no unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions;...

4
Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2010) 128–131 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Mathematical Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jmateco Short communication No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions; Equivalent conditions Manh-Hung Nguyen a,, Thai Ha-Huy b a Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA-INRA), 21 allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, France b University of Paris 1 (CES), 75013 Paris, France article info Article history: Received 1 March 2008 Received in revised form 28 April 2009 Accepted 20 May 2009 Available online 11 June 2009 JEL classification: C62 D50 Keywords: Arbitrage Equilibrium Recession cone abstract Page and Wooders [Page Jr., F.H., Wooders, M., 1996. A necessary and sufficient condition for compactness of individually rational and feasible outcomes and existence of an equi- librium. Economics Letters 52, 153–162] prove that the no unbounded arbitrage (NUBA), a special case of a condition in Page [Page, F.H., 1987. On equilibrium in Hart’s securities exchange model. Journal of Economic Theory 41, 392–404], is equivalent to the existence of a no arbitrage price system (NAPS) when no agent has non-null useless vectors. Allouch et al. [Allouch, N., Le Van, C., Page F.H., 2002. The geometry of arbitrage and the existence of competitive equilibrium. Journal of Mathematical Economics 38, 373–391] extend the NAPS introduced by Werner [Werner, J., 1987. Arbitrage and the existence of competitive equilib- rium. Econometrica 55, 1403–1418] and show that this condition is equivalent to the weak no market arbitrage (WNMA) of Hart [Hart, O., 1974. On the existence of an equilibrium in a securities model. Journal of Economic Theory 9, 293–311]. They mention that this result implies the one given by Page and Wooders [Page Jr., F.H., Wooders, M., 1996. A necessary and sufficient condition for compactness of individually rational and feasible outcomes and existence of an equilibrium. Economics Letters 52, 153–162]. In this note, we show that all these conditions are equivalent. © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction Allouch et al. (2002) consider the problem of existence of competitive equilibrium in an unbounded exchange economy. They extend the definition of no arbitrage price system (NAPS) introduced by Werner (1987) to the case where some agent in the economy has only useless vectors. They show that an extension of NAPS condition of Werner (1987) is actually equivalent to the weak no market arbitrage (WNMA) condition introduced by Hart (1974). They mention that this result implies one given by Page and Wooders (1996) who prove that no unbounded arbitrage (NUBA) condition, a special case of Page (1987), is equivalent to NAPS when no agent has non-null useless vectors. The proof of the claims consist of two parts. One is very easy (NAPS implies WNMA or NAPS implies NUBA). The converse part is more difficult. The purpose of this note is to show that when the statement NUBA implies NAPS (Page and Wooders, 1996) is true then we have WNMA implies NAPS (Allouch et al., 2002). But it is obvious that if the second statement holds then the first one also holds. The novelty of the result of this note is that the results are self-contained. While (Allouch et al., 2002) prove WNMA implies NAPS by using a difficult Lemma in Rockafellar (1970) and then deduce that NUBA implies NAPS when no agent has non-null useless vectors, we show that these conditions are actually circular. In some mathematical senses, these Corresponding author. Tel.: +33 5 6112 8516. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (M.-H. Nguyen), [email protected] (T. Ha-Huy). 0304-4068/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2009.05.003

Upload: manh-hung-nguyen

Post on 26-Jun-2016

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions; Equivalent conditions

Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2010) 128–131

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Mathematical Economics

journa l homepage: www.e lsev ier .com/ locate / jmateco

Short communication

No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrageprice system conditions; Equivalent conditions

Manh-Hung Nguyena,∗, Thai Ha-Huyb

a Toulouse School of Economics (LERNA-INRA), 21 allée de Brienne, 31000 Toulouse, Franceb University of Paris 1 (CES), 75013 Paris, France

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 1 March 2008Received in revised form 28 April 2009Accepted 20 May 2009Available online 11 June 2009

