phd course: structural var models iii. identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/lecture 3 - svar...

27
PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland Norwegian School of Management (BI)

Upload: trannhan

Post on 17-May-2018

235 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

PhD Course: Structural VAR models

III. Identification

Hilde C. Bjørnland

Norwegian School of Management (BI)

Page 2: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Lecture note III: Identification Content

1. Identification (cont.)

Choleski recursive restrictions and implication on the covariance matrix 2. Criticism of the recursive restrictions

3. Non-recursive restrictions on the contemporaneous matrix

4. Long run restrictions

Criticism of long run restrictions

Page 3: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

1. Identification (cont.) Recall the structural VAR

ttttt

ttttt

yyyyyyyy

21222112121212

11212111112121

εφφαψεφφαψ

+++=++++=+

−−

−−,

written in matrix notation as

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

t

t

t

t

t

t

yy

yy

2

1

12

11

2221

1211

2

1

2

1

21

12

11

εε

φφφφ

αα

ψψ

.

ttt yy εα +Φ+=Ψ −1 ,

where or, ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛22

21

2

1

0

0,

00

iid~ω

ωεε

t

t ( )Ω,0~tε .

Page 4: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

The structural moving average (SMA) representation was found as

tj

jtjt Lvvy εε )(0

Θ+=Θ+= ∑∞

=−

Where ...)()( 1

21

111 +Ψ+Ψ+Ψ=Ψ=Θ −−−− BBLBL

(Recall from lecture II, SVAR→ reduced form →SMA:

and ).

ttj

jtt LLBBey ενενν )()( 1

0

Θ+=Ψ+=+= −∞

=−∑

tte ε1−Ψ= Suppose that ε2t has no contemporaneous impact on y1t, that is θ12,0=0 in the SMA above

...0

12

11

1,221,21

1,121,11

2

1

0,220,21

0,11

2

1

2

1 +⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

t

t

t

t

t

t

vv

yy

εε

θθθθ

εε

θθθ

which is equivalent to

Page 5: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

= . 10

−Ψ=Θ ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

0,220,21

0,11 0θθ

θ

The equivalent restriction in the SVAR can be found from

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

−−

=⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

−Ψ

=Ψ−

11

11

11

)det(1

21

12

211221

121

ψψ

ψψψψ

,

or

012 =ψ

Page 6: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Example: Assume a reduced form bivariate VAR(1) consisting of the variables, interest rate (it) and output growth (Δxt) that is driven by the two structural shocks, monetary policy shocks )( ,tMPε and productivity shocks )( ,tPRε ,

and assuming zero mean. Let now output growth be ordered above the interest rate in the yt vector. The restriction θ12,0=0 implies that output growth does not respond contemporaneously to monetary policy shocks, as there is a lag (quarter or month, depending on sample frequencies) in the implementation of monetary policy shocks. By estimating the reduced form VAR

ttt eyAy += −11

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡Δ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡Δ

t

t

t

t

t

t

ee

ix

aaaa

ix

,2

,1

1

1

2221

1211,

we get the reduced form (infinite) moving average (MA) representation by multiplying with the finite order polynomial A(L)-1

Page 7: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

tttt eLBeLAIeLAy )()()( 11

1 =−== −− , where . j

j ABIB 10 , == Assuming no contemporaneous effect of monetary policy shocks on output growth (equivalent to assuming

012 =ψ ), or in terms of the structural VAR

tMPtttt

tPRttt

xixi

ixx

,122112212

,1121111

εφφψα

εφφα

+Δ++Δ−=

++Δ+=Δ

−−

−−

.

Using the SMA, the zero short run restriction can be found by assuming Ψ is lower triangular, so that

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=Ψ

101

21ψ .

From

Page 8: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

tte ε=Ψ , or in terms of matrix notation,

,1

01

,

,

2

1

21⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

tMP

tPR

t

t

ee

εε

ψ

we obtain

ttPRtttMP

ttPR

eee

e

2,212,121,

1,

+=+=

=

εψψε

ε

Hence, in this case, the restriction implies a causal ordering that can be identified using the Choleski decomposition. The system is now just identified and 21ψ can be uniquely identified from the elements of the reduced form covariance matrix Σ.

Page 9: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

As and denoting the CVM of the bivariate VAR above as tte ε1−Ψ= =Σ=)'( tteeE⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡2212

1221

σσ

σσ

Σ=ΩΨΨ= −− ')'( 11

tteeE

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

+−

−=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡ −

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

=⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡21

221

22

2121

2121

2121

22

21

212212

1221

101

0

0101

ωψωωψ

ωψωψ

ω

ωψσσ

σσ

Solving this, we get,

21

21 ωσ = , and 2

12112 ωψσ −= 21

221

22

22 ωψωσ +=

hence,

21

1221 σ

σψ

−=

We can identify the parameter from the covariance between the two variables in the VAR. If the covariance is zero, the coefficient will also be zero, hence there will be no contemporaneous relationship.

