jurnal

40
An Empirical Analysis of Big N Auditor Switches: Evidence from the pre- and post-Enron Eras Wayne R. Landsman, a Karen K. Nelson, b and Brian R. Rountree b a Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina b Jones Graduate School of Management, Rice University August 2006 Abstract Using a comprehensive sample of lateral switches among the largest auditors (i.e., the Big N) this study documents that the probability of a lateral switch in Big N audit firms increases significantly in both the audit and financial risk of the client in the pre-Enron period but not in the post-Enron period. In both periods, clients switching downward to a non-Big N auditor pose similar audit and financial risks as lateral Big N switches, but are smaller and tend to have going concern opinions. We interpret our findings as evidence that the swapping of large, risky clients between Big N auditors is less prevalent in the post-Enron era, suggesting that Big N auditors may have become more sensitive to risky clients in recent years. JEL classification: L14; L84; K22; M4 Keywords: Auditor switching; Audit risk; Financial risk; We appreciate the helpful comments and suggestions of Bill Beaver, Allen Blay, Ling Lei, and workshop participants at the 2005 American Accounting Association Annual Meeting. Scott Whisenant generously provided some of the data for this study. We acknowledge funding from the Center for Finance and Accounting Research at UNC-Chapel Hill. Corresponding author: Wayne Landsman, Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC, 27599-3490, [email protected] .

Upload: gito-manaloe

Post on 28-Sep-2015

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

bahasa

TRANSCRIPT

  • An Empirical Analysis of Big N Auditor Switches: Evidence from the pre- and post-Enron Eras

    Wayne R. Landsman,a Karen K. Nelson,b and Brian R. Rountree b

    a Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina

    b Jones Graduate School of Management, Rice University

    August 2006

    Abstract

    Using a comprehensive sample of lateral switches among the largest auditors (i.e., the Big N) this study documents that the probability of a lateral switch in Big N audit firms increases significantly in both the audit and financial risk of the client in the pre-Enron period but not in the post-Enron period. In both periods, clients switching downward to a non-Big N auditor pose similar audit and financial risks as lateral Big N switches, but are smaller and tend to have going concern opinions. We interpret our findings as evidence that the swapping of large, risky clients between Big N auditors is less prevalent in the post-Enron era, suggesting that Big N auditors may have become more sensitive to risky clients in recent years.

    JEL classification: L14; L84; K22; M4

    Keywords: Auditor switching; Audit risk; Financial risk;

    We appreciate the helpful comments and suggestions of Bill Beaver, Allen Blay, Ling Lei, and workshop participants at the 2005 American Accounting Association Annual Meeting. Scott Whisenant generously provided some of the data for this study. We acknowledge funding from the Center for Finance and Accounting Research at UNC-Chapel Hill.

    Corresponding author: Wayne Landsman, Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill, NC, 27599-3490, [email protected].

  • 1. Introduction

    Recent accounting scandals, including Enron, WorldCom, Global Crossing, and Qwest,

    have brought about a sea of change in the audit industry, most notably the dissolution of Arthur

    Andersen. The accounting industry has responded to the scandals in several ways, including an

    assertion by the remaining top-tier accounting firms (i.e., the Big N) that they have since dropped

    hundreds of clients that expose them to unacceptable levels of risk:

    After watching former Big Five accounting firm Arthur Andersen implode after its Enron (ENRNQ) Corp. entanglement, the surviving Big Four aren't leaving much to chance. PricewaterhouseCoopers and Deloitte & Touche each have shed about 500 clients in the past 18 months because of liability concerns. With earnings being restated at a record clip, shareholder lawsuits have increased. We have tightened up our standards, says Gregory Weaver, the head of Deloitte's U.S. audit practice. Ernst & Young has parted ways with more than 200 clients. KPMG declined to comment. (Hindo, 2003)

    Although risk avoidance has perhaps become more salient in recent years, it is certainly

    not a new issue. Beginning in the early 1990s, the Big N reportedly became more likely to

    avoid high-risk clients because of concerns that the profession faced increased liability (Cook et

    al., 1992]; POB, 1993; Holland et al., 1993; Berton, 1995; MacDonald, 1997). As a result, risky

    clients switching from one of the Big N firms are viewed as having little choice but to engage a

    smaller auditor that lacks the reputation and cachet of the Big N.

    Although prior academic studies generally show a positive correlation, on average,

    between client risk and the probability of an auditor switch (e.g., Krishnan and Krishnan, 1997;

    Shu, 2000; Johnstone and Bedard, 2004), this research typically pools auditor switches of all

    types. i.e., upward, downward, lateral Big N, and lateral non-Big N. As a result, it is impossible

    to infer from prior evidence whether risky clients are switching to a lower-tier auditor as claimed

    or laterally to another Big N auditor. The purpose of this paper is to directly examine lateral

  • 2

    switches among Big N auditors, the most economically significant set of auditor switches, both

    in the decade leading up to Enrons collapse and in the subsequent years.

    To investigate whether client risk factors are associated with lateral Big N auditor

    switches, we estimate a logit regression that models this type of auditor switch as a function of

    client audit risk and financial risk, as well as several control variables. The null hypothesis

    predicts that the risk factors will not be associated with lateral Big N auditor switches if risky

    clients are indeed excluded from the Big N audit market. In other words, risky clients leaving

    their incumbent Big N auditor will not be able to engage another Big N auditor. Alternatively, if

    risky clients are not excluded from the Big N auditor market but instead are able to switch

    laterally to another Big N auditor, there will be a significant association between client risk and

    the lateral Big N auditor switches in our sample.

    Our results indicate that the probability of a lateral switch among Big N auditors is

    significantly increasing in both client audit risk and financial risk. Thus, even though risky

    clients are more likely to switch auditors, another Big N auditor is willing to accept the

    engagement. These results hold regardless of whether the auditor resigned from the engagement

    or was dismissed by the client, and for all Big N auditors.

    To provide further evidence on the nature of lateral Big N auditor switches, we compare

    the risk profile of clients switching laterally to another Big N auditor to that of clients switching

    downward to a non-Big N auditor. The results indicate that these two types of auditor switches

    are associated with similar client-related risks. Companies excluded from the Big N audit

    market, however, are much smaller and tend to have going concern audit opinions, suggesting

    that large, risky companies are able to switch laterally to another Big N auditor while small

    companies that pose less economic risk to the auditor switch downward to a non-Big N auditor.

  • 3

    We also show that our findings for lateral Big N auditor switches cannot be explained by

    auditor realignment or clientele adjustment (Johnson and Lys, 1990; Shu, 2000). These theories

    of auditor switching predict that clients will replace their incumbent auditor with a substantially

    larger or smaller firm. Therefore, we expect auditor realignment to be a factor for companies

    switching downwards to a non-Big N auditor, but not for companies switching laterally to

    another Big N auditor. Our results support these predictions, thus confirming the results of prior

    studies for switches between large and small auditors and extending the literature to provide

    evidence of risky clients switching between large auditors.

    Finally, we examine the risk profile post-Enron auditor switches to determine whether

    sensitivity to client risk has changed. Although these results should be interpreted with caution

    because of limited data availability for the 2002-2004 post-Enron period, we find some evidence

    of changes in the market for auditor switches. Specifically, we document that lateral Big N

    switches occur with relatively lower frequency and are no longer significantly associated with

    client audit and financial risk. Downward switches in the post-Enron environment, however, still

    occur primarily for small clients with going concern opinions.

    Although the evidence in this paper is broadly consistent with claims that risky clients are

    more likely to switch auditors, suggesting that audit or financial risk cannot be fully priced

    (OKeefe et al., 1994; Bockus and Gigler, 1998; Bell et al., 2001), we extend prior literature to

    show that these risky clients are able to engage another Big N auditor. It is important to note,

    however, that our results do not necessarily imply suboptimal behavior on the part of Big N

    auditors. One possible explanation for our findings is that the successor Big N auditor is willing

    to accept the risk posed in hopes of higher fees in the future, and when these fees do not

    materialize the risky client again switches auditors. It is also possible that the risk faced by the

  • 4

    incumbent and successor auditors differ, even though the clients risk is unchanged. In

    particular, to the extent the successor auditor is not exposed to client risk arising from

    transactions that occurred under the incumbent auditor, client risk may be lower for the successor

    auditor, making the risky client profitable. Further understanding of the economic forces

    underlying lateral Big N auditor switches is thus a fruitful area for additional research.

    The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses prior research,

    and explains how our study builds on this literature. Section 3 outlines our research design.

    Section 4 describes the sample data and presents the empirical findings for the pre-Enron era.

    Section 5 presents results for the post-Enron era. Section 6 summarizes and concludes the study.

    2. Relation to prior literature

    Auditors frequently cite risk avoidance as a primary factor in managing their client

    portfolios (e.g., Holland et al., 1993; Berton, 1995; MacDonald, 1997; Hindo, 2003). Consistent

    with these claims, empirical evidence generally documents a positive association, on average,

    between client risk factors and auditor switches, particularly when the auditor resigns from an

    engagement (e.g., Krishnan and Krishnan, 1997; Shu, 2000; Johnstone and Bedard, 2004).

