introductory microeconomics (es10001) topic 5: perfect competition & monopoly

125
Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

Upload: laurence-nicholson

Post on 15-Jan-2016

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

Page 2: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

1. Introduction

MR = MC rule requires knowledge of market structure

One of the major influences on MR, and thus on its supply decision, is the degree of competitiveness the firm faces in the market.

That is, the number of actual and potential competitors

Page 3: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

1. Introduction

This makes sense! If firm is the only player in the market, then we would expect it to behave differently than if it were one of (very) many

In what follows we will examine the causes and effects of market structure

Page 4: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

2. Taxonomy of Competition

Microeconomics has tended to categorise the degree of competition a particular firm faces into three very precise and distinct categories:

A lot;

A bit;

None!

Page 5: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

Perfect Competition

Collusive (i.e. Cartel)

Oligopoly

Monopoly

Monopolistic Competition

Imperfect Competition

Non-Collusive

Figure 1: Taxonomy of Competition

More Competition Less Competition

Page 6: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Market structure where competitive forces are at their greatest

Definition: A Perfectly Competitive (PC) market is one in which both buyers and sellers believe that their own buying or selling decisions have no effect on the market price

Sometimes referred to as an ‘atomistic’ market

Page 7: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Formal Characteristics

1. (Very) Large number of buyers and sellers;

2. Homogenous product;

3. Free entry and exit (in long-run);

4. Perfect knowledge.

Implication: All firms face same, perfectly elastic, demand curve

Page 8: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0

Q0 Q q

p0

S0

D0

d0

Figure 2: Perfectly Elastic Demand

Industry Representative Firm

E0

Page 9: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Why would firm not raise or lower price above or below p0?

If p > p0, then it would sell nothing because consumers have perfect knowledge and good is homogenous

Conversely, no point in setting p < p0 since it can sell as much as it wishes at p0

Page 10: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Firm’s demand curve is also its AR and MR curve

Recall:

AR = TR / q

MR = ΔTR / Δq

Since demand is perfectly elastic, AR = MR = p

Page 11: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

d

1 2

5

Figure 3: Demand = AR = MR

E0 E1

Page 12: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

d

1 2

5

Figure 3: Demand = AR = MR

E0 E1

TR1=5

AR1=5/1=5

Page 13: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

d

1 2

5

Figure 3: Demand = AR = MR

E0 E1

TR2 =2*5=10

AR2=5/1=5

MR2 = TR2–TR1= 5

Page 14: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

d = AR = MR

1 2

5

Figure 3: Demand = AR = MR

E0 E1

Page 15: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Consider short-run profit maximising rule

First, we know that to maximise profit we need to set SMR = SMC

But, SMC must also be rising …

… otherwise, profit (loss) is minimised (maximised)

Page 16: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

q0 q1

p0 d = AR = MR

Figure 4: Optimal Output

E0 E1

π min π max

Page 17: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus, short-run profit maximising rule

(1) MR = SMC

(2) SMC is rising

But, it could always be in firm’s interest to produce nothing!

Is there a ‘shut-down’ price?

Page 18: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

SAVC

SAC

q0

p0

SAC0

PROFIT

Figure 5: Demand = AR = MR

π > 0

Eo AR =MR

Page 19: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

SAVC

SAC

q1

p1 AR = MR

Figure 6: Demand = AR = MR

π = 0

E1

Page 20: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

SAVC

SAC

q2

p2

SAC2LOSS < - TFC

Figure 7: Demand = AR = MR

- TFC < π < 0

MR

E2

Page 21: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

Figure 8: Demand = AR = MR

π = - TFC < 0

SAC

q3

p3

SAC3

LOSS = TFC

SAVC

AR = MR

E3

Page 22: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

SAVC

SAC

q4

p4

SAC4

LOSS > TFC

Figure 9: Demand = AR = MR

π < - TFC < 0

AR = MR

E4

Page 23: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus, short-run profit maximising rule

MR = SMC

SMC is rising

p > SAVC

Supply curve of the firm is that part of its SMC curve above minimum SAVC

Page 24: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

Figure 8: Demand = AR = MR

π = - TFC < 0

SAC

q3

p3

SAC3

LOSS = TFC

SAVC

AR = MR

E3

Page 25: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SMC

Figure 8:

p3

AR = MR

SAVC

Page 26: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SR Supply

Figure 8:

