses defaults to make the right action the path of

    least resistancewill keep providers from having to deplete willpower to

    continually remember to make the highest value choice.

    9. Mental Accounting and Salience:People react very differently to the same

    amount of payment if it is separate and visible as opposed to packaged

    together with much larger sums of money.38,39 A $100 incentive is more

    powerful if disbursed as a separate check than if it is folded into a paycheck

    and electronically deposited into a bank account. A 15.5% sin tax on

    unhealthy food is more effective when decoupled from the price of an entre

    than when folded into the total price of the dish.40

    These behavioral economics principles have been used with great effect in a

    variety of contexts ranging from consumer savings behavior, retirement planning,

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    12/24

    12

    personal health behavior, and enrollment in health insurance.14-16,41-45 To date they

    have been used by some health systems, but they have tended not to be

    systematically incorporated in the design provider incentive programs. However, as

    systems try to change provider behaviors to focus more on quality and cost-effective

    care, approaches informed by behavioral economics could make provider incentive

    and feedback programs more effective and efficient.

    Behavioral Economics and the Formulation of Financial and Non-Financial

    Incentives for Providers

    With few directly applicable studies, delineating the implications of these nine

    behavioral economics principles for the design of efforts to influence providers to

    provide higher value carewill inherently be theoretical and speculative.

    Nevertheless, the principles do suggest at least four broad lessons for designing

    such provider-focused initiatives (Table 2):

    1. The Limits of Information:Simply providing information to individual

    providers about the organizations goals or their own performance is

    unlikely to be sufficient to stimulate sustained behavior change.

    2. The Limits of Standard Economic Incentives:Standard economic

    incentives incorporated into fee-for-service reimbursement tend to

    encourage overuse of services and have been highly effective in doing so. P4P

    type programs within the US have not been effective in encouraging a focus

    on quality and cost-effective care, though much larger P4P incentives have

    been effective in the UK.46 Designing financial incentives that account for

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    13/24

    13

    common decision errors will likely have more impact in inducing providers

    to focus on quality and cost-effective care.

    3. The Importance of Infrastructure:Changing infrastructure to both remove

    barriers to optimal performance and make desired behaviors the default can

    effectively change behavior often without financial incentives.

    4. The Synergy of Incentives:Using non-financial incentives, such as social

    comparisons, and leveraging behavioral biases, such as loss aversion and

    immediacy, can stimulate behavior change alone and magnify the impact of

    financial incentives.

    To illustrate one of these lessons, the importance of synergy, Advocate used

    to release physician performance quarterly, but, because of immediacy, the results

    are now available on-line in real time. In addition, using the power of relative social

    ranking, individual performance rankings are visible to all providers in their

    practice group. Advocate also holds a public awards ceremony for outstanding

    performance annually where, invoking mental accounting and loss aversion, it

    distributes paper checks for rewards, including a report on unearned dollars and

    what would have needed to occur to receive the additional incentive (Pankaj Patel

    and Lee Sacks, Advocate Physician Partners, personal communication).

    These principles also suggest four specific interventions in the design of

    provider incentives and practice environments. First, the principle of choice

    overload highlights the importance of keeping financial incentives simple. Fee-for-

    service that incentivizes securing the highest possible RVUs has this virtue. In trying

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    14/24

    14

    to design incentives to reward high quality and cost consciousness, keeping it

    simple will be more challenging because of the need for sufficient measures to know

    quality has in fact improved.

    Second, mental accounting and relative social rank suggest that financial

    rewards should not just be folded into a regular paycheck and hidden from both the

    recipient and peers. For incentives to have their maximal impact, they should be

    given as a separate payment. Payment separated from the routine electronic

    paycheck deposit can enhance the impact of the incentive. For instance, the

    Massachusetts General Hospital prints checks and mails them home.30,31This allows

    the providers family to see the recognition and the financial payment and provide

    emotional reward to the provider. This can generally only be done with incentives

    that are structured as rewards and not penalties.

    Third, it could be important to deliver financial incentives at times when

    those incentives are particularly salient. For instance, Advocate pays its incentives

    around tax day, April 15th, and the Massachusetts General distributes checks at the

    start of December in time for the winter holiday shopping season.