JEL classification:C62D50

Keywords:ArbitrageEquilibriumRecession cone

a b s t r a c t

Page and Wooders [Page Jr., F.H., Wooders, M., 1996. A necessary and sufficient conditionfor compactness of individually rational and feasible outcomes and existence of an equi-librium. Economics Letters 52, 153–162] prove that the no unbounded arbitrage (NUBA),a special case of a condition in Page [Page, F.H., 1987. On equilibrium in Hart’s securitiesexchange model. Journal of Economic Theory 41, 392–404], is equivalent to the existence ofa no arbitrage price system (NAPS) when no agent has non-null useless vectors. Allouch etal. [Allouch, N., Le Van, C., Page F.H., 2002. The geometry of arbitrage and the existence ofcompetitive equilibrium. Journal of Mathematical Economics 38, 373–391] extend the NAPSintroduced by Werner [Werner, J., 1987. Arbitrage and the existence of competitive equilib-rium. Econometrica 55, 1403–1418] and show that this condition is equivalent to the weakno market arbitrage (WNMA) of Hart [Hart, O., 1974. On the existence of an equilibrium ina securities model. Journal of Economic Theory 9, 293–311]. They mention that this resultimplies the one given by Page and Wooders [Page Jr., F.H., Wooders, M., 1996. A necessaryand sufficient condition for compactness of individually rational and feasible outcomes andexistence of an equilibrium. Economics Letters 52, 153–162]. In this note, we show that allthese conditions are equivalent.

© 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

Allouch et al. (2002) consider the problem of existence of competitive equilibrium in an unbounded exchange economy.They extend the definition of no arbitrage price system (NAPS) introduced by Werner (1987) to the case where some agent inthe economy has only useless vectors. They show that an extension of NAPS condition of Werner (1987) is actually equivalentto the weak no market arbitrage (WNMA) condition introduced by Hart (1974). They mention that this result implies onegiven by Page and Wooders (1996) who prove that no unbounded arbitrage (NUBA) condition, a special case of Page (1987),is equivalent to NAPS when no agent has non-null useless vectors. The proof of the claims consist of two parts. One is veryeasy (NAPS implies WNMA or NAPS implies NUBA). The converse part is more difficult.

The purpose of this note is to show that when the statement NUBA implies NAPS (Page and Wooders, 1996) is true thenwe have WNMA implies NAPS (Allouch et al., 2002). But it is obvious that if the second statement holds then the first onealso holds. The novelty of the result of this note is that the results are self-contained. While (Allouch et al., 2002) proveWNMA implies NAPS by using a difficult Lemma in Rockafellar (1970) and then deduce that NUBA implies NAPS when noagent has non-null useless vectors, we show that these conditions are actually circular. In some mathematical senses, these

∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +33 5 6112 8516.E-mail addresses: [email protected] (M.-H. Nguyen), [email protected] (T. Ha-Huy).

0304-4068/$ – see front matter © 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.doi:10.1016/j.jmateco.2009.05.003

Page 2: No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions; Equivalent conditions

M.-H. Nguyen, T. Ha-Huy / Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2010) 128–131 129

conditions let us to think of the circular tours of Brouwer and Kakutani fixed-point theorems. Moreover, proofs are simpleand elementary.

We consider an unbounded exchange economy E with m agents indexed by i = 1, . . . , m. For each agent there is anendowment ei ∈Rl , a closed convex non-empty consumption set Xi ⊂ Rl and a upper semi-continuous, quasi-concave utilityfunction ui from Xi to R.

For a subset X ⊂ Rl , int X denotes the interior of X, X0 denotes the polar of X where X0 = {p ∈Rl|p · x ≤ 0, ∀x ∈ X} andX00 = (X0)

0. If X is closed, convex and contains the origin then X00 = X .

For x ∈ Xi, agent i′s weak preferred set at x is

Pi(x) = {y ∈ Xi|ui(y) ≥ ui(x)}.

Let Ri(x) be recession cone of Pi(x) (see Rockaffellar, 1970). The set Ri(x) is called the set of useful vectors for ui is given as

Ri(x) = {w ∈Rl|ui(x + �w) ≥ ui(x), for all � ≥ 0}.

It is easy to check that Ri(x) is a closed convex cone.The linearity space of Pi(x) is defined by

Li(x) = {w ∈Rl|ui(x + �w) = ui(x), for all � ∈R} = Ri(x) ∩ −Ri(x).

