innovation lit review

Upload: tyson-smith

Post on 05-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    1/34

    Innovation and R&Ds effects on firm success, methods

    of R&D, first mover effects,

    And the anchor-tenant hypothesis

    Tyson Smith

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    2/34

    Introduction:

    This paper will serve as an annotated bibliography/literature review of the various effects of

    innovation and research and development. Topics included will be the curse of the first -

    mover, competition and policys effect on innovation, incremental innovation vs. pure

    innovation, the effects of an anchor-tenant or a large firm with positive externalities,

    collaborative or cooperative R&D vs. in-house R&D and outsourced R&D, how a small firms

    approach to R&D effects their success, value of consumer innovation and its potential to

    benefit firms, and the effect of venture capital on R&D.

    Methodology:

    This paper will summarize and conglomerate previous works with mostly survey data from the

    US and the UK. Data collection and analysis will be summarized for the individual papers.

    Papers include (but are not limited to):

    Gourville (2005), Rayna & Striukova (2009), Banbury & Mitchell (1995), Von Hippel (2005), , von

    Hippel, de Jong & Flowers (2011), Ahn (2003), Agrawal & Cockburn (2003), Cassiman &

    Veugelers (2002), Sampson (2003), Baldwin (1995), Kortum & Lerner (2008).

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    3/34

    Summary of Findings:

    The curse of the first-mover is a result of reference dependence, loss aversion, and the

    endowment effect. Incremental innovation is strongly positively related to market share; the

    greater number of incremental innovations a firm is first to the market with, adopts an

    innovation within 4 years of the original release, and the sooner the firm adopts an innovation.

    Lead-user driven R&D results in significantly more novel ideas, addressed customer needs more

    effectively, and had a higher probability of success than non lead-user driven R&D. 6.1 percent

    of consumers in the UK create or modify the products they buy, of which only 2 percent protect

    their intellectual property, while 17 percent of the innovators diffused their ideas freely to

    others. R&D is positively related to innovation via number of patents to a certain level, then

    becomes negatively related after some maximizing point relative to firm size. Multifactor

    productivity is also positively related to R&D. Numbers ofeconomic regulations and barriers to

    trade are have a negative relationship with R&D, and thus decrease innovation. Anchor tenants

    have positive intellectual externalities on their surrounding area, having a direct positive effect

    on the numbers of papers published in the geographic area around them. Combining in-house

    R&D, working cooperatively with other firms on R&D, and purchasing external R&D increase

    number of innovative products released, and cooperation is most effective when the diversity

    of technologies between cooperating firms is intermediate. Small firms greatly underestimate

    the importance of R&D, and those who invest the most in their innovations have higher

    reported sales from new products.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    4/34

    Literature Review:

    Theory and Background: Curse of the First-Mover

    Gourville (2005) analyzes why highly innovative products fail at high rates, the so called

    curse of the first-mover. His argument is that there is a significant difference in perceived

    value of an innovative product between the consumers and the developers of the new product.

    He cites that according to Cierpicki, Wright, & Sharp (2000), 40 percent to 90 percent of new

    products fail to gain market acceptance. Gourville claims the effects most influential in

    innovation failures are reference dependence and loss aversion, with the endowment effect

    being the most revealing. He uses an experiment from Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (1990) to

    illustrate these effects in which students were split into two groups, where one group received

    a coffee mug and the other did not. Those who received the mugs were the sellers and were

    asked what amount of money they would sell the mug for, and those who did not receive mugs

    were the choosers and were asked how much they would spend for the mug. The median

    value for the sellers was $7.12 and was only $3.12 for the choosers, as the sellers have loss

    aversion for the value of the mug and the choosers have reference dependence relative to how

    much added value the mug would provide. Gourville outlines a behavioral model that shows

    the more that a customer would have to alter their behavior to use a new, innovative product,

    the lower the success rates, and incremental innovation has higher success rates than radical

    innovation.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    5/34

    Rayna & Striukova (2009) also analyze the curse of the first-mover and investigate the

    relations between both incremental and radical innovation on market dominance. They use a

    case study of four products of varying levels of innovativeness released by Apple, as well as

    using anecdotal evidence from several other companies. Rayna & Striukova believe that the

    determinants of a first-mover being cursed are technology maturity (the market has sufficient

    technology to utilize the innovative product), expertise of customers, network externalities

    (value attributed to a product is linearly related with the numbers of consumers using it),

    switching costs to adjust for competitor entry (Natural switching costs intrinsic to market:

    transportation, time, learning/training. Artificial switching costs created by firms: contracts

    with phone providers, know-how, cost of intellectual property rights, and complementary

    assets such as business partners, customers, reputation).