    Finally, it is important to align provider financial incentives both with the

    incentives of their organization, with those of managers, and ideally with those

    faced by their patients. Aligning incentives between providers and their

    organizational leadership makes sense to facilitate coordination where there might

    otherwise be conflict in the choice of performance metrics and the necessary,

    infrastructure changes. Having benefit designs that reinforce the goals of the

    provider incentive system might be effective for health metrics, such as weight

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    15/24

    15

    control and medication adherence, that may be more under a patients control than

    a providers.

    Outstanding Issues in Applying Behavioral

    Economics to Provider Incentives

    The guidance from behavioral economics on provider incentives leaves much

    that is, as yet, empirically untested. Indeed, a major issue is which combination of

    infrastructure, non-financial and financial incentives works best in which types of

    health care organizations and at what stage along the payment spectrum. It is

    unlikely that the same combination of provider incentives will be effective in

    shifting physicians from fee-for-service to shared savings models as will be effective

    in shifting physicians from capitated models to models that emphasize quality of

    care. Determining which combination of incentives is optimal for different

    organizations is an important open question.

    A second unknown relates to the distribution of incentives between

    individual providers and their provider group. Achieving many performance metrics

    requires collaboration among providers and not just performance of individual

    providers. Yet incentives to individuals can drive individualistic behaviors that are

    inimical to the support of the group. Conversely, incentives to groups may not lead

    each group member to exert him- or herself as much as under an individual

    incentive program. Advocate began providing 70% of the incentive based on the

    individual providers performance and 30% based on his or her group. Conversely,

    the Permanente Medical Group allocates almost all incentive dollars at the

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    16/24

    16

    department or module level, limits the total dollars to less than 10% of annual

    salary, and applies them only to quality and service measures, not cost. It is not

    known whether dividing performance rewards between individuals and groups

    enhances performance, and whether the 70-30 or 90-10 split is optimal and needs

    study.

    Third, using incentives to induce cost consciousness raises public concerns

    about skimping on care. This may be one reason some health systems have focused

    provider incentives on improving quality and patient safety rather than reducing

    use of low value services. An important area for future development is to identify

    areas in which quality gaps and excessive costs coexist, so that changes in incentives

    could produce quality and cost saving outcomes simultaneously. Such examples

    might include the care of diabetic foot ulcers, medical interventions that are proven

    to be of equal clinical effectiveness in randomized trials but of lower cost, such as

    the use of hypofractionated radiation for early stage breast cancer, or in which cost

    savings do not affect quality, such as dispensing generics or 90 day supplies of

    medications.47,48

    Fourth, we should investigate the size of financial incentives needed to

    change different types of behaviors. In the Medicare Acute Care Episode bundled

    payment model, orthopedists were able to receive a maximum of 25% payment

    increase per procedure to improve their compliance with quality metrics.49 Other

    organizations have used 2%, 5%, or 20% of base salary, and for each of these

    approaches anecdotal evidence points to multiple successes.30Still others have

    offered set dollar amounts ranging from $1,000 to $5,000 per physician in annual

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    17/24

    17

    incentive payments. To move from anecdote to science, the association between the

    size of incentives and behavior change, and where there are diminishing returns,

    needs to be more rigorously evaluated.

    There are myriad other issues, three of which we mention here. Instituting

    an appeals process for providers is important as a signal that the social ranking and

    any other incentives are done fairly. Second is the question of when to retire a

    performance metric and its associated incentive. The optimal time is when the

    performance is hard wired and has become a habit or default behavior, requiring

    little or no willpower for adherence, or when it is literally built into the

    infrastructure, as in electronic prescribing. Practices which are supported by

    defaults are less likely to regress when no longer directly assessed or incentivized.

    Finally, the optimal combination of the different behavioral economics principles is

    unknown. It may be possible for health care organizations without significant

    financial resources to achieve substantial change in performance by focusing on

    infrastructure and non-financial incentives, such as changes in office flows and

    public recognition of superior performance, rather than financial incentives. Careful

    empirical testing of the potential synergy of different complementary strategies is

    imperative.

    American health care is undergoing significant change toward a greater focus

    on quality and cost-effective delivery of care. Many health systems now have

    contracts that link payment to demonstrably higher quality and lower costs. They

    are challenged by how to change providers behaviors to align with these new

    payment models. Hundreds of billions of dollars are spent annually in the US on

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    18/24

    18

    provider payment with only a small handful of trials and limited data providing

    guidance on how to optimally improve the outcomes of the payment system.