    Bradshaw et al. (2001), however, finds that auditor switches are less likely for high accrual

    companies even though such companies are riskier to the extent that high accruals increase the

    likelihood of GAAP violations.

    In addition to divesting risky clients, evidence suggests that risk assessments factor into

    auditors client acceptance decisions (e.g., Johnstone, 2000; Johnstone and Bedard, 2003, 2004).

    A related stream of literature examines whether auditors accept risky clients, but attempt to

    manage this risk by adjusting audit fees, audit procedures, and/or engagement personnel. The

    evidence in this regard, however, is mixed. The findings in Johnstone (2000) are not consistent

  • 5

    with auditors adopting such risk management strategies, whereas Bell et al. (2001) and Johnstone

    and Bedard (2003) report that auditors do appear to respond to client risk factors. Bell et al.

    (2001) also notes, however, that risk management strategies cannot, in principle, eliminate or

    reduce auditor business risk below a certain level.

    Conventional wisdom suggests that risky clients leaving a Big N firm will be forced to

    hire smaller, lower tier accounting firms (e.g., Holland et al., 1993; Berton, 1995; MacDonald,

    1997; Hindo, 2003). Consistent with this perception, Bockus and Gigler (1998) analytically

    demonstrates that auditors will resign from riskier clients, and that these clients then engage a

    smaller (i.e., more wealth-constrained) auditor. However, despite the general view that risky

    clients drop to a lower tier auditor, prior empirical research typically pools auditor switches of all

    types, i.e., upward, downward, lateral Big N, and lateral non-Big N.1 As a result, there is very

    little direct evidence on the role of client risk in determining whether companies are excluded

    from the Big N audit market. In other words, simply because auditor switches are associated

    with client risk in general, one cannot conclude that client risk plays a role in all types of auditor

    switches, or that auditor switches involving risky clients generally result in the client switching

    to a non-Big N auditor.

    Based on 1986 data, Haskins and Williams (1990) finds that client financial distress, size,

    and growth, along with audit firm industry dominance, are the most important factors associated

    with lateral Big N auditor switches.2 For a sample of auditor switches by failing companies,

    1 In addition to the papers cited above, other work that does not differentiate the type of auditor switch in the

    empirical analysis includes Chow and Rice (1982), Francis and Wilson (1988), and Krishnan (1994). Although some of these studies present descriptive information on the frequency of auditor switches by type, none examines the risk profile of clients switching laterally within the Big N, or compare the lateral Big N switches to clients switching downward to a non-Big N auditor. 2 Unlike the other studies in the auditor change literature which rely on binary probability models, Haskin and

    Williams (1990) employs a recursive partitioning algorithm that sequentially identifies the best model, i.e., the model with the smallest apparent error rate. This approach, however, is subject to concerns about overfitting tendencies.

  • 6

    Schwartz and Menon (1985) shows that downward switches to a non-Big N auditor (10

    companies) are no more prevalent than lateral switches among Big N auditors (11 companies), or

    upward switches to a Big N auditor (12 companies). In contrast, Shu (2000) finds that riskier

    clients are less likely to engage another large auditor when the incumbent auditor resigns from

    the engagement. However, Shu (2000) defines large auditor broadly to include not only Big N

    auditors but also 18 non-Big N auditors with individual auditor codes on Compustat.

    A related set of studies examines risk characteristics of Big N client portfolios across

    periods of differing litigation risk. For a sample of small manufacturing companies, Jones and

    Raghunandan (1998) shows that Big N auditors were less likely to audit risky clients over a

    period of increasing litigation costs. Similarly, Choi et al. (2004) finds that the riskiness of Big

    N client portfolios changes in response to changes in the litigation environment. Their results

    show not only a significant increase since 1990 in the proportion of high risk clients departing

    the Big N audit market, but also a significant increase in the proportion of high risk clients

    entering the Big N audit market. Neither of these papers, however, examines the riskiness of

    clients switching between Big N auditors.

    We build on the prior literature in several important ways. First, we focus our analysis on

    lateral Big N auditor switches, and directly investigate whether risky clients are excluded from

    the Big N audit market. If this perception is correct, then risk factors should not play a role in

    lateral Big N auditor switches as risky clients will be unable to engage another Big N auditor.

    Contrary to this view, we present the first evidence of a significant association between lateral

    Big N auditor changes and client risk. Second, we contrast the risk profile of companies

    switching laterally between Big N auditors to that of companies switching downward to a non-

    Big N auditor. This analysis provides evidence on whether the sensitivity to client risk differs

  • 7

    for lateral Big N and downward switches. Again contrary to popular perceptions, we find that

    these two types of auditor switches are associated with similar client-related risks.

    Third, we differentiate our findings for lateral Big N auditor switches from theories of

    auditor realignment or clientele mismatch offered in prior research (e.g., Johnson and Lys, 1990;

    Shu, 2000). These theories predict that clients will replace their incumbent auditor with a

    substantially larger or smaller firm, and thus should not explain lateral Big N switches in which

    the incumbent auditor is replaced with a firm of similar size. Consistent with our expectations,

    we find that auditor realignment is not a factor in lateral Big N switches, but is a factor in

    downward switches to a non-Big N auditor. Thus, while our study reinforces the evidence of

    realignment between auditors of different sizes presented in these studies, we also provide new

    evidence of the swapping of risky clients among the Big N audit firms.

    Finally, we present the first empirical evidence comparing the risk profiles of pre -and

    post-Enron auditor switches. Following Enrons collapse, some suggest that auditors,

    particularly the Big N, have become more sensitive to risky clients (e.g., Hindo, 2003). We find

    some evidence consistent with this view, as lateral Big N switches are less frequent and are no

    longer significantly associated with client risk factors.

    3. Research design and data

    3.1. Lateral Big N auditor switches

    We model lateral switches among Big N auditors as a function of client-specific risk

    characteristics and various controls, including year and industry fixed effects to allow for

    differences in mean switch rates across time and industries:

  • 8

    itititit

    itititititit

    itititititI It tit

    M&ASIZEEXPERTLEVERAGELOSSROATENUREMODOPGC

    NEGACCACCNEGACCACCGROWTHSWITCH

    ++++

    ++++++

    +++++=

    113112111

    1101918171615

    114131211

    where the variables are defined as follows (Compustat data items in parentheses):

    SWITCH = 1 if the client changed among Big N auditors during the year, and 0 otherwise;

    GROWTH = total assets (#6) less beginning total assets, divided by beginning total assets;

    ACC = performance adjusted discretionary total accruals following Kothari et al. (2005);

    NEGACC = 1 if ACC is negative, and 0 otherwise; GC = 1 if the audit opinion is a going concern, and 0 otherwise;

    MODOP = 1 if the audit opinion is modified for anything other than a going concern, and 0 if unqualified;

    TENURE = number of years audited by the incumbent auditor, with a maximum of 10 years;

    ROA = return on assets, defined as net income before extraordinary items (#18) divided by average total assets (#6);

    LOSS = 1 if ROA < 0, and 0 otherwise; LEVERAGE = ratio of debt (#9 + #34) to total assets (#6);

    EXPERT = 1 if the incumbent auditor has at least 5% more clients in a particular industry and state, and 0 otherwise;

    SIZE = Natural logarithm of market value of equity (#25 #199); M&A = 1 if the client had a merger or acquisition (footnote code #1) in the

    two most recent years , and 0 otherwise; i denotes client firm; t denotes year; and I denotes industry.

    The regressors in the model are measures of client audit and financial risk identified in

    the prior literature.3 The audit risk measures are GROWTH, ACC, GC, MODOP, and TENURE.

    Stice (1991) finds a positive association between client growth and auditor litigation, and

    conjectures that high growth may be accompanied by an ineffective internal control system and

    3 As commonly defined, client financial risk is the risk of a decline in the clients economic condition, and audit risk

    is the risk that the auditor will incorrectly give an unqualified opinion on financial statements that are materially misstated. A third type of risk, auditor business risk, captures the audit firms risk of loss resulting from the engagement. By definition, auditor business risk is significantly higher for public clients. Because our sample consists entirely of publicly-traded firms, we do not include a dichotomous variable for public/private status as in prior research (e.g., OKeefe, et al., 1994; Bell et al., 2001; Johnstone and Bedard, 2004). Client financial risk can affect both the auditors business risk and audit risk (OKeefe et al., 1994).

  • 9

    misleading financial statements. Accordingly, the predicted coefficient on GROWTH is positive.

    Similarly, Heninger (2001) finds that the risk of auditor litigation increases for clients reporting

    more positive (income-increasing) abnormal accruals. The model therefore includes

    performance-matched discretionary accruals, ACC, an indicator variable, NEGACC, for negative

    discretionary accruals, and the interaction of these two variables.4 Because audit risk increases

    when reported financial results are inflated, we expect a positive coefficient estimate on ACC.

    On the other hand, large negative discretionary accruals are consistent with auditor conservatism,

    creating an incentive for clients to dismiss the incumbent auditor in hopes of finding a more

    reasonable successor (DeFond and Subramanyan, 1998). The total coefficient for negative

    discretionary accruals is 2 + 4.