Elements in Li(x) will be called useless vectors at x. Note that Ri(x) and Li(x) do not depend on x, let us set Ri = Ri(ei), Li = Li(ei).Denote L⊥

iis the orthogonal space of Li.

Let us first recall the no-unbounded-arbitrage condition denoted now on by NUBA introduced by Page (1987) and Pageand Wooders (1996) which requires non-existence of an unbounded set of mutually compatible net trades that are utilitynon-decreasing.

Definition 1. The economy satisfies the NUBA condition if∑m

i=1wi = 0 and wi ∈ Ri for all i implies wi = 0 for all i.

There exists a weaker condition, called the weak-no-market-arbitrage condition (WNMA), introduced by Hart (1974). Thiscondition requires that all mutually compatible net trades which are utility non-decreasing be useless.

Definition 2. The economy satisfies the WNMA condition if∑m

i=1wi = 0 and wi ∈ Ri for all i implies wi ∈ Li for all i.

If Li = {0}, ∀i, then WNMA is equivalent to NUBA.We shall use the concepts of no-arbitrage-price system condition (NAPS) of Allouch et al. (2002). Define the notion of

no-arbitrage price:

Definition 3. Si ={

{p ∈ L⊥i

|p · w > 0, ∀w ∈ (Ri ∩ L⊥i

)\{0} if Ri\Li /= ∅}L⊥

iif Ri = Li

}.

Observe that, when Li = {0}, then we can write

Si = {p ∈Rl|p · w > 0, ∀w ∈ Ri \ {0}}.

Definition 4. The economy E satisfies the NAPS condition if ∩iSi /= ∅.

2. The equivalent conditions

As we mentioned above, the proofs of the implications NAPS ⇒ NUBA and NAPS ⇒ WNMA are easy. We now giveelementary proofs for NUBA ⇒ NAPS and WNMA ⇒NAPS.

The following lemma is useful in our proof.

Lemma 1. WNMA ⇒ ∑i(Ri ∩ L⊥

i) is closed. In particular, if Li = {0} for all i, then NUBA ⇒ ∑

iRi is closed.

Proof. Assume that there exists a sequence∑

iwin → w, with wi

n ∈ Ri ∩ L⊥i

for all i and n. We shall prove that the sum∑

i||win||

is bounded, and then the vector w is in∑

i(Ri ∩ L⊥i

). Suppose that

limn→+∞

∑i

||win|| = +∞.

Page 3: No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions; Equivalent conditions

130 M.-H. Nguyen, T. Ha-Huy / Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2010) 128–131

Then we have

limn→+∞

m∑i=1

win∑

i

||win||

= 0,

limn→+∞

m∑i=1

||win||∑

i

||win||

= 1.

Therefore we can suppose that (win/

∑i||wi

n||) → wi when n → +∞. Note that since Ri is a closed convex cone, we have wi ∈ Ri

and∑

iwi = 0,

∑i||wi|| = 1. But WNMA implies that when wi ∈ Li, we also have wi ∈ L⊥

i. Hence, for all i, wi = 0 that leads to

a contradiction. �

The following result has been proven by Page and Wooders (1996) where they used Dubovitskii and Milyutin (1965)Theorem. We give here an elementary proof to make the note self-contained.

Proposition 1. Assume Li = {0}, ∀ i. Then NUBA ⇒ NAPS.

Proof. Since Li = {0}, it holds that Si /= ∅∀ i. Assume now that ∩iSi = ∅. Then ∩iSi is contained in a linear subspace H ⊂ Rl

since int ∩iSi = int ∩iSi = ∅.

It follows from Si = −(Ri)0 that ∩iS

i = −(∑

iRi)0 ⊂ H.

This implies

H⊥ ⊂ (∑

i

Ri)00

.

The sum∑

iRi is closed by Lemma 1, hence∑

iRi = (∑

iRi)00 since it is closed convex set and contains the origin. Hence,

H⊥ ⊂∑

iRi and∑

iRi contains a line.Thus there exist r ∈ H⊥, r /= 0, −r ∈ H⊥ and (r1, . . . , rm) /= 0, ri ∈ Ri such that

r =m∑

i=1

ri

Since −r ∈∑

iRi, there exist (r′1, . . . , r′m) /= 0, r′i ∈ Ri such that

∑i

r′i = −r.