    Systematically incorporating the principles of behavioral economics could enhance

    the impact of provider payment systems to improve quality and reduce costs and

    pay enormous dividends. To move off haphazard approaches, we need a systematic

    program assessing infrastructure changes, non-financial incentives, and financial

    provider incentives so that by 2020, healthcare delivery systems can adopt proven

    incentive programs with a much better sense of the likely impact of those programs.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    19/24

    19

    TABLE 1: Principles of Behavioral Economics relevant to Provider Payment

    Principle Description Examples in Health and Health CareLimitations ofinformationprovision

    Providing information isnecessary and reflectssocial norms, but is rarelysufficient alone to inducebehavior change.

    Smoking: smokers know that smokingcauses cancer but many despite thatcontinue to smoke

    Menu labeling: In New York City, therewas no significant change in meannumber of calories purchased beforeand after menu labeling of calories.

    Inertia orstatus quo bias

    People tend to favor thestatus quo and current

    practices rather thaninitiating change.

    Generic prescribing: When genericsare the default in CPOE there is a

    significant increase in the prescriptionof generic drugs.

    Organ donation: When people mustactively sign up to donate organs ornot, such as in the Netherlands 27.5%of population does. In neighboringBelgium, organs are procured unlesspeople actively refuse. Consequently98% of Belgians are listed as donors.

    Choiceoverload

    Too many choice optionsor too complex choicesinduce paralysis and lackof action. Fewer, simplechoices are more likely toinduce behavior change.

    Health plan choice: Choosing from theuniverse of health plans is difficultwithout someone prescreeningchoices and narrowing down thechoice to a smaller number

    Immediacy People respond morestrongly to immediateincentives rather thandelayed incentives.

    Using the gym: People are more likelyto go to the gym if given feedbacktoday rather than at the end of theyear

    Loss aversion People react more stronglyto the same situation,framed in terms of losses,than framed in terms ofgains

    Physician bonuses: Paying providers abonus at the end of the year may beless effective than giving them thebonus at the beginning of the year andmaking keeping it conditional onimprovement in performance

    Relative socialranking

    People care about howthey compare to others

    Release of provider performance data:Providers do not want to be viewed as

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    20/24

    20

    especially when thosepeople are known and inclose proximity to them.

    a low performer relative to their

    peers.

    Goal gradientsand threshold

    effects

    People try harder whenthey are close to achieving

    a goal and tend not to tryas hard far from the goal.

    Provider performance effort:Providers who are near a threshold

    target (e.g. 80% of patients who getbeta blockers) will try hard to getthere; those who are far away willview the goal as too difficult to reach

    Limits ofwillpower

    Willpower is anexpendable resource. Themore people need toexercise willpower in oneactivity, they less likelythey are to have willpowerin other activities.

    Provider effort: Having to constantlyremember to prescribe a generic isless likely to be effective than settingthis up as a default within an EMR

    Mentalaccounting andsalience

    The incentive is stronger ifgiven distinctly andexplicitly rather thanfolded into a regularpaycheck.

    Distributing provider financialbonuses: $1,000 in a separate check ismore noticeable than $1,000electronically deposited as part of apaycheck

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    21/24

    21

    Table 2: Four Lessons from Behavioral Economics Principles

    Lesson Description

    The limits of information Providing information aboutperformance goals or optimal

    performance is likely to beinsufficient to stimulate sustainedbehavior change.

    The limits of standardeconomic incentives

    Common decision errorssuch asloss aversionpowerfully influencehuman behavior and poorly designedfinancial incentives will be less potentthan ones that account for sucherrors.

    The importance ofinfrastructure

    Changing infrastructure to bothremove barriers to optimal

    performance and make desiredbehaviors the default can effectivelychange behavior often withoutfinancial incentives.

    The synergy of incentives Leveraging non-financial incentivesand behavioral biases can bothstimulate behavior change alone andmagnify the impact of financialincentives.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    22/24

    22

    REFERENCES

    1 Rosenthal MB, Frank RG, Li Z, and Epstein AM. Early experience with pay-for-

    performance: From concept to practice.JAMA. 2005;294(14):1788-1793.2

    Rosenthal MB. Beyond pay for performanceemerging models of provider-payment reform. N Engl J Med. 2008;359(12):1197-1200.

    3 Thaler RH and Sunstein CR. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth,

    and Happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press, 2008.4 Kahneman D. Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux,

    2011.5 Volpp KG, Troxel AB, Pauly MV, et al. A randomized controlled trial of financial

    incentives for smoking cessation. N Engl J Med. 2009;360:699-709.6 Donatelle RJ, Hudson D, Dobie S, Goodall A, Hunsberger M, and Oswald K.