Page 10: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

2. Criticisms of recursive restrictions Cooley and LeRoy (1985) criticized the VAR methodology because of its “atheoretical” identification scheme. They argued that Sims did not explicitly justify the identification restrictions and claimed that a model identified by this arbitrary procedure cannot be interpreted as a structural model, because a different variable ordering yields different structural parameters. In the example above, the restriction θ12,0=0 implies that output growth does not respond contemporaneously to monetary policy shocks, as there is a lag in the implementation of monetary policy shocks. Alternatively, had the interest rate been ordered above output growth, the restriction would have implied that monetary policy, (i.e. the central bank) does not react contemporaneously to technology shocks, (hence they observe productivity changes with a lag). Both are plausible assumptions. Which should you choose?

Page 11: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Difficult to test, as rearranging the order of variables (as suggested originally by Sims) may not allow you to uncover the “true” structural relations, as you always assume one of the contemporaneous relationship to be zero. If there is a degree of simultaneity between two variables, is it measurable? In the example from Bjørnland (2006), (see Lecture notes II), where the interdependence between monetary policy and the exchange rate was analyzed, the two different Choleski orderings gave responses close to zero (for all countries but Canada). Hence, we would expect the covariance between the two variables of interest to be zero. However, a covariance of zero may NOT imply that the ordering does not matter, as illustrated below.

Page 12: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Figure 1. Response in the exchange rate to a 1 pp. monetary policy shock; two different Choleski orderings a) Australia b) Canada c) New Zealand

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Real exchange rateReal exchange rate (exc-i)

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Real exchange rateReal exchange rate (exc-i)

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Real exchange rateReal exchange rate (exc-i)

d) Sweden e) UK

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Real exchange rateReal exchange rate (exc-i)

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

Real exchange rate Real exchange rate (exc-i)

1) Source Bjørnland (2006) The solid line corresponds to the Choleski decomposition where the interest rate is ordered before the exchange rate in the VAR. In the alternative ordering (exc-i), the interest rate and the exchange rate swap places. An increase in the exchange rate implies depreciation.

Page 13: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

In particular, assume for simplicity a system in two variables, the interest rate and the exchange rate. The reduced form residuals, will be linear relationship of the structural shocks, that is, a structural monetary policy shock and an exchange rate shock,

texctmptexc

texctmpti

e

e

,,,

,,,

εβε

αεε

+=

+=

[ ] 22,,,,,, ))((),cov( excmptexctmptexctmptexcti Eee βωαωεβεαεε +=++=

A covariance close to zero implies either that the true structural relationship is zero,

00),cov( ,, ==→= βαtexcti ee

or that the effects are equal, but opposite in signs!

αωω

β 2

2

exc

mp−=

Page 14: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Only by allowing the parameters to be freely estimated, can we test if the “orderings matter”. Need to use other identifying restrictions, short run or long run. As an alternative to the recursive identification scheme, Bernanke (1986) and Blanchard and Watson (1986) among others introduced non-recursive restrictions on the contemporaneous interactions among variables for identification. As economic theory often does not provide enough meaningful contemporaneous restrictions (and the more variables you put into your system, the more restrictions you need), the search for additional identifying restrictions led Blanchard and Quah (1989) and subsequently Shapiro and Watson (1988) and Galí (1992) to introduce restrictions on the system’s long run properties. These long run restrictions are usually based on neutrality postulates. More recently, imposing sign restrictions, allows you to test the implications of all types of restrictions. By dropping one after one of the “dubious restrictions”, one can test whether the responses to shocks are sensitive to the restrictions often imposed.

Page 15: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

3. Alternative non-recursive restrictions Eventhough the structural model cannot be written in lower triangular from, we can still give a structural

interpretation to the VAR exploring the relationships , i.e. tte ε1−Ψ= '11 −− ΩΨΨ=Σ .

As an alternative to the recursive identification scheme, one could introduce non-recursive restrictions on the contemporaneous interactions among variables for identification. For an open economy application related to the discussion on the exchange rate, Kim and Roubini (2000) adopt identification schemes that do not employ the recursiveness assumption. Rather than assuming the recursive assumption between interest rates and the exchange rate (Eichenbaum and Evans, 1995), they suggested that one should allow for a contemporaneous interaction between monetary policy and the exchange rate. Instead they assume that the monetary policymaker can not respond contemporaneously to the foreign interest rate. They observe fewer puzzles in the exchange rates than other studies. However, still not an assumption allowing for simultaneous response between the interest rate differential and the exchange rate.