    They then proceed with the case study of Apples radical and incremental innovations.

    Lisa, the first PC with a GUI, failed because it cost far too much money - the equivalent of

    $20,893 today. There were no complementary assets, as third-party programmers chose the

    IBM PC model instead, and the only devices compatible were proprietarily Apple products. The

    Apple Newton was the first PDA, commercially released in 1993. The Newton was also too

    expensive, lacked compatibility with existing systems, and had high associated switching costs.

    Soon after, Palm released the Palm Pilot and though it was less technologically advanced, it was

    smaller and easier to use, and it soon dominated the market. Apples real success started with

    its incremental innovation, the iMac, in 1998. It used industry standard peripheral attachments

    (USB, Ethernet) and did essentially the same thing a PC did but in a more simplified and

    attractive manner, allowing for color customization. Even more successful was the iPod, an

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    6/34

    incremental innovation of an mp3 player released in 2001, four years after the first mass-

    produced mp3. It also did not revolutionize the product, just simplified it and made it more

    attractive. It was compatible with Macs and minimized switching costs by releasing a software

    update to allow it to work with PCs. The reduction of switching costs, increase of technological

    maturity, and decrease in required expertise of customers allowed the incremental innovations

    of Apple to gain significant market share.

    Effects of Incremental Innovation:

    Banbury & Mitchell (1995) looks at the effect of incremental innovation on market

    share, and how difference in market share changes how firms benefit from incremental

    innovation. They go into their data analysis with six hypotheses about incumbent firms:

    1) The more times they are the first to introduce incremental innovations, the greater

    their market share will be.

    2) The more times they adopt incremental innovations, the greater their market share

    will be.

    3) The sooner they introduce incremental innovations, the greater the market share.

    4) The more competitors that offer similar products, the smaller the incumbents market

    share.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    7/34

    5) Incremental innovation only influences business survival by changing the businesss

    market share.

    6) The more competitors that offer similar products, the more likely that an incumbent

    firm will shut down.

    To test their hypotheses, Banbury & Mitchell use data from the implantable cardiac

    pacemaker industry in America from 1960 to 1990, an industry with a high importance of

    product reliability. The data uses archival sources to document incremental innovation for

    pacemakers, which started in 1963, identifying 11 successful and revolutionary incremental

    innovations in the industry over the period. They used a generalized least squares linear

    regression to predict the dependent variable for market share, and the independent variables

    that were used were how many times out of 11 that the firm was the first to bring an

    innovation to market, how soon it was adopted, how many competitors adopted the innovation

    and how long it took them, total number of competitor introductions, market share at the time

    of the most recent innovation, and a lagged variable of the market share. The results can be

    seen in Table 1.

    Banbury & Mitchell find market share was greater the more times an incumbent was

    among the first to introduce one of the 11 incremental innovations. If a firm adopted an

    innovation within 2-3 years of its initial release, its market share increased. After the 4

    th

    year

    past introduction, adoption of the innovation has a negative relationship with market share.

    These results confirmed Hypotheses 1, 2, and 3. Hypothesis 4 does not hold until at least 4

    years after adoption, as the data shows that market shares were greater for firms that were the

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    8/34

    first to introduce innovations, even as the number of firms offering similar products increased

    for the first 4 years after introduction to the market. Other results seem counterintuitive, such

    as a positive relationship between competitive density and first to market against the negative

    relationship between competitive density and adoption of the innovation. This may be due to

    first movers capturing the majority of the market share before competitors can respond, and

    the late movers find it harder to attain market share.

    The Share at most recent introduction shows that market leaders are often the first to

    introduce incremental innovations to maintain their top spot. An incumbent firm gains long-

    term market share advantages from number of times first to market, while industry entrants

    with first to market innovations did not achieve any similar long term effects. Hypothesis 5 was

    tested by adding the lag share variable and results were consistent with the hypothesis,

    showing that introduction of incremental innovations does not decrease the likelihood of the

    business dissolving. Hypothesis 6 is tested by adding the competition variable, and is confirmed

    by the data which shows that the likelihood of a business shutting down increases as the

    number of firms offering similar products increases.