    Incentives in smoking cessation: Status of the field and implications for researchand practice with pregnant smokers. Nicotine & Tobacco Research.

    2004;6(2):S163S179.7 Volpp KG, John LK, Troxel AB, Norton LA, Fassbender JE, and Loewenstein G.

    Financial incentive-based approaches for weight loss: A randomized trial.JAMA.2008;300:2631-2637.

    8 Volpp KG, Loewenstein G, Troxel AB, et al. A test of financial incentives to

    improve Warfarin adherence. BMC Health Serv Res. 2008;8:272.9 Sutherland K, Christianson JB, and Leatherman S. Impact of targeted financial

    incentives on personal health behavior: A review of the literature. Med Care ResRev. 2008;65.6 suppl:36S-78S.

    10 Giuffrida A and Torgerson DJ. Should we pay the patient? Review of financial

    incentives to enhance patient compliance. BMJ. 1998;315(7110):703-707.

    11

    Kane RL, Johnson PE, Town RJ, and Butler M. A structured review of the effect ofeconomic incentives on consumers' preventive behavior.Am J Prev Med.2004;27(4):327-352.

    12 Stitzer ML, Petry NM, and Peirce J. Motivational incentives research in the

    National Drug Abuse Treatment Clinical Trials Network.J Subst Abuse Treat.2010;38(Suppl. 1):S61-69.

    13 Jeffery RW, Gerber WM, Rosenthal BS, Lindquist RA. Monetary Contracts in

    Weight Control: Effectiveness of Group and Individual Contracts of Varying Size.J Consult Clin Psychol. 1983;51(2):242-248.

    14 Jeffery RW. Financial incentives and weight control. Prev Med. 2012;55:S61-S67.

    15 Loewenstein G, Asch DA, and Volpp KG. Behavioral economics holds potential to

    deliver better results for patients, insurers, and employers. Health Aff(Millwood).2013;32(7):1244-1250.

    16 Volpp KG, Pauly MV, Loewenstein G, and Bangsberg D. P4P4P: An agenda for

    research on pay-for-performance for patients. Health Aff (Millwood).2009;28(1):206-214.

    17 Ariely D. Predictably Irrational. New York: HarperCollins, 2008.

    18 Gneezy U and Rustichini A. Pay enough or dont pay at all. Quarterly Journal of

    Economics. 2000;115(3):791-810.

  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    23/24

    23

    19 Viscusi WK. Do smokers underestimate risks?Journal of Political Economy.

    1990;98(6):1253-1269.20

    Elbel B, Kersh R, Brescoll VL, and Dixon LB. Calorie labeling and food choices: Afirst look at the effects on low-income people in New York City. Health Aff(Millwood).2009;28(6):w1110-w1121.

    21

    Samuelson W and Zeckhauser R. Status quo bias in decision making.Journal ofRisk and Uncertainty. 1988;1(1):7-59.

    22 Patel M, Day S, Small D, and Volpp KG. Using default options to improve health

    care value by reducing the use of brand name medications with existing genericequivalents.Ann Intern Med.2014; in press.

    23 Johnson EJ and Goldstein DG. Do defaults save lives? Science. 2003;302(5649):

    13381339.24

    Iyengar SS and Lepper MR. When choice is demotivating: Can one desire toomuch of a good thing?J Pers Soc Psychol. 2000;79(6):995-1006.

    25 Redelmeier DA and Shafir E. Medical decision making in situations that offer

    multiple alternatives.JAMA. 1995;273(4):302-305.

    26

    Van der Sijs H, Aarts J, Vulto A, and Berg M. Overriding of drug safety alerts incomputerized physician order entry.J Am Med Inform Assoc. 2006;13(2):138147.

    27 ODonoghue Tand Rabin M. Doing it now or later.American Economic Review.

    1999;89(1):103-124.28

    Lussier JP, Heil SH, Mongeon JA, Badger GJ, and Higgins ST. A meta-analysis ofvoucher-based reinforcement therapy for substance use disorders.Addiction.2006;101(2):192-203.

    29 Fryer RJ, Levitt SD, List JA, and Sadoff S. Enhancing the efficacy of teacher

    incentives through loss aversion: A field experiment. NBER Working PaperNo.18237, 2012.