    The remaining audit risk variables capture client-specific aspects of the audit

    engagement. Following Krishnan and Krishnan (1997) and Johnstone and Bedard (2004), we

    expect that companies with other than a clean opinion are more risky, increasing the likelihood

    of a change in auditors. Thus, we predict a positive coefficient on GC and MODOP. Stice

    (1991) and Krishnan and Krishnan (1997) assert that audit risk also relates to the tenure of the

    auditor-client relationship; shorter tenure with a client results in less client-specific knowledge

    and a greater likelihood of audit failure resulting in a negative prediction for the coefficient on

    TENURE.

    Following Johnstone and Bedard (2004), our measures of financial risk are ROA, LOSS,

    and LEVERAGE. More profitable companies pose less financial risk to the auditor, and thus we

    expect the coefficient estimate on ROA to be negative and that on LOSS to be positive.

    4 Earlier research on the relation between auditor litigation and total accruals yields inconclusive results (e.g., Stice,

    1991; Lys and Watts, 1994), and thus we focus on measures of discretionary accruals. Untabulated results indicate that inferences are unchanged if we use deflated total accruals as in Krishnan and Krishnan (1997) and the portfolio equivalent as in Bradshaw et al. (2001).

  • 10

    Similarly, higher debt levels pose more financial risk, which we expect will result in a positive

    coefficient estimate on LEVERAGE.

    Finally, in addition to year and industry fixed effects, we include three other controls in

    the regression model, audit firm expertise (EXPERT), client firm size (SIZE), and an indicator

    variable for merger and acquisition activity (M&A). Audit firms have been shown to exhibit

    general tendencies consistent with investment in industry expertise (Hogan and Jeter, 1999). As

    such, companies may switch auditors for expertise reasons unrelated to their risk profile.

    Because the costs of changing auditors are expected to be higher for larger clients (DeAngelo,

    1981), we predict a negative coefficient estimate on SIZE. We include M&A because companies

    are more likely to change auditors after a merger or acquisition if the newly-combined entities

    had previously engaged different auditors, and hence we expect a positive coefficient estimate on

    this variable.

    We estimate the auditor change model using two complementary approaches. The first

    pools dismissals and resignations. The second permits coefficient estimates to differ for

    dismissals and resignations using a multinomial logit technique. Multinomial logit is an

    extension of the binary logit model to multiple choices. The procedure estimates the probability

    of a particular alternative relative to the probabilities of all other alternatives. In the analysis of

    lateral Big N auditor switches, there are three alternatives: (i) no change in auditor, (ii) client

    dismissal, or (iii) auditor resignation. An advantage of multinomial logit is that it controls for the

    probability of changing auditors when testing for coefficient differences between the dismissal

    and resignation subsamples. Prior research finds that auditors are more likely to resign rather

    than be dismissed from clients that pose greater risk (Krishnan and Krishnan, 1997), and that

    clients associated with resignations are riskier than continuing clients (Shu, 2000; Johnstone and

  • 11

    Bedard, 2004). We therefore expect the sensitivity of auditor switches to a firms risk

    characteristics to be greater for resignations than dismissals. However, there may be noise in the

    classification of resignations and dismissals, which would bias against finding a difference in

    coefficient estimates between the two subsamples.5

    3.2. Comparison of lateral Big N auditor switches and downward auditor switches

    The tests outlined in the preceding section limit auditor switches to client companies

    switching between Big N auditors. We extend this analysis to consider whether client risk

    characteristics distinguish between lateral and downward switches (i.e., switches to a non-Big N

    auditor). Assertions in the financial press suggest that a downward switch is more likely than a

    lateral switch for risky clients. To directly test this assertion, we estimate the above regression

    model permitting the coefficient estimates to differ by the direction of the switch (lateral or

    downward) and the type of the switch (dismissal or resignation).6 This specification permits us

    to test whether the sensitivity to client risk differs for lateral Big N and downward switches. If

    risky clients are more likely to be excluded from the Big N audit market, as many have

    conjectured, downward switches (and, in particular, those triggered by an auditor resignation)

    will be more highly associated with client risk characteristics than lateral switches.

    3.3. Data

    Our sample consists of auditor switches during fiscal years 1993-2001 reported on the

    AuditorTrak database, as well as those occurring during fiscal years 2002-2004 on the Auditor

    5 Firms are required to disclose in an 8-K filing whether the auditor resigned, declined to stand for re-election, or

    was dismissed. We consider declining to stand for re-election as tantamount to a resignation, and code these few observations accordingly. We note that the two-way partition, although common in prior research, does not necessarily fully capture the underlying dynamics of the auditor change. For example, auditors may prefer to be dismissed from an engagement because of concerns that resignations could harm their ability to attract new clients. Alternatively, clients may rush to dismiss an auditor they believe is about to resign because of concerns that the resignation will be viewed negatively by market participants and perhaps even regulators. 6 Because our sample consists of all firms with an incumbent Big N auditor, the only possible outcomes are a lateral

    switch to another Big N auditor, a downward switch to a non-Big N auditor, or no switch. Thus, our analysis does not include upward switches from a non-Big N auditor to a Big N auditor.

  • 12

    Analytics database, which only covers the period from 2000-present.7 We exclude companies in

    the financial services sector (SIC codes 6000-6999) because of its unique operating environment

    and differences in accounting classifications that make inferences difficult in subsequent

    analyses. The sample period begins with the first year of available data, and in the pre-Enron

    period ends in the year prior to the Enron scandal. The pre-Enron (1993-2001) sample thus

    spans a period of relative stability in the audit market, with only one merger among the major

    audit firms between Coopers & Lybrand and Price Waterhouse in 1998 and prior to the

    dissolution of Arthur Anderson and subsequent governance reforms that together caused many

    public companies and their auditors to reassess their business relationship.8 Our post-Enron

    period is limited by data availability to the three fiscal years, 2002-2004, where fiscal year is

    defined as on Compustat.

    The databases obtain the identity of both the predecessor and successor auditors for all

    switches from a search of SEC filings and other sources. Both databases also provide

    information on whether the auditor resigned or was dismissed by the client, as reported in the 8-

    K filing, the date of the change, and total sales revenue in the last fiscal year audited by the

    predecessor auditor.

    Table 1 reports the frequency of auditor switches during the pre-Enron (panel A) and

    post-Enron (panel B) periods. We classify each change based on the identity of the predecessor

    and successor auditor. Of the 5,369 switches in panel A, lateral switches among non-Big N

    auditors occur with the greatest frequency (1,868 or 34.8%). Lateral switches among Big N

    7 Source: Auditor-Trak. Copyright 2003 by Strafford Publications, Inc. All rights reserved. Used by permission.

    We do not have access to AuditorTrak data post 2001, but do have access to Auditor Analytics. Both datasets are comprehensive, and we are not aware of any biases in either database that would confound comparisons of results across time periods. 8 We exclude all auditor switches after October 15, 2001 (the date Enron announced its restatement plans) from the

    pre-Enron period.

  • 13

    auditors are the second most common type (1,632 or 30.4%), surpassing downward switches

    from a Big N to a non-Big N auditor (1,181 or 22.0%). Finally, there are relatively few upward

    switches to a Big N auditor (688 or 12.8%). A very different picture emerges, however, when

    the data are weighted by the clients total sales revenue in the year prior to the change.9 These

    findings reveal that the overwhelming majority of activity occurs among Big N firms,

    representing 87.1% of sales-weighted auditor switches in the pre-Enron period.

    The remaining columns in table 1, panel A, partition the data into auditor resignations

    and client dismissals. The results are generally similar in both analyses, although lateral Big N

    switches are relatively less common in the case of an auditor resignation, while downward

    switches to a non-Big N auditor are relatively more common. However, in both partitions,

    lateral Big N switches continue to dominate in economic importance. On a sales-weighted basis,

    71.6% of auditor resignations and 90.2% of client dismissals are among Big N auditors.

    The findings in table 1, panel A, provide clear evidence of the importance of lateral Big

    N auditor switches relative to other types of auditor switches. Clearly, lateral Big N switches

    represent the most economically significant set of auditor switches, and thus are of inherent

    interest. Moreover, as discussed above, most prior research pools all types of auditor switches,

    or concentrates on switches between Big N and non-Big N auditors. By focusing on lateral Big

    N switches, this paper extends the literature to an important, yet mostly overlooked, segment of

    auditor switches. Unless otherwise noted, the remainder of the analysis in this paper refers to

    this set of lateral switches among Big N auditors.

    Table 1, panel B documents similar statistics for the post-Enron period (2002-2004). The

    findings here indicate lateral Big N switches have become less frequent than downward switches,

    but still dominate on a sales-weighted basis (80.6%). The lower frequency of lateral Big N

    9 All sales-weighted statistics reported in the paper have been adjusted for inflation.

  • 14

    switches relative to downward switches indicates the audit market has undergone some changes,

    some of which are expected given the reduction in the number of Big N auditors in this period

    because of the loss of Arthur Andersen. However, other changes, such as increased auditing

    requirements, may also be affecting the statistics. For instance, Plitch and Wei (2004) notes a

    recent escalation in auditor switches pooling across all types, which the authors attribute to

    companies rotating auditors as part of an effort to strengthen corporate governance and a

    reluctance on the part of large audit firms to retain smaller clients amid new and more extensive

    auditing requirements. Whether these factors have led to any substantive post-Enron changes in

    the risk profiles of companies switching auditors is an empirical question that we address in

    section 5.