Min AVC

Page 27: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Note, short-run ‘shutdown’ price = p3 = SAVC(q3)

π(p3) = p3*q3 – SAC(q3)*q3

= [SAVC(q3) – SAC(q3)]*q3

= -AFC(q3)*q3

= -TFC

Page 28: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus, short-run supply curve of firm is that part of its SMC above minimum AVC

Similarly, long-run supply curve is that part of LMC above minimum LAC

i.e. long-run ‘shutdown’ option is to leave the industry

Page 29: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

LMC

LAC

q0

p0 AR = MR

Figure 10: Long-Run Shut-Down

Page 30: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Compare SR and LR supply curves

SR supply curve of firm is that part of its SMC above minimum AVC; similarly, long-run supply curve is that part of LMC above minimum LAC

i.e. LR ‘shutdown’ option is to leave the industry

Note that SR supply curve lays below LR supply curve (recall ‘Envelope’) and is steeper

Page 31: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

SSR

SLR

p1

p0

Min LAC

Min AVC

Figure 11: Long-Run & Short-Run Supply

Page 32: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

SSR lays below SLR because LAC is envelope of SAC’s and SAVC’s lay below SAC since SAC includes AFC

SSR is steeper than SLR because it will always be less costly for firm to increase output when it can alter all inputs (i.e. K an L) appropriately (i.e. when it is in LR)

Now, consider MR = MC condition

Page 33: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

TR0 = p0q0

TR1 = p1q1

Thus:

ΔTR =TR1 - TR0 = p1q1 - p0q0

= p1q1 - p0q0 + (p1q0 - p1q0)

= p1q1 - p1q0 + p1q0 - p0q0

= p1(q1 - q0) + (p1 - p0)q0

Page 34: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

ΔTR = p1(q1 - q0) + (p1 - p0)q0

= p1Δq + Δpq0

Thus:

Consider ‘small’ changes in (p, q) such that p1 ≈ p0, q1 ≈ q0 , and so (p0, p1) ≈ p and (q0, q1) ≈ q

Page 35: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus:

Now, recall:

Page 36: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus:

Under perfect competition, E => ∞ such that MR => p

Also, since MR = MC in equilibrium, then:

Page 37: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus:

Page 38: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Lerner (1934) ‘Index of Monopoly Power’

Note that under perfect competition, E => ∞ such that p => MC

Firms can only ‘mark-up’ p over MC iff E < ∞

Page 39: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 q

da

Figure 12: Elasticity of Demand and Slope of (Inverse) Demand Curve

db

dc

E0

Page 40: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Industry Supply

SR industry supply curve (when factor prices are given) is the horizontal summation of each firm’s SMC curve above minimum AVC

Similarly, LR industry supply curve (when factor prices are given) is horizontal summation of each firm’s LMC curve above minimum LAC

Page 41: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

p0

p1

p2

0 0

Firm A Firm B Industry

q0 q1 q2 q0 q1 q2 Q0 Q1 Q2 qa qb Q

Figure 13: SR Industry Supply

Page 42: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Consider effect of an exogenous increase in industry demand for the good

Increase in demand will increase each existing firm’s profit

Existing firms increase SR supply by moving up their SMC curves

Page 43: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p

0

Q0 Q q0 q

p0

D0

d0

SMC

Figure 14a: SR Industry Supply

SAC

E0e0

Industry Representative Firm

Page 44: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p

0

Q0 Q1 Q q0 q1 q

p0

D0

d0

SMC

d1

D1

Figure 14b: SR Industry Supply

SAC

E0

E1

e0

e1

Industry Representative Firm

Page 45: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

But, the existence of super-normal profits will attract other firms into the industry

This will shift out industry (SR) supply curve and lead to a fall in the (perfectly elastic) demand facing individuals firms

Industry supply is higher because of entry of new firms; each firm produces same amount in new equilibrium (E2) as original firms produced in original equilibrium (E0)

Page 46: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p

0

Q0 Q1 Q2 Q q0 q1 q

p0

D0

d0

SMC

d1

D1

Figure 14c: SR Industry Supply

SAC

E0 E2

E1

e2 = e0

e1

Industry Representative Firm

Page 47: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

LR supply curve of industry is horizontal / perfectly elastic

LR supply price of industry is equal to minimum LAC of constituent firms

Thus, demand only determines quantity; price is supply (i.e. cost) determined)