    30

    Torchiana DF, Colton DG, Rao SK, Lenz SK, Meyer GS, and Ferris TG.Massachusetts General Physicians Organizations Quality Incentive Program

    produces encouraging results. Health Aff (Millwood).2013;32(10):1748-1756.31

    Meyer GS, Torchiana DF, Colton D, et al. The use of modest incentives to boostadoption of safety practices and systems. In: Henriksen K, Battles JB, Keyes MA,Grady ML, editors.Advances in Patient Safety: New directions and Alternative

    Approaches.Vol. 3: Performance and tools [Internet]. Rockville (MD): Agency forHealthcare Research and Quality; 2008 Aug [cited 2014 Nov 6]. Available from:http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/n/aps2v3/advances-meyer_41/.

    32 Allcott H and Rogers T. The short-run and long-run effects of behavioral

    interventions: Experimental evidence from energy conservation.American

    Economic Review. 2014;104(10):3003-3037.33

    Ayres I, Raseman S, and Shih A. Evidence from two large field experiments thatpeer comparison feedback can reduce residential energy usage.Journal of Law,Economics, and Organization. 2013;29(5):992-1022.

    34 Kolstad J. Information and quality when motivation is intrinsic: Evidence from

    surgeon report cards.American Economic Review. 2013;103(7):2875-2910.35

    Hull CL. The goal-gradient hypothesis and maze learning. Psychological Review.1932;39(1):2543.

    http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/n/aps2v3/advances-meyer_41/http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/n/aps2v3/advances-meyer_41/http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/n/aps2v3/advances-meyer_41/
  • 7/24/2019 Emanuel_Behavioral Economics and Physician Incentives

    24/24

    36 Lacetera N and Macis M. Social image concerns and prosocial behavior: Field

    evidence from a nonlinear incentive scheme.Journal of Economic Behavior &Organization. 2010;76(2):225-237.

    37 Baumeister RF, Bratslavsky E, Muraven M, and Tice DM. Ego depletion: Is the

    active self a limited resource?J Pers Soc Psychol. 1998;74(5):1252-1265.38

    Thaler R. Mental accounting matters.Journal of Behavioral Decision Making.1999;12(3):183206.

    39 Thaler R. Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science.

    1985;4(3):199-214.40

    Shah AM, Bettman JR, Ubel PA, Keller PA, and Edell JA. Surcharges plus unhealthylabels reduce demand for unhealthy menu items.Journal of Marketing Research.2014;51(6):773-789.

    41 Choi JJ, Laibson D, Madrian BC, and Metrick A. Optimal defaults.American

    Economic Review. 2003;93(2):180-185.42

    Madrian BC and Shea DF. The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k)participation and savings behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics.

    2001;116(4):1149-1187.43

    Petry NM, Rash CJ, Byrne S, Ashraf S, and White WB. Financial reinforcers forimproving medication adherence: Findings from a meta-analysis.Am J Med.2012;125(9):888-896.

    44 Baicker K, Congdon WJ, and Mullainathan S. Health insurance coverage and take-

    up: Lessons from behavioral economics. Milbank Q. 2012;90(1):107-134.45

    Frank RG. Behavioral Economics and Health Economics. NBER Working PaperNo. 10881, 2004.

    46 Roland M and Campbell S. Successes and failures of pay for performance in the

    United Kingdom. N Engl J Med. 2014;370(20):1944-1949.47

    START Trialists Group,Bentzen SM, Agrawal RK, et al. The UK Standardarisation

    of Breast Radiotherapy (START) Trial A of radiotherapy hypofractionation fortreatment of early breast cancer: A randomised trial. Lancet Oncol.2008;9(4):331-341.

    48 Gagne JJ, Choudhry NK, Kesselheim AS, et al. Comparative effectiveness of

    generic and brand-name statins on patient outcomes: A cohort study.Ann InternMed. 2014;161(6):400-407.

    49

    Acute Care Episode Demonstration Fact Sheet, [Internet]. Woodlawn (MD):

    Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services; [cited 2014 Nov 6]. Available from:http://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdf;FrequentlyAsked Questions about the Acute Care Episode (ACE) Demonstration,[Internet].

    Woodlawn (MD): Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services; 2008 Jul [cited2014 Nov 6]. Available from:http://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdf.

    http://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEMoreInfo.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdfhttp://www.cms.gov/Medicare/Demonstration-Projects/DemoProjectsEvalRpts/Downloads/ACEFactSheet.pdf