Page 16: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Figure 2. Response in the exchange rate to a 1 pp. monetary policy shock; Choleski versus non-recursive restrictions between the interest rate and the exchange rate (assuming instead that the monetary policymaker can not respond contemporaneously to the foreign interest rate)

-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24

CholeskyCholesky (reverse order)Kim and Roubini

Source Bjørnland (2005)

Page 17: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

4. Long run restriction Following Blanchard and Quah (1989), SVAR can also be identified using “long run restrictions”. These are restrictions on sums of coefficients in )(Lθ and not only on the contemporaneous effect in 0θ only.

These restrictions usually follows from some economic theory, and are therefore considered as being more sophisticated than the “delayed reaction” theory underlying most zero restrictions on 0θ . Long run

restrictions are often with regard to neutrality of the effects of certain shocks over time. Blanchard and Quah (henceforth BQ) imposed restrictions on the long-term multipliers of a model (including the growth of output and unemployment) to identify a permanent and transitory components of output. They then postulated that the variables were driven by two orthogonal structural shocks (“supply” and “demand”), and argue that a demand shock should have no permanent effect on the level of output, whereas a supply shock could. The unemployment rate was considered stationary; hence no shocks could change unemployment permanently.

Page 18: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Based on the identification, GDP could potentially be split into two different components; a component determined by shocks that have a permanent effect on the supply side of the economy, and a component determined by shocks that only affect demand in the short term. The first component represents potential GDP and will consist of the accumulated supply shocks, while the latter can be interpreted as the output gap and will consist of the accumulated demand shocks. Example: The (bivariate) SMA representation

∑∞

=−Θ+=

0jjtjt vy ε , where ( )Ω,0~tε

...12

11

1,221,21

1,121,11

2

1

0,220,21

0,120,11

2

1

2

1 +⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

t

t

t

t

t

t

vv

yy

εε

θθθθ

εε

θθθθ

Suppose ε2t has no long run cumulative impact on y1t, then we could write,

Page 19: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

0)1(0

,1112 ∑∞

=

==s

sθθ (1)

So that

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=

⎥⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢⎢

∑∑

∑∞

=

=

=

)1()1(0)1(

0)1(

2221

11

0,22

0,21

0,11

θθθ

θθ

θ

ss

ss

ss

This turns out to be a non-linear restriction on the coefficient of the SVAR

111111

111 )()()1()1()1( −−−−−−−− ΨΦΨ−=Ψ−=Ψ=Ψ=Θ IAIAB (2)

Page 20: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

An interesting case Assume the MA representation from the reduced form VAR (ignore constant)

tt eLBy )(=

Again we assume the relationship between the reduced form VAR and the SVAR, , and

. Let the structural shocks ε

tte ε1−Ψ=

)()( 1 LLB Θ=Ψ−t‘s be normalized so they all have unit variance ( )I,0~tε .

From the normalisation of var(εt) it follows that '' 1111 −−−− ΨΨ=ΩΨΨ=Σ . If you order the variables so that

the long run matrix turns out to be lower triangular, we can use this to recover )1(Θ 1−Ψ . In particular,

combining the expression for Σ and the long run representation implies

)'1()1()'1()1(

)'1()1()')1(()1(

)1()1(

11

1

ΘΘ=Σ

ΘΘ=ΨΨ

Θ=Ψ

−−

BB

BB

B

(3)

Page 21: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

(3) can be computed from the estimate of Σ and B(1)(=A(1)-1). As )1(Θ is lower triangular, expression (3)

implies that )1(Θ will be the unique lower triangular Choleski factor of )'1()1( BB Σ . Example 1: The original paper with LR restrictions Blanchard and Quah (1989) Estimate a model in GDP growth and unemployment. Assume aggregate demand shocks can have no long run effect on the level of output. Equivalent to assuming the sum of the differences will eventually be zero

tAD

AS

tuy

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡Δ

ε

εθθ

θ)1()1(

0)1(

2221

11

The important issue is to include a variable that is stationary (i.e. do not need to impose any restrictions) and has dynamic interactions with GDP. More recent papers have tended to use Δp in the vector instead of u. However, results are not robust to the inclusion of another variable, as illustrated by Faust and Leeper (1997).