    Lead User R&D and Consumer Innovation:

    Von Hippel (2005) investigates the effects of lead user driven R&D and innovation. He

    cites his study from 2002, Lilien, Morrison, Searls, Sonnack and Von Hippel, which investigated

    the difference between 5 lead user research projects and 42 non lead user projects by the

    company 3M from February 1999 to May 2000. Results of this study can be found in Table 2.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    9/34

    They show that lead user projects were significantly more novel ideas, addressed customer

    needs more effectively, had higher probability of success, and most remarkably, the 5 lead user

    concepts accounted for $146 million in sales whereas the 42 non lead user concepts accounted

    for only $18 million in sales. Von Hippel also shows that users of many different products are

    innovating on their own and freely distributing their innovations. He cites Luthje (2003) which

    explored surgeons modifying their medical equipment in Germany. 262 surgeons responded to

    the questionnaire and 22 percent of those respondents indicated that they had developed or

    improved medical equipment on their own, and 48 percent of these innovations would soon be

    marketed and released by manufacturers of medical equipment.

    Von Hippel, de Jong, & Flowers (2011) is an investigation of the development and

    modification of consumer products in the UK via a phone survey of 1,173 UK consumers. 6.1

    percent of those surveyed say that they had created or modified products that they had used in

    the last 3 years and spend an estimated 3.2 billion annually, which is nearly one and a half

    times the R&D expenditures of all firms in the UK combined. 17% of the innovators surveyed

    diffused their ideas to other people. More impressive was that 90 percent of respondents

    reported developing their innovations entirely on their own. Only 2 percent of respondents

    formally protected their innovations with intellectual property rights, showing that the

    consumer innovators are willing to share their ideas and they think property rights protection

    ineffective or too expensive. The conclusion of the article calls for policy makers to account for

    consumer innovation in their countries and decrease costs of communication between

    innovators and institute policies to encourage diffusion of innovation.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    10/34

    Effects of regulation and R&D intensity on Innovation:

    Ahn (2003) is a massive literature review on innovation. The main conclusions are that

    competition enhancing policies cannot be measured with gains of efficiency in the short run,

    network effects and positive feedback effects make competition fierce and increase innovation,

    market concentration is not conducive to innovation (this contradicts the Anchor-Tenant

    hypothesis highlighted later in this paper), and firm dynamics are an important part of

    innovation and productivity growth.

    Ahn cites Bound et al (1984) and Pavitt et al (1987) that show that both very large and

    very small firms account for a large share of innovations. R&D intensity does not just increase

    with size of firm, and some data in Bound et al (1984) show that productivity declines after R&D

    increases to a certain level. This is shown in Graph 1, as patents per million R&D dollars

    decreases as the size of R&D increases. A study of 16 OECD countries from 1980-1998

    conducted by Guellec & de la Potterie (2001) showed that R&D increases multifactor

    productivity, shown in Table 3. According to their regression, 1 period-lagged Foreign R&D

    growth, 2 period-lagged Public R&D growth, 2 period-lagged Business R&D, and 3 period-lagged

    Public R&D are all positively correlated with multifactor productivity. Ahn also cites Bassanini &

    Ernst (2002) which found a negative correlation between R&D intensity and numbers of

    domestic economic regulations and non-tariff barriers to trade. These results can be found in

    Table 4, which illustrates that increasing regulation decreases R&D and thus innovation. This is

    backed up by Olley and Pakes (1996) which found that productivity in the telecommunications

    equipment industry saw significant increases in periods that decreased regulations.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    11/34

    Anchor-Tenant Hypothesis:

    Agrawal & Cockburn (2003) attempts to find support for the anchor-tenant hypothesis.

    The anchor-tenant hypothesis is that a large, local, R&D intensive firm will enhance the regional

    innovation system. They define an anchor-tenant as a firm that is heavily engaged in R&D and

    has some sort of absorptive capacity in a technological area. The idea is that the anchor-tenants

    will have significant positive externalities on smaller innovative firms. The data used were

    indicators of academic research activity among a sample consisting of 259 census metropolitan

    statistical areas (MSAs) in the US and Canada. Patent counts were used to measure industrial

    R&D and publication counts were used to measure university research activity. Comparisons

    between similar sized MSAs show the effects of anchor tenants.