    Table 2 reports descriptive statistics for lateral Big N switches by calendar year. The

    findings reveal that the frequency of lateral Big N switches increased somewhat in the 1997-

    2001 time frame and have since slowed in the post-Enron period.10 A similar pattern is observed

    for dismissals. Resignations appear to have peaked in the 1998-2000 time frame, with the

    exception of a substantial spike in 2003. The last two columns present comparison statistics for

    the Compustat population of non-switch observations with a Big N auditor. These findings also

    show a somewhat higher frequency of observations, particularly on a sales-weighted basis, in the

    latter half of the sample period.

    10 The unusually high sales-weighted switch frequency of 17.0% in 2000 is largely attributable to both Hewlett

    Packard and Compaq Computer changing auditors from PricewaterhouseCoopers to Ernst & Young because of independence concerns arising from Hewlett Packards possible acquisition of Compaq and PWC Consulting. Also in that year, Verizon merged with GTE and the merged entity concurrently changed auditors to Ernst & Young. Without these four switches, all of which were considered dismissals, the sales-weighted switch frequency in 2000 is 15.0% in the pooled sample and 14.2% in the dismissals sample. Similarly, the unusually high sales-weighted switch frequency in the 1998 resignations sample is attributable to the merger of British Petroleum and Amoco and the concurrent resignation of PricewaterhouseCoopers as the combined entitys auditor. Without this change, the sales-weighted switch frequency in the 1998 resignation sample is 6.8%.

  • 15

    4. Results from the pre-Enron era

    4.1. Univariate tests

    Table 3 presents means and medians for the regressors appearing in the estimating

    equations for the pre-Enron (1993-2001) sample. Panel A presents statistics comparing

    differences in means and medians for the switch and no switch subsamples; panel B presents

    analogous statistics for dismissals and resignations within the switch subsample. Because of

    missing data, the regression sample contains 1,203 lateral Big N auditor switches, consisting of

    1,046 client dismissals and 157 auditor resignations. The corresponding sample of no switch

    observations includes all firm-years on Compustat with a Big N auditor in both the current and

    prior year (i.e., years t and t 1) that did not switch auditors (whether lateral, downward, or

    upward) within 2 years, resulting in 26,302 non-switch observations. We winsorize all non-

    indicator variables at the 1% and 99% levels.

    Panel A reveals that companies switching to another Big N auditor are more likely to

    have received a going concern opinion from their incumbent Big N auditor (GC) and have a

    shorter history with that incumbent (TENURE). In addition, companies switching between Big

    N auditors are significantly less profitable (ROA and LOSS) and more highly levered

    (LEVERAGE) than companies that do not switch Big N auditors. Finally, companies switching

    between Big N auditors are less likely to have an incumbent auditor that is an expert in the

    clients industry (EXPERT), are smaller (SIZE), and are more likely to have recently engaged in

    merger and acquisition activity (M&A). The results in panel B indicate that among companies

    that switch laterally between Big N auditors, those that do so because of an auditor resignation

    are significantly less profitable, smaller, more likely to have received a going concern or other

  • 16

    modified opinion, and have a shorter track record with the incumbent than companies that

    dismiss their Big N auditor.

    In summary, the findings in table 3 suggest that companies switching laterally between

    Big N auditors are riskier than those retaining their incumbent Big N auditor (panel A), and that

    auditor resignations are associated with riskier clients than client dismissals (panel B). In

    interpreting these results, we emphasize that the sample of auditor switches in our analysis is

    distinctly different from prior research in that it contains only lateral Big N switches. By

    implication, then, the risky clients in our sample are not excluded from the Big N audit market,

    even when the incumbent Big N auditor resigns from the engagement. In the next section, we

    further investigate the risk profile of companies changing laterally between Big N auditors using

    the logistic regression model developed above.

    4.2. Regression analysis of lateral Big N auditor switches

    Table 4 presents regression summary statistics for estimations of the logistic regression

    model. The first set of results, labeled Binary Logit Estimation, includes all lateral Big N

    auditor switches in a binary logistic regression with the sample of companies not switching Big N

    auditors as the reference category. The second set of results, labeled Multinomial Logit

    Estimation, is for a single multinomial logistic regression that permits different coefficient

    estimates for auditor switches identified as dismissals and resignations, with companies not

    switching Big N auditors as the reference category. The final column in the table presents

    significance levels for tests of coefficient differences between the dismissal and resignation

    subsamples in the multinomial estimation. For parsimony, year and industry fixed-effects are not

    tabulated, although some of the individual coefficients are significant.

  • 17

    Results for the sample of all lateral Big N switches reveal that many of the coefficient

    estimates are significant and are consistent with audit risk increasing the probability of a lateral

    Big N switch. Specifically, the coefficient estimate on GROWTH is significantly positive, which

    is consistent with the findings of Stice (1991). In addition, the issuance of either a going concern

    (GC) or otherwise modified audit opinion (MODOP) significantly increases the probability of a

    lateral switch in Big N auditors, as does shorter tenure with the client (TENURE) and less

    expertise in the clients industry (EXPERT). Finally, the control variables, SIZE and M&A, are

    significant in the predicted direction, indicating that the likelihood of switching Big N auditors is

    decreasing in client firm size and increasing in the incidence of recent merger or acquisition

    activity. Among the audit risk measures, only the coefficient estimates on the discretionary

    accruals variables are insignificant.

    The results on the financial risk variables are also generally consistent with expectations

    and the univariate tests in table 3. In particular, the positive and significant coefficient estimate

    on LOSS indicates that loss companies are more likely to switch laterally to another Big N

    auditor. The coefficient estimate on ROA, however, is insignificant, suggesting that reported

    profitability is not incrementally important in the switch decision. Only when LOSS is excluded

    from the estimation is the coefficient estimate on ROA significantly negative (results

    untabulated). Also as expected, LEVERAGE has a significant positive effect on the probability

    of switching between Big N auditors.

    The remaining columns of table 4 present findings from the multinomial logit estimation

    that permits coefficient estimates to differ for lateral Big N auditor switches identified by the

    client as dismissals or resignations. With one exception, the findings for dismissals parallel those

    of the pooled model; specifically, the issuance of a going concern audit opinion does not

  • 18

    significantly increase the probability that the incumbent will be dismissed in favor of another Big

    N auditor. The results for resignations are also generally consistent with the pooled model,

    although client growth, the issuance of a modified audit opinion, and auditor expertise are not

    significant at traditional levels. Finally, it is not surprising that the coefficient estimate on the

    control variable M&A is insignificant for resignations, as there is no reason to expect auditors to

    resign from clients that have recently engaged in a merger or acquisition. The final column of

    table 4 reveals that most of the differences in coefficient estimates between lateral Big N

    dismissals and resignations are insignificant. However, the probability a Big N auditor will

    resign rather than be dismissed from an engagement increases with the issuance of a going

    concern audit opinion and decreases with auditor tenure.

    Although the focus of our study is not on the distinction between resignations and

    dismissals, we note that these findings are consistent with Krishnan and Krishnan (1997), which

    pools all auditor switches, including downward switches to a non-Big N auditor. Krishnan and

    Krishnan (1997) concludes, however, that the studys evidence supports claims that risk

    avoidance by the Big N leads to the withdrawal of audit services for an important segment of the

    market, even though they do not examine the direction of the auditor switch. Because our sample

    consists entirely of lateral Big N auditor switches, our findings contradict this conclusion.

    Instead, we show that even though Big N firms are more likely to resign from clients with certain

    risk characteristics, another Big N firm is willing to audit these risky clients. Thus, although

    prior studies document risk differences between clients whose auditor resigned and clients that

    dismiss their auditor (Krishnan and Krishnan, 1997; Shu, 2000) or continue with their incumbent

    auditor (Shu, 2000; Johnstone and Bedard, 2004), this is the first study to show that these same

    risk characteristics also explain lateral switches among Big N auditors.

  • 19

    4.3. Comparison of lateral Big N and downward switches

    Although the findings presented in table 4 are consistent with an increased likelihood of a

    lateral switch in Big N auditors for riskier clients, the evidence does not address the related issue

    of the extent to which client risk distinguishes between lateral and downward switches to a non-

    Big N auditor. The assumption in prior research is that riskier clients switching from one of the

    Big N firms will engage a smaller, non-Big N auditor rather than another Big N auditor.

    However, as discussed above, there is limited evidence on this question and the results are

    inconclusive. In this section we present evidence from a multinomial logit estimation that

    permits coefficient estimates to differ for lateral and downward switches. T-tests for pairwise

    coefficient differences, conducted separately for dismissals and resignations, indicate whether

    client risk factors distinguish between the likelihood a client will change laterally to another Big

    N auditor or move downward to a non-Big N auditor. The sample of downward switches

    includes all companies switching from a Big N to a non-Big N auditor, while the sample of non-

    switch observations is the same as above.