Page 48: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p P

0 q* q 0 Q* Q

p* SLR

LMC

LAC

e*

D

E*

Figure 15: LR Industry Supply

Representative Firm Industry

Page 49: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

LR supply curve of industry is upward sloping in two situations:

1. Factor prices increase with usage

2. Heterogeneous firms

Consider each in turn

Page 50: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Consider first the SR response of a representative firm and the industry to an increase in demand

If factor prices increase with usage, then increase in demand induces each firm to increase output along its SMC curve

But, increase in industry supply of output increases demand for / price of the variable input

Page 51: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Increase in price of variable input shifts up vertically each firm’s SMC curve

The expansion of output by each firm can thus be interpreted as a combination of a ‘movement along’ and a ‘shift of’ its SMC curve

Similarly, the expansion of output by the industry - combination of a ‘movement along’ / ‘shift of’ the aggregation of constituent firms’ SMC curves

Page 52: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p

0

q0 q1 q Q0 Q1 Q

p0

D1

∑SMC0

D0

SMC1

Figure 16: SR Industry Supply

Factor prices increase with usage

e0

e1E1

E0

Representative Firm Industry

SMC0

SSR

p1

∑SMC1

∑SSR

Page 53: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

In LR, free entry / exit implies each firm produces at minimum LAC

If firms are equally efficient, then firms have same minimum LAC and industry supply is perfectly elastic

Intuitively, whatever happens to demand, SR supply, and thus price, competitive forces ensure a normal-profit LR equilibrium such that LR supply is perfectly elastic at minimum LAC

Page 54: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

But this presumes factor prices are fixed

What if factor prices increase with their usage?

In this case, then LR expansion of output by the industry will increase the price of all factors such that each constituent firm’s LAC and LMC will shift-up

Page 55: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Thus, LR industry response to increase in demand when factor prices increase with their usage is a combination of:

(i) a ‘movement along’ a perfectly elastic LR supply curve (i.e. one determined by minimum LAC of equally efficient constituent firms, but where factor prices are held constant);

(ii) a ‘shift-up’ of such a curve (i.e. where factor prices are allowed to increase)

Page 56: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D1

Figure 17: LR Industry Supply

Factor prices increase with usage

D0

E1

E0

Page 57: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

Consider also ‘heterogeneous firms’

i.e. inter-firm differences in efficiency

The earlier firms enter into an industry, the lower their cost curves; subsequent firms are increasingly less efficient

Page 58: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

3. Perfect Competition

At any particular LR equilibrium price, p*, the least efficient (i.e. ‘marginal’) firm is that firm which can make just normal profit at p*

The more efficient (i.e. ‘intra-marginal’) firms make positive profits at p* and, thus, produce in the region of DRS

Page 59: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

0 0

(Intra-Marginal) Firm 1 (Marginal) Firm 2 Industry

SLRLMC1

LMC2

LAC2

D

LAC1

p*

q1 q q2 q Q* Q

LAC1

Figure 18: LR Industry SupplyHeterogeneous Firms

e2E*

e1

Page 60: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Consider now the other extreme market environment

Monopoly; single seller

The monopolist is the industry; no distinction between firm and industry; less need to distinguish SR and LR since entry / exit is less of an issue

Consider monopolist's AR and MR curves

Page 61: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

As with PC firm, demand curve is also the AR curve

But since AR curve is downward sloping, MR curve lays below AR curve

Intuitively, to sell more Q, monopolist has to cut p on all units of Q

Page 62: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

TR1 = p1

TR2 = 2p2

MR2 = 2p2 - p1

= p2 - (p1-p2) < p2

1 2

p1

p2

MR2

MR

Figure 19a: AR and MR

A

B

C

Page 63: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

TR1 = p1

TR2 = 2p2

MR2 = 2p2 - p1

= p2 - (p1-p2) < p2

1 2

p1

p2

MR2

MR

Figure 19b: AR and MR

A

B

C

p2

Page 64: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

TR1 = p1

TR2 = 2p2

MR2 = 2p2 - p1

= p2 - (p1-p2) < p2

1 2

p1

p2

MR2

MR

Figure 19c: AR and MR

A

B

C

p2

(p1-p2)

Page 65: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

We will assume that the monopolist, like PC firms and industries, faces increasing and then decreasing returns to both factors and scale; i.e. ‘U-Shaped’ SAC / LAC