    Analysis descriptive statistics of the data shows that counts of patents and papers are

    highly concentrated within a handful of MSAs, illustrated in Table 5. There are positive

    correlations between papers and patents across MSAs, showing a positive statistical

    relationship between levels of university research and levels of industrial R&D. Similar sized

    MSAs, such as LA and NY, can be compared to show large differences in industry patent

    numbers relative to the presence of anchor tenants, shown in Table 6. LA had 21 medical

    imaging industry patents whereas NY had 43, and the NY MSA contained two anchor tenants,

    IBM and Lucent Technologies, whereas LA had none. Similar comparisons could be seen with

    Pittsburgh not having an anchor tenant and only getting 1 industry patent, while Rochester,

    who has Eastman Kodak as an anchor tenant, received 34 industry patents over the same time

    period.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    12/34

    Agrawal & Cockburn then regress their ZIP (Zero-Inflated Poisson) model to find out the

    relationship between the presence of an anchor tenant within an MSA and the number of

    papers and patents coming from the MSAs, shown by Table 7. They find that for the three

    technology areas they focused on (medical imaging, signal processing, neural networks) that

    the coefficient on the interaction term between anchor tenants and papers are all positive and

    strongly significant, showing that the presence of an anchor tenant has a direct effect on

    numbers of papers published. To further test this hypothesis, Agrawal & Cockburn analyze a

    locational Gini coefficient, which measures the extent to which the distribution of paper

    publishing activity across geographical units strays from a uniform distribution. A Gini

    coefficient score of 0 shows that academic research is evenly distributed via geographical units,

    and a Gini coefficient score approaching .5 shows academic research that is highly concentrated

    in a single geographical unit. Their results are shown in Table 8. The locational Gini coefficients

    for all three technology areas are all above .4, which further backs up the hypothesis that

    academic research is focused around highly centralized areas around anchor tenants.

    Differences resulting from using multiple sources of R&D, including cooperative efforts:

    Cassiman and Veugelers (2002) investigate complementarity between different

    innovating activities using data from the Community Innovation Survey on Belgian

    manufacturing firms. A sample of 445 innovative Belgian firms from 1993 was used for analysis.

    The regressions analyze the differences in effectiveness of in-house R&D, purchased R&D, and

    different combinations of the two. To summarize the data, 81 percent of the innovating firms

    had their own internal R&D activities, 30 percent of firms had cooperative agreements with

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    13/34

    other firms, and 69 percent bought their R&D via external sources. 35 percent of firms both

    made and bought their R&D, 27 percent of firms made, bought, and cooperated with other

    firms for their R&D.

    Cassiman & Veugelers then regress their independent variables:

    SIZE (sales in 108

    1992 Belgian Francs), EMPL (# employees in 1992 in units of

    10), EXPINT (intensity of exports in 1992 exports/sales x 0.1), OBSTMARKET (scale of 1-5

    on market importance of innovation), OBSTTECHNOLOGY (scale of 1-5 of importance of

    lack of technological opportunities as barriers to innovation), PROTLEG (scale of 1-5 of

    effectiveness of patent effectiveness), PROTSTRAT (scale of 1-5 of effectiveness of

    secrecy as protection measure of innovation), PROTECTION (scale of 1-5 of effectiveness

    of patents, copyrights, registrations of brands as measure of innovation), BASICRD

    (importance for the innovation process of information from research institutes),

    OBSTRESO (scale 1-5 importance of lack of innovation as barrier to innovation),

    FREEINFO (importance of patents, conferences, publications as information sources for

    innovation), COMPINFO (scale 1-5 importance of competitors as information sources for

    innovation), Make&Buy R&D, MakeOnly, BuyOnly, NoMake&Buy, Make&Buy&Coop,

    Make&Coop, Buy&Coop, and INDUSTRY DUMMIES against the independent variable

    %SalesNewP (percentage of sales generated by new products within the past two

    years).

    EXPINT is the most highly correlated with a coefficient of .739, significant to the 5% level.

    Make&Buy R&D increases sales 13.9 percent, significant to the 5% level. Make&Buy&Coop

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    14/34

    increased sales 12.6 percent, significant to the 10% level. They go on to do a multinomial logit

    model, which shows that firm size positively affects all combinations of innovation activity.