    Table 5, panel A, presents summary statistics from the multinomial logit estimation, and

    panel B presents p-values for tests of coefficient differences. Because the estimation sample in

    table 5 includes downward switches in addition to lateral Big N switches, the coefficient

    estimates for lateral Big N dismissals and resignations are not identical to the coefficient

    estimates reported in table 4. However, the results are quite similar, and none of our previous

    inferences regarding lateral Big N switches is altered. More importantly, the findings show that

    lateral Big N and downward switches are sensitive to the same client risk characteristics. For

    example, of the 8 coefficient estimates that are significant at the 0.10 level or less for lateral Big

    N dismissals, 6 are also significant in the same direction for downward dismissals. Unlike lateral

  • 20

    dismissals, LEVERAGE and M&A are insignificant for downward dismissals, while a going

    concern audit opinion and negative discretionary accruals (ACC + ACC*NEGACC) are

    incrementally significant. The latter result is consistent with the findings of DeFond and

    Subramanyan (1998) showing that companies dismiss incumbent auditors that impose

    conservative accounting choices in hopes of finding a less conservative successor auditor.

    The findings in table 5, panel A, also reveal that 4 of the 5 variables that are significant

    for lateral Big N resignations are also significant for downward resignations. Similar to the

    dismissal results, however, LEVERAGE is insignificant for downward resignations. In addition,

    the likelihood of a downward resignation increases significantly for companies with poor

    financial performance (ROA), low growth (GROWTH), a modified audit opinion (MODOP), and

    an incumbent auditor with less expertise in the clients industry (EXPERT).

    Despite the similarities between lateral Big N and downward auditor switches observable

    in panel A, the coefficient estimates for downward switches are generally of greater magnitude.

    Inspection of the p-values for tests of coefficient differences reported in panel B, however,

    reveals that many of the coefficient differences between lateral and downward switches are

    insignificant. The likelihood of a downward switch, whether by dismissal or resignation, is

    decreasing in client size and growth and the tenure of the incumbent Big N auditor. In addition,

    downward dismissals are more sensitive than lateral dismissals to a going concern opinion and to

    positive (ACC) and negative (ACC+ACC*NEGACC) discretionary accruals. Contrary to

    expectations, lateral Big N switches, both dismissals and resignations, are more sensitive to

    client leverage than downward switches. Finally, untabulated findings reveal that 20% of the

    downward sample had switched upward to a Big N auditor within the previous five years.

    Excluding these companies from the estimation generally does not affect inferences, although the

  • 21

    coefficient estimates on GC and negative discretionary accruals (ACC+ACC*NEGACC) are no

    longer significantly different.

    It is important to note that most of the significant differences between the lateral and

    downward samples in table 5, panel B, are related to client dismissals, not auditor resignations.

    Moreover, the downward switches appear to represent small clients with going concern opinions,

    and thus are arguably no longer of interest to the Big N. Untabulated statistics indicate that

    downward switch companies are much smaller than lateral switch companies. Specifically, the

    lower size quartile of lateral Big N switches is larger than the upper size quartile of downward

    switches. Additional untabulated statistics reveal that more than 25% of downward switches had

    going concern opinions in the year prior to the change, compared to only 7% of lateral Big N

    switches. Many of these going concern companies likely face bankruptcy, which could preclude

    their ability to afford a Big N auditor or create independence issues if there are outstanding fees

    to the incumbent Big N auditor. Consequently, our evidence suggests that large, risky

    companies are able to switch laterally within the Big N audit tier, while small companies that

    generally pose less risk to the auditor, all else equal, switch downward to a non-Big N auditor.

    4.4. Sensitivity analyses

    We conduct several additional analyses to assess the robustness of our results. First, we

    examine whether our results are distinct from switches due to auditor realignment or clientele

    mismatch (e.g., Johnson and Lys, 1990, Shu, 2000). Specifically, following the procedure in Shu

    (2000), we calculate an annual index measure for each client that captures how well that client is

    matched with its current auditor, and then determine an optimal cut-off probability that predicts

    whether a client is better matched with a Big N or non-Big N auditor. If an actual auditor-client

  • 22

    pairing is opposite to the prediction in the current year but not in the prior year, then the client

    has become mismatched with its auditor and the likelihood of a switch is expected to increase.

    In untabulated analyses, we find that the clientele mismatch variable is incrementally

    positive and significant at the 0.01 level for downward switches, whether dismissals or

    resignations. This finding is consistent with the results reported by Shu (2000). Importantly,

    however, we find that the clientele mismatch variable is insignificant in explaining lateral Big N

    auditor switches, while none of the inferences regarding our client risk variables is altered.11

    Thus, we show that our results regarding the lateral movement of risky clients between Big N

    auditors are distinct from prior evidence regarding clientele adjustment or auditor realignment.

    Second, we examine whether our results are robust across Big N auditors by permitting

    the coefficient estimates in our logistic model to differ for each Big N successor auditor.

    Untabulated results reveal no significant differences in the coefficient estimates across auditors.

    Thus, our results do not appear to be driven by the behavior of one or a few of the Big N

    auditors.

    Third, we investigate the frequency of reportable events and accounting disagreements

    for clients switching laterally between Big N auditors and downwards to a non-Big N auditor.

    Reportable events and accounting disagreements disclosed at the time of the switch are generally

    viewed to be indicative of client risk.12 The untabulated results reveal that lateral Big N

    (downward) switches are accompanied by a reportable event 7.3% (9.1%) of the time and by an

    11 For completeness, in these analyses we also include the summary measure of litigation risk that is the other

    primary variable of interest in Shu (2000). Except for downward resignations, this variable is not incrementally significant. 12

    SEC rules require registrants to report a change in auditor by filing a Form 8-K within five days of the change. Among other disclosure requirements, the company must reveal whether in the two most recent fiscal years the auditor had advised them of any of the following reportable events: (i) internal controls necessary to develop reliable financial statements do not exist; (ii) the auditor was unwilling to rely on managements representations; (iii) the scope of the audit needs to be significantly expanded; or (iv) information has become available that materially affects the fairness or reliability of a previously issued audit report or financial statements. The company must also disclose any disagreements on accounting matters even if resolved to the auditors satisfaction.

  • 23

    accounting disagreement 4.6% (5.7%) of the time. These frequencies are not statistically

    different at the 10% level. Thus, consistent with our primary results, riskier clients are no more

    likely to be excluded from the Big N audit market.

    5. Results from the post-Enron era

    The results for the 1993-2001 period indicate that risky clients switch between Big N

    auditors rather than being forced to move to lower tier auditors as the popular press suggests.

    However, given the many legal and regulatory changes subsequent to Enrons collapse, the

    auditing market experienced a significant number of changes including the loss of one of the Big

    N auditors (Andersen), as well as restrictions on the services auditors are allowed to perform.

    These changes, coupled with the realization that the risk posed by clients is likely higher than

    previously thought, could have significantly affected the auditor switch market. To determine

    whether this is the case, we repeat the analyses in tables 4 and 5 utilizing a sample of companies

    from the post-Enron period (2002-2004). In conducting these analyses, we exclude all auditor

    switches where Arthur Andersen was the predecessor auditor, as these companies were forced to

    change auditors (Blouin et al., 2005), a fundamentally different situation from the auditor

    switches examined in this paper and the prior literature.

    In contrast to the pre-Enron findings, the results from the binary logit estimation reported

    in table 6 indicate that only the control variables EXPERT, SIZE and M&A are significant in the

    post-Enron period. The multinomial logistic regression that permits coefficient estimates to

    differ for dismissals and resignations reveals similar findings for both types of auditor switches

    with the exception of M&A which is insignificant for resignations. Tests of coefficient

    differences in the last column of table 6 reveal no significant differences between lateral Big N

    dismissals and resignations in the post-Enron period.

  • 24

    Table 7 compares lateral Big N and downward switches in the post-Enron period.

    Although the coefficient estimates in the lateral Big N switch columns may differ from those

    reported in table 6 because of the inclusion of downward switches in the estimation, all

    inferences regarding post-Enron lateral Big N switches remain unchanged. Unlike the results for

    the lateral Big N switches, several of the coefficient estimates for the downward switches,

    whether dismissals or resignations, retain their significance in the post-Enron period.

    To facilitate comparison of the findings of the pre- and post-Enron periods, table 8

    reports a summary of the results from tests of coefficient differences in the pre- and post-Enron

    periods. A Yes indicates the coefficients across the comparison categories (e.g., Lateral

    Dismissal versus Lateral Resignation) are significantly different at or below the 10% level, while

    a No indicates the coefficient differences are not significantly different. The comparison of

    lateral Big N dismissals versus resignations reveals no significant coefficient differences in the

    post-Enron period, compared to just two in the pre-Enron period. The results for lateral versus

    downward dismissals and lateral versus downward resignations also indicate there are fewer

    significant differences in the post-Enron period. However, in both instances, several of the

    significant coefficient differences continue to exist in the post-Enron period. Moreover, as in the

    pre-Enron period, the significant differences relate primarily to client dismissals, and appear to

    represent small clients with going concern opinions.