N.B. Monopoly that faces IRS always is termed a ‘Natural Monopoly’

Monopolist's profit can be supernormal (most likely), normal or negative

Page 66: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMC

LAC

Q0

p0

LAC0D = AR

MR

Profit

Figure 20a: Monopolist LR Equilibrium

π > 0

Page 67: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMCLAC

Q0

p0

LAC0

D = ARMR

Loss

Figure 20b: Monopolist LR Equilibrium

π < 0

Page 68: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMC

LAC

Q0

p0 = LAC0

D = ARMR

Figure 20c: Monopolist LR Equilibrium

π = 0

Page 69: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Consider efficiency

Allocative Efficiency (AE)

p = MC

Productive Efficiency (PE)

IRS are exhausted such that LAC is minimised

Page 70: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

(Non-Discriminating) monopolist is never AE and (extremely) unlikely to be PE

PE would require MR curve to cross MC at minimum AC

It can happen, but infinitely small chance!

Page 71: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMC

LAC

Qmes

pmes

LACmes

D = AR

MR

Figure 21: Monopolist LR Equilibrium

Productive efficiency is possible, but very unlikely!

Page 72: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Allocative Efficiency requires marginal (social) benefit (MSB) to equal marginal (social) cost (MSC)

Define: MSC = MPC + MEC

MSB = MPB + MEB

i.e. marginal social benefit (cost) equals marginal private benefit (cost) plus marginal external benefit (costs)

Page 73: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Private benefits (costs) are those enjoyed (incurred) by agent producing or consuming) the good

External benefits (costs) are the non-price effects on the production or consumption of other members of society

Assume (for now!) that MEC = MEB = 0 such that allocative efficiency requires MPC = MPB

Page 74: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Now:

MPC = LMC of monopolist

MPB = price consumers willing to pay for good

Thus, the MPB can be derived from the monopolist's Demand = AR curve

Recall, the (inverse) demand curve sets out consumer's reservation price vis. the maximum price the consumer is willing to pay

Page 75: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = MPB

Q1 Q2 Q3

p1

p2

Figure 22: D = MPB

A

B

Cp3

Page 76: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

It is apparent that the monopolist produces less output than the socially optimal (allocatively efficient) level

Monopolist maximises profit by setting MR = MC

Allocative efficiency is achieved when p = MC

Since p > MR, it must be the case that monopolist output is less than socially optimal

Page 77: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMC = MPC

LAC

Q0 Q1

p0

LAC0D = AR = MPB

MR

Figure 23: Monopolist LR Equilibrium

DWL = ABC

A

C

B

Privately Optimal

Socially Optimal

Page 78: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Consider the (‘overnight’) monopolisation of a PC industry

The constituent firms of the industry become manufacturing plants for the monopolist

Assume that the SLR = ∑LMC of the PC industry becomes the monopolist’s LMC curve (N.B. heterogeneous firms thus SLR is upward sloping)

Page 79: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Define social welfare (SW) as sum of consumer surplus (CS) and producer surplus (PS)

SW = PS + CS

NB: No concern with equity! 1+ 99 = 100 = 99 + 1

Define CS as excess of what consumers are willing to pay over what they actually pay; PS as excess of what producers actually receive over what they are willing to receive

Page 80: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

Qc

pc

CS

SLR

PS

A

B C

D

Figure 22a: Monopoly and PC

Perfect CompetitionCS = ABCPS = BCDSW = ABD

Page 81: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

Qm Qc

pc

MR

LMC

A

B C

D

pm E

F

G

Figure 22a: Monopoly and DWL

MonopolyCS = AEGPS = GEFDSW = AEFDDWL = EBF

Page 82: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

Qm Qc

pc

MR

LMC

A

B C

D

pm E

F

G

Figure 22a: Monopoly and DWL

MonopolyΔCS = -GEHC - EBHΔPS = +GEHC - BHFΔSW = -EBH - BHF

H

Page 83: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

But this is a static analysis - i.e. the instantaneous effects of monopolisation; what happens to cost over time, i.e. dynamic effects?