    They find that making and buying R&D increases product introductions by 7 percent, and if the

    firms cooperate, the productivity increases even more. The data shows that small firms are

    more successful with their innovations, and export-oriented firms are more productive via

    innovation. The most productive firms are those that both make and buy their R&D, and

    acquiring outside R&D significantly increases innovative performance only when the firm has

    their own internal R&D. The results for their productivity regression and their multinomial logit

    and bivariate probit models can be seen in Tables 9 and 10.

    Sampson (2003) conducts similar research to that of Cassiman and Veugelers (2002),

    while focusing on the telecommunications equipment industry. They use a sample of firm

    patenting performance from 463 R&D alliances from the US, Japan, and Europe. The dependent

    variable for regression analysis is Firm Innovative Performance (Post Patent). Dependent

    variables are Technological Diversity and Organization, and control variables Pre-alliance Firm

    Patents, Alliance Scope (Narrow, Intermediate, Broad), Multilateral Alliances, Prior Linkages,

    Time of Alliance, Prior Alliance Experience, Other Concurrent Alliances, and International

    Alliances. Sampson has two hypotheses that he intends to investigate:

    H1: R&D alliances with moderate diversity contribute more to firm innovation than

    alliances with very low or very high levels of capability diversity.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    15/34

    H2: At higher levels of technological capability diversity, alliances organized by equity

    joint venture contribute more to firm innovation than alliances organized by bilateral

    contract. (Sampson 2003)

    Through a negative binomial estimation model of firm patenting based on the described

    independent variables without including alliance organization effects, Sampson finds that

    Technological Diversity is positive and Technological Diversity2

    is negative, shown in Table 11.

    This shows that firm patents increase with Technological Diversity to a certain point, and then

    the relationship becomes negative, illustrated in Figure 2. The effects of the alliance

    organization on this relationship are illustrated in Figure 3.

    Variations in Small Firms effectiveness in approaches to R&D:

    Baldwin (1995) examines different strategies as determinants of success among small

    and medium sized firms; management, human resource practices, marketing, financing, and

    innovativeness of the firm. They find that innovation is the most important determinant of

    success for a wide range of industries. The data came from a survey of firms with less than 500

    employees and less than $100 million of assets in 1984. Only firms that had growth in

    employment, assets, and sales between 1984 and 1988 were used for the sample to eliminate

    declining firms. There were a total of 1,480 valid firms included in the survey, with average

    sales of $6.6 million in 1989, average assets of $4.7 million, and an average employment of 44

    people. 86 percent of the firms were independently owned and operated with the other 14

    percent affiliated with a parent firm.

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    16/34

    The firms were asked to assess the importance relative to growth and competitiveness

    of the various determinants of performance already listed on a scale of 0-5, with 0-N/A, 1-not

    important, and 5-crucial. The results are shown in Figure 4, with the firms ranking management

    skills, skilled labor, marketing capacity, and access to the market the highest, with mean scores

    over 2.5. R&D is ranked second to last, just above 1.4. The firms were asked to rank their

    sources of innovation, scoring customers, management, and their suppliers the highest, all

    above 2.5. R&D was ranked near the bottom at 1.1, shown in Figure 5. Figure 6 shows the firms

    self-assessed rank of their position compared to their competitors, with the highest mean

    reported self-assessment scores between 3.5 and 4.0 for customer service, flexibility to

    customers, and quality of product. The self-assessed mean score for R&D Spending was the

    lowest at 1.4. Baldwin finds that the firms that were in the more-successful group had reported

    a mean self-assessed score of R&D-innovation capability 41 percent higher than the less-

    successful group, and a 33 percent higher score for R&D innovation spending. This shows that

    for small and medium sized firms, R&D capability and spending are the most overlooked,

    underappreciated, and undervalued sources of potential profits.