Page 22: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Example 2: Evaluating different output gaps (using alternative methods) for forecasting inflation Bjørnland, Brubakk and Jore (2005) Augment BQ by estimating a three variable VAR (unemployment growth, GDP growth and inflation). Identify three shocks; Nominal and real demand shocks and one supply shock. Assume nominal demand shock can have no long run effect on GDP nor unemployment, whereas the real demand shock could potentially affect GDP in the long run, but not unemployment. No restrictions on inflation that is stationary.

t

ND

RD

AS

tpyu

⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎡=

⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

ΔΔΔ

ε

ε

ε

θθθθθ

θ

)1()1()1(0)1()1(00)1(

333231

2221

11

Output gap will be the accumulated nominal demand (monetary policy) shocks that can be found as

∑∞

=−− =+++=Δ

0jj13,212,13111,1310,13 0where..., θεθεθεθ tttty

so that the sum of coefficients will be zero (what’s going up has to go down). However, we also allow for short run contribution form real demand shock, by adding the 8-th step forecast error to the output gap. Movement after that will contribute to trend movement.

Page 23: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Figure 3a Impulse responses for GDP Figure 3b Accumulated demand shocks, (historical

decomposition)

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1 5 9 13 17 21 25 29 33 37 41 45

ASRDND

-5-4-3-2-1012345

78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04-5-4-3-2-1012345

Chart A.6 Structural vector autoregressive method (SVAR). Output gap. Percentage of potential GDP.

Source: Bjørnland, Brubakk and Jore (2005).

Page 24: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Example 3: Core inflation Quah and Vahey (1995) Core inflation is defined as the component in inflation that has no long run effect on output. Compute core inflation through historical decompositions, (as in the example with output gap) i.e.

tCORE

NC

tpy

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡=⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡ΔΔ

ε

εθθ

θ)1()1(

0)1(

2221

11

Provides the Central Bank with a concept of core inflation that is more “economically founded”. Note that place no restrictions on inflation, hence can test for overidentifying restrictions (do the impulse responses look reasonable?) What is non-core? VAR a means to obtain an estimate of core inflation.

Page 25: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Criticism of long run restrictions Faust and Leeper (1997) have criticised the use of long run restrictions to identify structural shocks, and show that unless the economy satisfies some types of strong restrictions, the long run restrictions will be unreliable. They argue that for a long-run identifying restriction to be robust, it has to be tied to restriction of finite horizon dynamics. Substantial distortions are possible due to small sample bias and measurement errors. The aggregation of shocks in small models should be checked for consistency using alternative models.

Page 26: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

References Bernanke, B. (1986). “Alternative Explanations of the Money-Income Correlation”, Carnegie Rochester Conference in Public Policy, 25, 49-100. Bjørnland, H.C. (2005), “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Interactions in a Small Open Economy,” Working Paper 2005/16, Norges Bank. Bjørnland, H.C. (2006), “Monetary policy and exchange rate overshooting: Dornbusch was right after all”, Manuscript, University of Oslo. Bjørnland, H.C. Brubakk, L. and A.S. Jore (2006), “Forecasting inflation with an uncertain output gap” Working Paper 2005/16, Norges Bank. Blanchard, O. J. and M.W.Watson (1986). “Are Business Cycles All Alike?” in R. Gordon, ed., The American Business Cycle - Continuity and Change, NBER Studies in Business Cycles, Vol. 25, Chicago, University of Chicago Press. Blanchard, O. J. and D. Quah (1989). “The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances”, The American Economic Review, 79, 655-673.

Page 27: PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identificationhome.bi.no/a0310125/Lecture 3 - SVAR identification.pdf · PhD Course: Structural VAR models III. Identification Hilde C. Bjørnland

Cooley, T. F. and S. F. Leroy (1985). “Atheoretical Macroeconometrics. A Critique.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 16 , 283-308. Eichenbaum, M. and C. Evans (1995), “Some empirical evidence on the effects of shocks to monetary policy on exchange rates,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 975-1010. Faust, Jon and Eric M. Leeper (1997) “When Do Long-Run Identifying Restrictions Give Reliable Results?” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. 345 ? 353. Gali, J. (1992) “How Well Does the ISLM Model Fit Postwar U.S. Data?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 709-38. Gali J. (1999), “Technology, employment, and the business cycle: do technology shocks explain aggregate fluctuations?”, American Economic Review, Vol 89, p 249-271. Kim, S. and N. Roubini (2000), “Exchange rate anomalies in the industrial countries: A solution with a structural VAR approach”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 45, 561-586. Quah, D.T and S.P. Vahey (1995) “Measuring Core Inflation?”, Economic Journal, 105, 1130–1144. Shapiro, M.D. and M.W. Watson (1988). “Sources of Business Cycle Fluctuations”, in S. Fischer (ed.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1988. The MIT Press, Cambridge (Mass.) and London.