Two scenarios: (i) Liebenstein ‘X-Inefficency’ (pessimistic)

(ii) Schumpeter ‘R&D’ (optimistic)

Balance of argument - empirical issue

Page 84: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = AR

Qm Qc

pc

MR

LMC

A

B C

D

pm E

F

B

Schumpeter

Liebenstein

Figure 22a: Monopoly and DWL

Page 85: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

To summarise; monopolies would appear to be harmful to society in sense that they lead to DWL (i.e. consumers lose more than producers gain)

Perhaps some benefits over time (R&D), but that is an empirical issue

There is an argument, however, that if we are to have monopolies, then we should make them as powerful as possible!

Page 86: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Price Discrimination (PD)

Selling different units of the same good at different

prices

Two basic approaches to PD:

Charging different prices to different consumers for same units of the good;

Charging same consumers different prices for different units of the good

Page 87: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Three main types of PD:

1. First-Degree (Perfect);

2. Second-Degree;

3. Third-Degree

Consider each in turn

Page 88: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

First-Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination

Monopolist charges each consumer maximum price willing to pay for each unit of the good; thus demand curve is also MR curve, since only reduce p on additional units of Q

Monopolist produces socially optimal Q (i.e. p = MC) and is thus allocatively efficient (DWL = 0) but completely inequitable (CS = 0)

Page 89: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = MR

1 2 Q*

LMC

PS

A

B

C

Figure 23: First Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination

Perfect PDCS = 0PS = ABCSW = ABC

DWL = 0

p1

p2

p*

A'

A''

Page 90: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

First-Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination

Monopolist charges each consumer maximum price willing to pay for each unit of the good; thus demand curve is also MR curve, since only reduce p on additional units of Q

Monopolist produces socially optimal Q (i.e. p = MC) and is thus allocatively efficient (DWL = 0) but completely inequitable (CS = 0)

Page 91: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = MR

1 2 3 Q*

LMC

PS

A

F B

E

Figure 23: First Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination

Perfect Price Discrimination

Price = ABCD; Quantity = Q*

CS = 0PS = ABESW = ABE

DWL = 0

p1

p2

p*

A1

A2

A3p3

D C

Page 92: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D = MR

1 2 3 Q*

LMC

PS

A

B

E

Figure 23: First Degree (Perfect) Price Discrimination

Perfect Price Discrimination

Price = ABCD; Quantity = Q*

CS = 0PS = ABESW = ABE

DWL = 0

Page 93: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Second-Degree Price Discrimination

Monopolist knows there are different ‘types’ of consumers with different WTP (i.e. utility from consuming good) but cannot identify them individually

CSi(x) = ui(x) – p(x) i = H, L

uH(x) > uL(x) – i.e. H values good x more than L

Page 94: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A C

xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

DH

DL

Consider two ‘packages’ vis:

(pH, xH)

(pL, xL)

Assume production is costless

D

B

Page 95: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A C

xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

DH

DL

Ideally, monopolist would like to extract all CS. e.g.

pH = A + B + C

pL = A

D

B

Page 96: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A C

xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

DH

DL

Such pricing will ensure zero CS vis:

pH = A + B + C

pL = A

=>

CSH(xH) = 0 = CSL(xL)

D

B

Page 97: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A C

xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

DH

DL

D

But H prefers (pL, xL) to (pH, xH):

pH = A + B + C

pL = A

=>

CSL(xH) = - (B + C + D) < 0

CSH(xL) = B > 0B

Page 98: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A C

xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

DH

DL

D

B

Thus, monopolist must remove B from (pH, xH):

pH = A + C pL = A

=>

CSH(xH) = B = CSH(xL)

CSL(xL) = 0

CSL(xH) = - (C + D) < 0

Page 99: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A1 A2 C

xLL xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

B1 B2

DH

DL

Optimal packages? Consider cut in xL to xLL

=>

pH(xH) = A1 + A2 + B2 + C pL(xLL) = A1

D

Page 100: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A1 A2 C

xLL xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

B1 B2

DH

DL

(xLL, xH) is still incentive compatible

=>

CSH(xH) = B1 = CSH(xL)

CSL(xLL) = 0

CSL(xH) = - (B2+ C + D) < 0

D

Page 101: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A1 A2 C

xLL xL xH

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

B1 B2

DH

DL

Effect on profit?