    Effects of Venture Capital investment on R&D productivity:

    Kortum & Lerner (1998) investigates the magnitude of venture capitals effect on

    industrial innovation and R&D. They constructed a sample of 530 venture-backed and non-

    venture-backed companies in Middlesex County, Massachusetts, spanning 20 industries from

    1965-1992. They use regression analysis to determine the ratio of venture financing dollars to

    private R&D expenditures, finding evidence that suggests a dollar of venture capital is as much

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    17/34

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    18/34

    Tables:

    Source: Banbury & Mitchell 1995

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    19/34

    Source: Von Hippel 2005

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    20/34

    Source: Guellac & Potterie 2001

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    21/34

    Source: Bassanini & Ernst 2002

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    22/34

    Source: Agrawal & Cockburn 2003

    Source: Agrawal & Cockburn 2003

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    23/34

    Source: Agrawal & Cockburn 2003

    Source: Agrawal & Cockburn 2003

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    24/34

    Source: Cassiman & Veugelers 2002

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    25/34

    Source: Cassiman & Veugelers 2002

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    26/34

    Source: Sampson 2003

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    27/34

    Source: Kortum & Lerner 2008

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    28/34

    Graphs:

    Source: Bound et al 1984

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    29/34

    Source: Sampson 2003

    Source: Sampson 2003

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    30/34

    Source: Baldwin 1995

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    31/34

    Source: Baldwin 1995

    Source: Baldwin 1995

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    32/34

    Source: Baldwin 1995

  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    33/34

    References

    Agrawal, Cockburn (2003) - The anchor tenant hypothesis: exploring the role of large, local,

    R&D-intensive firms in regional innovation systems International Journal of Industrial

    Organization Vol. 21, pg. 1227-1253

    Ahn (2002) - Competition, innovation and productivity growth: a review of theory and

    evidence OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 317, Jan 17

    Baldwin (1995) - Innovation: The key to success in small firms Micro-Economic Studies and

    Analysis Division, Statistics Canada and Canadian Institute for Advanced Research, Economic

    Project Growth, February

    Banbury, Mitchell (1995) - The effect of introducing important incremental innovations on

    market share and business survivalStrategic Management Journal, Vol. 16, pg. 161-182

    Bassanini, Ernst (2002) - Labour Market Institutions, Product Market Regulation, and

    Innovation: Cross-Country Evidence, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 316,

    OECD Publishing.

    Bound et al (1984)Who does R&D and who patents?, National Bureau of Economic

    Research, pg. 21-54

    Cassiman, Veugelers (2002)Complementarity in the Innovation Strategy: Internal R&D,

    External Technology Acquisition, and Cooperation in R&D, - Social Science Research Network

    Electronic Paper Collection:http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=303562

    Cierpicki, Wright, Sharp (2000)Managers knowledge of marketing principles: the case of

    new product development,Journal of Empirical Generalisations in Marketing Science, Vol. 5,

    pg 771-790

    Gourville (2005)The curse of innovation: A theory of why new products fail in the

    marketplace, Harvard Business School Marketing Research Papers, No. 05-06, Social Science

    Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:

    http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=777644

    Guellec, Potterie (2001) - R&D and Productivity Growth: Panel Data Analysis of16 OECDCountries, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers, 2001/03, OECD Publishing.

    Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (1990)The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo

    bias,Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5, No. 1, Winter 1991, pg. 193-206

    Kortum, Lerner (1998)Does Venture Capital Spur Innovation? National Bureau of Economic

    Research, November

    http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=303562http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=303562http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=303562http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=777644http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=777644http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=777644http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=303562
  • 7/31/2019 Innovation Lit Review

    34/34

    Lilien, Morrison, Searls, Sonnack, Von Hippel (2002) Performance assessment of the lead

    user idea-generation process for new product development, Management Science, Vol. 48,

    No. 8, August 2002, pg. 1042-1059

    Lthje, (2003) - Customers as Co-Inventors: An Empirical Analysis of the Antecedents of

    Customer-Driven Innovations in the Field of Medical Equipment. In Proceedings of the 32thEMAC Conference, Glasgow.

    Olley, Pakes (1996)The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment

    Industry, Econometrica, Vol. 64, No. 6 (November, 1996), pg. 1263-1297

    Pavitt et al (1987), The size distribution of innovating firms in the UK: 1945-1983, The Journal

    of Industrial Economics, Vol.35, No.3, pp.297-316

    Rayna, Striukova (2009)The curse of the first-mover: when incremental innovation leads to

    radical change, Int. J. Collaborative Enterprise, Vol. 1, No. 1, pg 4-21

    Sampson (2003)R&D Alliances & Firm Performance: The impact of technological diversity

    and alliance organization on innovation, New York University

    Von Hippel (2005)Democratizing Innovation, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts

    Von Hippel, de Jong, Flowers (2011)Comparing business and household sector innovation in

    consumer products: findings from a representative study in the UK, Social Science Research

    Network, URL: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1683503