    Although the post-Enron findings should be interpreted with caution because of limited

    data availability, the results reported above suggest there have been some changes in the market

    for audit switches in the post-Enron era. Most importantly, lateral Big N switches, particularly

    auditor resignations, have become less frequent relative to downward switches (table 1).

    Although this decline in lateral Big N switches could be simply the result of a smaller number of

  • 25

    Big N auditors, we also find that audit and financial risk factors of clients are no longer

    significantly associated with lateral Big N auditor switches (table 6). Taken together, these

    findings provide some evidence that risky firms are less likely to switch laterally to another Big

    N auditor in the post-Enron environment. There appears to be fewer post-Enron changes in

    downward switches, as it is still small companies with going concern opinions that are excluded

    from the Big N auditor market. As more data become available, exploration of post-Enron

    auditor switches, both laterally between the remaining Big N auditors and downwards to non-Big

    N auditors, is likely to provide further insights into the forces affecting auditors risk

    management decisions.

    6. Summary and conclusion

    This study examines a comprehensive sample of lateral switches among Big N auditors to

    investigate the extent to which risky clients are excluded from the Big N audit market in the pre-

    Enron (1993-2001) and post-Enron (2002-2004) eras. Understanding auditors risk management

    practices is of great importance to auditors, managers, regulators, and academics, particularly in

    light of the accounting scandals that have recently rocked the auditing industry. We examine the

    decade preceding these events to better understand characteristics of lateral switches among Big

    N auditors in general and as a means of establishing baseline results for our examination of

    auditor switches in the new environment.

    To investigate the client risk factors associated with lateral Big N auditor switches, we

    estimate a logit regression that models auditor switches as a function of a set of variables that

    measure client audit and financial risk. Our results show that the probability of a lateral Big N

    auditor switch is significantly increasing in both dimensions of client risk. Moreover, we find

    that similar risk factors are associated with lateral Big N dismissals and resignations. Findings

  • 26

    from robustness tests reveal no systematic differences between individual Big N auditors. We

    also compare the risk profile of lateral Big N auditor switches with downward switches to a non-

    Big N auditor, and find that lateral and downward switches are sensitive to similar client risk

    characteristics. The downward switches generally comprise much smaller companies with going

    concern opinions, suggesting that the Big N are willing to accept large, risky clients that have left

    another Big N firm, but are unwilling to accept clients that pose less risk because of their small

    size but are also are likely to be less profitable.

    The analysis of the post-Enron period indicates that downward switches have become

    more frequent than lateral Big N switches. More importantly, several risk factors that were

    significant determinants of lateral Big N auditor switches in the pre-Enron period are no longer

    significant in the post-Enron period, consistent with a shift in the risk management practices of

    the remaining Big N auditors. However, downward switches to a non-Big N auditor continue to

    relate to small clients with going concern opinions.

    Taken together, we provide several key new findings not documented in the prior

    literature on auditor switches. By focusing on lateral Big N auditor switches, we are able to

    show that although the relationship between risky clients and one Big N auditor may be

    terminated, one of the other Big N firms is willing to accept the engagement. Our post-Enron

    analysis, however, suggests that Big N auditors may have become more sensitive to risky clients

    in recent years. As such, our study not only offers insights into prior research on auditor

    switching, but also suggests opportunities for future research. Because our post-Enron analysis

    is limited to a few years, additional work can be done as more data becomes available. In

    addition, researchers could explore the economic forces underlying the swapping of risky clients.

  • 27

    References

    Bell, T. B., Landsman, W. R., Shackelford, D.A., 2001. Auditors perceived business risk and audit fees: analysis and evidence. Journal of Accounting Research 39, 35-43.

    Berton, L., 1995. Big accounting firms weed out risky clients. The Wall Street Journal, June 26, B1.

    Blouin, J., Grein, B., Rountree, B. R., 2005. An analysis of forced auditor rotation: the case of former Arthur Andersen clients. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania.

    Bockus, K., Gigler, F., 1998. A theory of auditor resignation. Journal of Accounting Research 36, 191-208.

    Bradshaw, M. T., Richardson, S. A., Sloan, R. G., 2001. Do analysts and auditors use information in accruals? Journal of Accounting Research 39, 45-74.

    Choi, J-H., Doogar, R., Ganguly, A. R., 2004. The riskiness of large audit firm client portfolios and changes in audit liability regimes: evidence from the U.S. audit market. Contemporary Accounting Research 21, 747-785.

    Chow, C. W., Rice, S.J., 1982. Qualified audit opinions and auditor wwitching. The Accounting Review 57, 326-335.

    Cook, J. M., Freedman, E. M. , Groves, R. J., Madonna, J. C., OMalley, S. F., Weinbach, L. A., 1992. The Liability crisis in the United States: impact on the accounting profession. Journal of Accountancy 174, 19-23.

    DeAngelo, L. E., 1981. Auditor size and audit quality. Journal of Accounting and Economics 3, 183-199.

    DeFond, M. L., Subramanyam, K.R., 1998. Auditor changes and discretionary accruals. Journal of Accounting and Economics 25, 35-67.

    Francis, J. R., Wilson, E. R., 1988. Auditor changes: a joint test of theories relating to agency costs and auditor differentiation. The Accounting Review 63, 663-682.

    Haskins, M. E., Williams, D. D., 1990. A contingent model of intra-Big Eight auditor changes. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory 9, 55-74.

    Heninger, W. G., 2001. The association between auditor litigation and abnormal accruals. The Accounting Review 76, 111-126.

    Hindo, B., 2003. Audit clients get the heave-ho. Business Week, December 1, 7.

  • 28

    Hogan, C. E., Jeter, D. C., 1999. Industry specialization by auditors. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory 8, 1-17.

    Holland, K., Light, L., Galen, M., 1993. Big Six firms are firing clients. Business Week, March 1, 76-77.

    Johnson, W. B., Lys, T., 1990. The market for audit services: evidence from voluntary auditor changes. Journal of Accounting and Economics 12, 281-308.

    Johnstone, K. M. Client-acceptance decisions: simultaneous effects of client business risk, audit risk, and auditor business risk, and risk adaptation. Auditing: A Journal of Practice and Theory 19, 1-25.

    Johnstone, K. M., Bedard, J. C., 2003. Risk management in client acceptance decisions. The Accounting Review 78, 1003-1025.

    Johnstone, K. M., Bedard, J. C. 2004. Audit firm portfolio management decisions. Journal of Accounting Research 42, 659-690.

    Kothari, S. P., Leone, A., Wasley, C., 2005. Performance matched discretionary accrual measures. Journal of Accounting and Economics 3, 163-207.

    Krishnan, J., 1994. Auditor switching and conservatism. The Accounting Review 69, 200-215.

    Krishnan, J., Krishnan, J., 1997. Litigation risk and auditor resignations. The Accounting Review 72, 539-560.

    Lys, T., Watts, R. L., 1994. Lawsuits against auditors. Journal of Accounting Research 32, 65-93.

    MacDonald, E., 1997. More accounting firms are dumping risky clients: Big Six worry about their reputations and chance of costly litigation. The Wall Street Journal, April 25, A2.

    OKeefe, T. B., Simunic, D. A., Stein, M. T., 1994. The production of audit services: evidence from a major public accounting rirm. Journal of Accounting Research 32, 241-261.

    Plitch, P., Wei, L., 2004. Auditor-client breakups rise, while disclosure often lags. The Wall Street Journal, August 3, C3.

    Schwartz, K. B., Menon, K., 1985. Auditor switches by failing firms. The Accounting Review 60, 248-261.

    Shu, S. Z., 2000. Auditor resignations: clientele effects and legal liability. Journal of Accounting and Economics 29, 173-205.

  • 29

    Stice, J. D.. 1991. Using financial and market information to identify pre-engagement factors associated with lawsuits against public accountants. The Accounting Review 66, 516-533.