=>

π(xH, xL) = (A1 + A2) + (A1 + A2 + C)

π(xH, xLL) = A1 + (A1 + A2 + B2 + C)

=>

Δπ = π(xH, xLL) - π(xH, xL) = - A2 + B2

D

Page 102: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 x A1 A2 C

xL* xH*

Figure 23: Second-Degree Price Discrimination

B1

DH

DL

Optimal package is found by reducing xL until MC (i.e. in A2) equals MR (i.e. in B2)

pH(xH*) = A1 + A2 + B2 + C

pL(xL*) = A1

where

a-b = b-c

a

b

c

B2

D

Page 103: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Monopolist sells good at different prices to different groups of consumers

Monopolist must be able to identify distinct markets

Geographical, age, gender, race …

Page 104: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Assume monopolist sells identical good to two markets (A and B)

Assume costs of producing and supplying good to either market are identical

E.g. Cinema selling seats in Bath to students and lecturers who have distinct reservations prices and elasticities of demand from each other

Page 105: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

0 0

Market A Market B Market A + B Lecturers Students

LMC

MRA

MRBARA

ARB

MR

AR

Figure 24a: Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Page 106: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Assume first that price-discrimination is illegal

The cinema will maximise profit by setting (aggregate) MR = LMC

Thus, sells seats in total at a common price of

to lecturers and to students

Page 107: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

0 0

LMC

MRA

MRBARA

ARB

MR

AR

Figure 24b: Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Market A Market B Market A + B Lecturers Students

Page 108: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Assume now that price discrimination is legal

Setting a common price implies that MRA ≠ MRB

Thus, the monopolist can increase its revenue (and since production costs are independent of the market supplied, its profit) by transferring Q from the low MR market to the high MR market

Page 109: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

0 0

LMC

MRA

MRBARA

ARB

MR

AR

Figure 24c: Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Market A Market B Market A + B Lecturers Students

Page 110: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

As Q is withdrawn from the low MR market, p and MR in that market rise;

And vice versa, as Q is transferred to the high MR market, p and MR in that market fall; profit is maximised when MRA = MRB

Page 111: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p p

0

0 0

LMC

MRA

MRBARB

ARB

MR

AR

Market A Market B Market A + B

Page 112: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Intuitively, lecturers have relatively inelastic demand, thus it is optimal to raise the price they face, since relatively little demand is lost

Conversely, students have relatively elastic demand, thus it is optimal to lower the price they face since demand increases substantially

Page 113: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Recall:

Thus:

Page 114: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Recall:

Thus:

If MRA = MRB, but EA < EB, then pA > pB

Page 115: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

For all this to work:

1. Group making up sub-markets must have distinct elasticities of demand;

2. Third-degree price discrimination must be legal;

3. There must be no arbitrage between the groups (i.e. usually used in service industries)

Page 116: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p p

0 qb

pb

pa

ARb = Db ARa = Da

A K

B E G J M

D F H N

I L

C

Page 117: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

Area No Price Discrimination (1)

Price Discrimination (2)

Change (2) – (1)

       

CSb +A +A+B+E+G +B+E+G

Rb +B+E+C+D+F +C+D+F+H -B-E+H

CSa +K+I+L +K -I-L

Ra +G+H+J+M+N +L+M+N -G-H-J+L

       

SW +A+B+C+D+E+F+G+H+I+J+K+L+M+

N

+A+B+C+D+E+F+G+H+K+L+M+N

-I-J

Page 118: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D

Qm

Figure 23: Natural Monopoly

pm

LMC

LAC

MR

LAC

Page 119: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D

QLAC Q*

Figure 23: Natural Monopoly

LMC

LAC

MR

p = LMC

Page 120: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D

QMES

Figure 23: Monopoly and Perfect Competition

LAC

If demand is small relative to MES, A competitive market is likely to result

Page 121: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

When is monopoly likely to happen?

Depends on minimum efficient scale and demand

Page 122: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D

QMES

Figure 23: Monopoly and Competition

LAC

If demand is large relative to MES, A monopolistic market structure is possible

Page 123: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

D

Q*

Figure 23: Natural Monopoly

p* = LMC

LMC

LAC

MR

LAC

Page 124: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

4. Monopoly

Finally …

Note that the monopolist does not have a supply curve

No one-to-one mapping between price and quantity supplied

Page 125: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001) Topic 5: Perfect Competition & Monopoly

p

0 Q

LMC

Q0 Q1

p0

AR1

MR0

MR1AR0

E0 E1

Figure 23: Monopolist does not have a supply curve