Therefore∑

i(ri + r′i) = 0 and ri + r′i ∈ Ri since Ri is the convex cone. By the NUBA condition, we have ri = −r′i. This means

that, for some i, Ri contains a line and Si = ∅: a contradiction. �

Allouch et al. (2002) prove the equivalence of NAPS and WNMA by using a lemma which is based on the concept of asupport function (Corollary 16.2.2 in Rockafellar, 1970). From Proposition 1, we get the following proposition, the proof ofwhich is elementary.

Proposition 2. WNMA ⇒ ∩iSi /= ∅.

Proof. Consider a new economy E = (Xi, ui, ei) defined by

Xi = Xi ∩ L⊥i

, ui = ui|Xi, ei = (ei)

Ri = Ri ∩ L⊥i

We have Li = (Ri ∩ L⊥i

) ∩ −(Ri ∩ L⊥i

) = {0}. Hence, in the economy E, WNMA is NUBA. Proposition 1 implies that ∩iSi /= ∅where

Si = {p ∈Rl|p · w > 0, ∀w ∈ (Ri ∩ L⊥i ) \ {0}}.

It is easy to see that Si = Si + Li. Thus, if (∩iSi) ∩ (∩iL⊥i

) /= ∅, then ∩iSi /= ∅.We will show that (∩iSi) ∩ (∩iL

⊥i

) /= ∅. On the contrary, suppose that (∩iSi) ∩ (∩iL⊥i

) = ∅. By using a separation theorem(see, e.g., Theorem 11.3, Rockafellar, 1970), note that ∩iSi is open and ∩iL

⊥i

is a subspace, there exists a vector w /= 0 such that:

w · p > 0 = w · l, ∀p ∈ ∩iSi, ∀l ∈ ∩iL⊥i .

Page 4: No unbounded arbitrage, weak no market arbitrage and no arbitrage price system conditions; Equivalent conditions

M.-H. Nguyen, T. Ha-Huy / Journal of Mathematical Economics 46 (2010) 128–131 131

Therefore, we get

w ∈m∑

i=1

Li.

Moreover, we have

w · p ≥ 0 ∀p ∈ ∩iSi.

Since for every i, Si is open, and ∩iSi /= ∅we have ∩iSi = ∩i¯Si. From Lemma 1,

∑iRi is closed. We then have:

w ∈ − (∩iSi)0

= (∑

i

Ri)00

=∑

i

Ri

Therefore, for each i, there exists li ∈ Li, wi ∈ Ri such that w =∑

ili =∑

iwi, in other words,

∑i(li − wi) = 0. The WNMA

implies that li − wi ∈ Li. Since Ri = Ri ∩ L⊥i

, it implies that wi ∈ Li and wi ∈ L⊥i

. Thus wi = 0 for all i and w = 0: we obtain acontradiction. The proof is complete. �

The following result is trivial:

Proposition 3. If Proposition 2 holds then Proposition 1 holds.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Cuong Le Van and an anonymous referee for their valuable suggestions.

References

Allouch, N., Le Van, C., Page, F.H., 2002. The geometry of arbitrage and the existence of competitive equilibrium. Journal of Mathematical Economics 38,373–391.

Dubovitskii, A., Milyutin, A.A., 1965. Extremum problems in the presence of restrictions. USSR Computational Mathematics and Mathematical Statistics 5,1.

Hart, O., 1974. On the existence of an equilibrium in a securities model. Journal of Economic Theory 9, 293–311.Page Jr., F.H., Wooders, M., 1996. A necessary and sufficient condition for compactness of individually rational and feasible outcomes and existence of an

equilibrium. Economics Letters 52, 153–162.Page, F.H., 1987. On equilibrium in Hart’s securities exchange model. Journal of Economic Theory 41, 392–404.Rockafellar, R.T., 1970. Convex Analysis. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Werner, J., 1987. Arbitrage and the existence of competitive equilibrium. Econometrica 55, 1403–1418.