  • 30

    Table 1 Relative Importance of Auditor Switches for Big N and non-Big N Auditors

    Panel A: Auditor Switches by Type (1993-2001) Pooled Resignations Dismissals Sales Sales Sales

    Direction of Change Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Non-Big N to Big N (Up) 688 12.8 2.4 58 4.6 1.6 630 15.3 2.6 Big N to non-Big N (Down) 1,181 22.0 6.0 443 35.2 25.1 738 18.0 2.2 Lateral non-Big N 1,868 34.8 4.4 532 42.3 1.7 1,336 32.5 5.0 Lateral Big N 1,632 30.4 87.1 226 18.0 71.6 1,406 34.2 90.2 Total 5,369 100.0 100.0 1,384 100.0 100.0 5,022 100.0 100.0

    Panel B: Auditor Switches by Type (2002-2004) Pooled Resignations Dismissals Sales Sales Sales

    Direction of Change Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Non-Big N to Big N (Up) 112 3.0 3.4 21 1.8 4.3 91 3.6 3.3 Big N to non-Big N (Down) 796 21.6 11.3 283 23.9 31.7 513 20.5 8.5 Lateral non-Big N 2,397 65.0 4.7 826 69.9 12.2 1,571 62.8 3.7 Lateral Big N 380 10.3 80.6 52 4.4 51.8 328 13.1 84.5 Total 3,685 100.0 100.0 1,182 100.0 100.0 2,503 100.0 100.0 This table provides descriptive statistics on auditor switches between January 1, 1993 and October 15, 2001 in Panel A, and January 1, 2002 and December 31, 2004 in Panel B (Post-Enron), except for companies in the financial service industries (SIC codes 6000-6999). Big N auditors are defined as Arthur Andersen, Deloitte & Touche, Ernst & Young, KPMG, and PricewaterhouseCoopers or its predecessor firms, Price Waterhouse and Coopers & Lybrand. All other auditors are classified as non-Big N. Switches from Arthur Andersen as a result of their collapse are excluded in Panel B. Sales in the sales-weighted calculations is for the last fiscal year audited by the predecessor auditor, per the AuditorTrak database in the 1993-2001 period and Auditor Analytics in the 2002-2004 period (supplemented by Compustat data if necessary), adjusted for inflation.

  • 31

    Table 2 Characteristics of Lateral Switches among Big N Auditors

    Pooled Resignations Dismissals Compustat Population Calendar Sales Sales Sales Sales

    Year Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Number Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) Freq. (%) Wtd. (%) 1993 153 7.6 2.0 10 3.6 0.5 143 8.2 2.2 7.8 6.0 1994 168 8.3 4.8 20 7.2 1.1 148 8.5 5.3 8.1 6.4 1995 177 8.8 6.4 21 7.6 2.9 156 9.0 6.8 8.7 7.2 1996 142 7.1 4.3 21 7.6 1.2 121 7.0 4.7 9.7 7.8 1997 199 9.9 7.3 24 8.6 1.3 175 10.1 8.1 9.9 8.2 1998 192 9.5 8.7 37 13.3 40.8 155 8.9 4.5 9.4 8.2 1999 197 9.8 9.0 36 12.9 10.9 161 9.3 8.8 9.3 8.7 2000 205 10.2 17.0 38 13.7 9.4 167 9.6 18.0 8.7 9.6 2001 199 9.9 8.4 19 6.8 10.9 180 10.4 8.1 8.1 9.6 2002 122 6.1 4.7 10 3.6 6.2 112 6.5 4.5 7.3 8.8 2003 159 7.9 14.9 28 10.1 11.9 131 7.6 15.3 6.9 9.7 2004 99 4.9 12.5 14 5.0 3.0 85 4.9 13.8 6.0 9.7

    Total 2,012 100.0 100.0 278 100.0 100.0 1,734 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 This table provides descriptive statistics on auditor switches between January 1, 1993 and May 31, 2005, except for companies in the financial service industries (SIC codes 6000-6999). Big N auditors are defined as Arthur Andersen, Deloitte & Touche, Ernst & Young, KPMG, and PricewaterhouseCoopers or its predecessor firms, Price Waterhouse and Coopers & Lybrand. Except for the Compustat Population, sales in the sales-weighted calculations are for the last fiscal year audited by the predecessor auditor adjusted for inflation. Data for the Compustat Population are obtained from Compustat, and are based on all firm-years on Compustat during 1993-2004 with a Big N auditor in both the current and prior year.

  • 32

    Table 3 Descriptive Statistics on Regression Variables, 1993-2001

    Panel A: Comparison of Switch and No Switch Samples Mean Median

    Variable No Change Change No Change Change GROWTH 0.14 0.14 0.07 0.06 ACC 0.00* 0.01 0.00 0.00 NEGACC 0.52 0.52 1.00 1.00 GC 0.03 0.07*** 0.00 0.00*** MODOP 0.14 0.16 0.00 0.00 TENURE 6.89*** 6.08 7.00*** 6.00 ROA 0.04*** 0.13 0.03*** 0.00 LOSS 0.32 0.48*** 0.00 0.00*** LEVERAGE 0.23 0.27*** 0.20 0.23*** EXPERT 0.31*** 0.25 0.00*** 0.00 SIZE 5.21*** 4.42 5.07*** 4.27 M&A 0.31 0.36*** 0.00 0.00***

    N 26,302 1,203 26,302 1,203

    Panel B: Comparison of Resignations and Dismissals for the Switch Sample Mean Median

    Variable Dismissal Resignation Dismissal Resignation GROWTH 0.15 0.12 0.07 0.02 ACC 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.02 NEGACC 0.52 0.52 1.00 1.00 GC 0.06 0.17*** 0.00 0.00*** MODOP 0.17** 0.11 0.00* 0.00 TENURE 6.21*** 5.22 6.00*** 4.00 ROA 0.11*** 0.23 0.01*** 0.05 LOSS 0.46 0.61*** 0.00 1.00*** LEVERAGE 0.27 0.28 0.23 0.23 EXPERT 0.26 0.22 0.00 0.00 SIZE 4.47*** 4.05 4.32** 3.98 M&A 0.36 0.34 0.00 0.00

    N 1,046 157 1,046 157

  • 33

    Table 3 Continued The Switch sample consists of firm-years during 1993-2001 with a lateral switch among Big N auditors. The No Switch sample consists of firm-years during 1993-2001 with a Big N auditor in both the current and prior year that did not switch auditors (whether lateral, downward, or upward) within 2 years. GROWTH is total assets less beginning total assets, divided by beginning total assets. ACC is performance-adjusted discretionary total accruals. NEGACC equals 1 if ACC is negative, and 0 otherwise. GC equals 1 if the audit opinion is a going concern, and 0 otherwise. MODOP equals 1 if the audit opinion is modified for anything other than a going concern, and 0 otherwise. TENURE is the number of years audited by the incumbent auditor, with a maximum of 10 years. ROA is net income before extraordinary items, divided by average total assets. LOSS equals 1 if ROA < 0, and 0 otherwise. LEVERAGE is long-term debt divided by total assets. EXPERT equals 1 if the incumbent auditor has at least 5% more clients in a particular industry and state than any other auditor, and 0 otherwise. SIZE is the natural logarithm of market value of equity. M&A equals 1 if the client engaged in a merger or acquisition in the preceding two years, and 0 otherwise. All non-indicator variables are winsorized at the 1% and 99% levels.

    *, **, and *** indicate variable is significantly greater than the corresponding value at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively, using two-tailed tests.

  • 34

    Table 4 Regressions of Lateral Big N Auditor Switches on Client Risk Characteristics, 1993-2001

    Model:

    = + + + + +

    + + + + + +

    + + + +

    it t I 1 it 1 2 it 1 3 it 1 4 it 1 it 1t I5 it 1 6 it 1 7 it 1 8 it 1 9 it 1 10 it 1

    11 it 1 12 it 1 13 it 1 it

    SWITCH GROWTH ACC NEGACC ACC NEGACCGC MODOP TENURE ROA LOSS LEVERAGEEXPERT SIZE M & A

    Binary Logit Estimation Multinomial Logit Estimation Tests of All Switches Dismissals Resignations Differences

    Variable Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value p-values GROWTH 0.21 0.00 0.24 0.00 0.07 0.56 0.17 ACC 0.40 0.25 0.50 0.19 0.08 0.92 0.51 NEGACC 0.03 0.74 0.04 0.59 0.09 0.69 0.57 ACC*NEGACC 0.32 0.50 0.34 0.51 0.25 0.82 0.94 GC 0.33 0.01 0.15 0.31 0.96 0.00 0.00 MODOP 0.39 0.00 0.40 0.00 0.22 0.42 0.54 TENURE 0.05 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.14 0.00 0.00 ROA 0.09 0.54 0.05 0.74 0.15 0.64 0.78 LOSS 0.38 0.00 0.36 0.00 0.57 0.01 0.35 LEVERAGE 0.46 0.00 0.44 0.00 0.62 0.05 0.60 EXPERT 0.19 0.01 0.17 0.02 0.31 0.12 0.51 SIZE 0.16 0.00 0.16 0.00 0.19 0.00 0.52 M&A 0.21 0.00 0.22 0.00 0.14 0.44 0.69

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC 0.08 0.77 0.16 0.59 0.33 0.63 0.50

    Switch 1,203 1,046 157 No Switch 26,302 26,302 26,302

    See table 3 for variable definitions. The columns labeled Binary Logit Estimation includes all lateral Big N auditor switches for the 1993-2001 period in a binary logistic regression with the sample of companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.05). The columns labeled Multinomial Logit Estimation are for a single multinomial logistic regression for the 1993-2001 period that permits different coefficient estimates for auditor switches identified as dismissals and resignations, with companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.06). The Tests of Differences are for a comparison of the coefficient estimates for Dismissals and Resignations. All p-values are two-tailed.

  • 35

    Table 5 Regression of Lateral Big N and Downward Auditor Switches on Client Risk Characteristics, 1993-2001

    Model:

    = + + + + +

    + + + + + +

    + + + +

    it t I 1 it 1 2 it 1 3 it 1 4 it 1 it 1t I5 it 1 6 it 1 7 it 1 8 it 1 9 it 1 10 it 1

    11 it 1 12 it 1 13 it 1 it

    SWITCH GROWTH ACC NEGACC ACC NEGACCGC MODOP TENURE ROA LOSS LEVERAGEEXPERT SIZE M & A

    Panel A: Summary Statistics from Multinomial Logit Estimation Lateral Big N Switches Downward Switches Dismissals Resignations Dismissals Resignations

    Variable Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value GROWTH 0.24 0.00 0.07 0.57 0.30 0.00 0.33 0.01 ACC 0.49 0.20 0.13 0.87 0.72 0.11 0.72 0.21 NEGACC 0.04 0.60 0.10 0.64 0.04 0.76 0.12 0.55 ACC*NEGACC 0.31 0.54 0.18 0.87 1.94 0.00 1.39 0.09 GC 0.17 0.25 0.99 0.00 0.56 0.00 1.06 0.00 MODOP 0.41 0.00 0.23 0.41 0.55 0.00 0.76 0.00 TENURE 0.04 0.00 0.14 0.00 0.19 0.00 0.26 0.00 ROA 0.04 0.78 0.17 0.60 0.25 0.17 0.67 0.00 LOSS 0.36 0.00 0.55 0.01 0.42 0.00 0.65 0.00 LEVERAGE 0.45 0.00 0.64 0.04 0.11 0.56 0.19 0.46 EXPERT 0.17 0.02 0.31 0.11 0.29 0.02 0.56 0.00 SIZE 0.16 0.00 0.20 0.00 0.84 0.00 0.66 0.00 M&A 0.22 0.00 0.16 0.40 0.07 0.63 0.19 0.28

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC 0.18 0.54 0.32 0.64 1.22 0.00 0.67 0.19

    Switch 1,046 157 473 227 No Switch 26,302 26,302 26,302 26,302

  • 36

    Table 5 Continued

    Panel B: p-values for Tests of Coefficient Differences Lateral Lateral versus Downward Lateral versus Downward

    Variable Dismissals versus Resignations Dismissals Resignations GROWTH 0.16 0.00 0.02 ACC 0.48 0.03 0.55 NEGACC 0.53 1.00 0.45 ACC*NEGACC 0.92 0.00 0.25 GC 0.00 0.05 0.80 MODOP 0.54 0.39 0.12 TENURE 0.00 0.00 0.00 ROA 0.72 0.38 0.20 LOSS 0.39 0.68 0.75 LEVERAGE 0.58 0.01 0.04 EXPERT 0.49 0.40 0.35 SIZE 0.44 0.00 0.00 M&A 0.76 0.06 0.90

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC 0.50 0.03 0.24 See table 3 for variable definitions. The results are from a single multinomial logistic regression for the 1993-2001 period with the sample of companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.19). In panel B, reported p-values are for the indicated tests of differences in coefficient estimates reported in panel A. All p-values are two-tailed.

  • 37

    Table 6 Regressions of Lateral Big N Auditor Switches on Client Risk Characteristics, 2002-2004

    Model:

    = + + + + +

    + + + + + +

    + + + +

    it t I 1 it 1 2 it 1 3 it 1 4 it 1 it 1t I5 it 1 6 it 1 7 it 1 8 it 1 9 it 1 10 it 1

    11 it 1 12 it 1 13 it 1 it

    SWITCH GROWTH ACC NEGACC ACC NEGACCGC MODOP TENURE ROA LOSS LEVERAGEEXPERT SIZE M & A

    Binary Logit Estimation Multinomial Logit Estimation Tests of All Switches Dismissals Resignations Differences

    Variable Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value p-values GROWTH 0.17 0.30 0.20 0.24 -0.07 0.88 0.59 ACC 0.37 0.57 0.62 0.38 -1.42 0.49 0.34 NEGACC 0.08 0.62 0.10 0.57 -0.04 0.93 0.76 ACC*NEGACC -0.03 0.98 -0.32 0.78 2.17 0.49 0.46 GC -0.36 0.37 -0.53 0.26 0.24 0.76 0.40 MODOP 0.15 0.36 0.12 0.50 0.25 0.51 0.76 TENURE -0.03 0.13 -0.02 0.32 -0.09 0.11 0.27 ROA 0.20 0.44 0.18 0.53 0.26 0.70 0.91 LOSS -0.20 0.24 -0.21 0.25 -0.15 0.72 0.90 LEVERAGE -0.13 0.67 -0.29 0.41 0.51 0.47 0.30 EXPERT -1.13 0.00 -1.07 0.00 -1.55 0.04 0.54 SIZE -0.18 0.00 -0.19 0.00 -0.15 0.08 0.73 M&A 0.34 0.02 0.40 0.01 -0.02 0.97 0.33

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC 0.34 0.69 0.29 0.75 0.75 0.74 0.85

    Switch 245 207 38 No Switch 10,315 10,315 10,315

    See table 3 for variable definitions. The estimations use only post-Enron data (2002-2004) and exclude all auditor switches related to the collapse of Arthur Andersen. The columns labeled Binary Logit Estimation includes all lateral Big N auditor switches in a binary logistic regression with the sample of companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.05). The columns labeled Multinomial Logit Estimation are for a single multinomial logistic regression that permits different coefficient estimates for auditor switches identified as dismissals and resignations, with companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.05). The Tests of Differences are for a comparison of the coefficient estimates for Dismissals and Resignations. All p-values are two-tailed.

  • 38

    Table 7 Regression of Lateral Big N and Downward Auditor Switches on Client Risk Characteristics, 2002-2004

    Model:

    = + + + + +

    + + + + + +

    + + + +

    it t I 1 it 1 2 it 1 3 it 1 4 it 1 it 1t I5 it 1 6 it 1 7 it 1 8 it 1 9 it 1 10 it 1

    11 it 1 12 it 1 13 it 1 it

    SWITCH GROWTH ACC NEGACC ACC NEGACCGC MODOP TENURE ROA LOSS LEVERAGEEXPERT SIZE M & A

    Lateral Big N Switches Downward Switches Dismissals Resignations Dismissals Resignations

    Variable Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value Coeff. Est. p-value GROWTH 0.20 0.24 -0.07 0.88 -0.24 0.07 -0.75 0.00 ACC 0.60 0.39 -1.33 0.51 0.18 0.70 0.98 0.09 NEGACC 0.10 0.60 -0.04 0.93 -0.19 0.23 0.11 0.60 ACC*NEGACC -0.37 0.75 2.04 0.52 -1.58 0.04 -1.25 0.21 GC -0.51 0.29 0.27 0.74 0.56 0.00 0.82 0.00 MODOP 0.13 0.48 0.25 0.52 0.37 0.01 0.23 0.26 TENURE -0.02 0.32 -0.09 0.11 0.01 0.55 0.03 0.32 ROA 0.24 0.55 0.12 0.90 -0.69 0.00 -1.10 0.00 LOSS -0.21 0.30 -0.19 0.66 -0.29 0.06 0.32 0.16 LEVERAGE -0.30 0.39 0.48 0.48 -0.42 0.06 -0.50 0.10 EXPERT -1.07 0.00 -1.54 0.04 0.02 0.90 0.00 0.98 SIZE -0.19 0.00 -0.15 0.09 -0.77 0.00 -0.58 0.00 M&A 0.40 0.01 0.00 0.99 -0.15 0.37 0.07 0.75

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC 0.23 0.80 0.71 0.76 -1.40 0.01 -0.27

    Switch 207 38 367 185 No Switch 10,315 10,315 10,315 10,315

    See table 3 for variable definitions. The estimations use only post-Enron data (2002-2004) and exclude all auditor switches related to the collapse of Arthur Andersen. The results are from a single multinomial logistic regression with the sample of companies not changing Big N auditors as the reference category (pseudo R2 = 0.18).

  • 39

    Table 8 Summary of Tests of Coefficient Differences for the pre- and post-Enron Periods

    Lateral Lateral versus Downward Lateral versus Downward Dismissals versus Resignations Dismissals Resignations

    Variable Pre-Enron Post-Enron Pre-Enron Post-Enron Pre-Enron Post-Enron GROWTH No No Yes Yes Yes No ACC No No Yes No No No NEGACC No No No No No No ACC*NEGACC No No Yes No No No GC Yes No Yes Yes No No MODOP No No No No No No TENURE Yes No Yes No Yes Yes ROA No No No Yes No No LOSS No No No No No No LEVERAGE No No Yes No Yes No EXPERT No No No Yes No Yes SIZE No No Yes Yes Yes Yes M&A No No Yes Yes No No

    ACC + ACC*NEGACC No No Yes No No No

    See table 3 for variable definitions. A Yes indicates the coefficients across the comparison categories (e.g., Lateral Dismissal versus Lateral Resignation) are significantly different at or below the 10% level, while a No indicates the coefficient differences are not significantly different. The Pre-Enron (Post-Enron) columns refer to findings for the 1993-2001 (2002-2004) time period.