presentation 9-21-10

Upload: paul-seever

Post on 10-Apr-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    1/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    2/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    3/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    4/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    5/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    6/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    7/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    8/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    9/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    10/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    11/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    12/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    13/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    14/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    15/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    16/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    17/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    18/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    19/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    20/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    21/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    22/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    23/43

    Luxembourg Income StudyWorking Paper Series

    Luxembourg Income Study (LIS), asbl

    Working Paper No. 517

    Public Policies and the Middle Classthroughout the World in the Mid 2000s

    Steven Pressman

    July 2009

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    24/43

    20

    times of unemployment, we would expect to see declines in the number of hours worked

    and the number of weeks worked full-time during the year. As a result, the middle class

    should shrink. Unfortunately, such labor market variables are rare in the LIS, and only

    Finland and the US have relevant data in Wave #6 to perform such an analysis.

    My shift-share analysis for Finland found no change in the size of the Finnish

    middle class as a result of changes in either weeks worked part-time or full-time, or due

    to weeks unemployed by either the household head or spouse. For the US, there was also

    virtually no change due to hours worked per week, or due to weeks employed full-time or

    part-time by either the household head or spouse. In all cases, the results were so small

    (.1 percentage point or zero) and could have been due to rounding. Only for weeks

    employed full-time by household heads in the US did this labor market change push up

    the size of the middle class by .2 percentage points. But this is still not a large change in

    the middle class stemming from labor market changes. (These results are available from

    the author upon request.)

    7. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

    This study has used the LIS to examine the size of the middle class across nations and

    over time. Its main conclusions support the arguments made in Pressman (2007). A main

    finding is that in the mid 2000s the size of a countrys middle class depends to a large

    extent on the government tax and spending policy. The size of the national middle class is

    pretty much the same looking at either factor income or market income, and it is also

    relatively low (less than 20 percent) in all developed countries. Only with generous

    government transfers and progressive taxes does the middle class grow to close to half

    the nations households. This paper expands on my earlier work by identifying the

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    25/43

    TABLE # 3

    MIDDLE-CLASS (as a percentage of all households) UNDER ALTERNATIVE DEFINITIONS

    OF MIDDLE CLASS

    COUNTRY MAIN D2 D3 D4

    Australia 29,1% 39,7% 48,2% 53,9%

    Canada 34,9% 46,4% 54,0% 59,0%

    Denmark 48,7% 62,8% 70,6% 74,1%

    Finland 43,5% 56,4% 64,0% 68,4%

    Luxembourg 41,7% 53,9% 61,1% 64,9%

    Mexico 24,7% 32,1% 38,5% 42,6%

    Norway 46,5% 60,9% 67,8% 70,9%

    Sweden 48,5% 62,9% 91,9% 95,2%

    Taiwan 36,2% 46,8% 53,8% 58,6%

    UK 33,8% 45,5% 52,6% 57,6%

    US 28,7% 39,0% 46,5% 51,8%

    Averages

    (unweighted)37,8% 49,7% 59,0% 63,4%

    Source: Author's calculations from the Luxembourg Income Study

    Note: Main definition is median adjusted household income (median) 25%median; D2 = 75% median>medianmedianmedian

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    26/43

    TABLE#2

    MIDDLECLASSHOUSEHOLDS(ASAPERCENTAGEOFALLH

    COUNTRY

    MiddleClass

    Households

    withChildren

    MiddleClass

    Households

    withChildren

    (SubtractingChild

    Allowances)

    MiddleClass

    Householdswith

    Children

    (Subtracting

    AlimonyandChild

    Support)

    MiddleClass

    Householdswith

    Children

    (SubstractingFamily

    Leave)

    AUSTRALIA 39,4% 34,2% 38,6% 36,9%

    CANADA 38,5% 36,4% 37,7% 38,5%

    DENMARK 60,0% 56,5% 57,8% 58,2%

    FINLAND 53,1% 48,6% 52,6% 50,3%LUXEMBOURG 42,0% 32,2% N.A. 42,0%

    NORWAY 59,1% 52,7% 59,0% 53,8%

    SWEDEN 58,2% 53,3% 55,2% 52,8%

    UK 37,6% 35,5% 37,0% 37,5%

    US 32,0% 32,0% 31,6% 32,0%

    AVERAGES

    (unweighted) 46,7% 42,4% 46,2% 44,7%

    Source: Author'scalculationsfromtheLuxembourgIncomeStudy

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    27/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    28/43

    Understanding Mobility in America

    Understanding Mobility

    in America

    Tom Hertz, American University

    ProgressiveIdeasfo

    raStrong,

    Just,andFreeA

    merica

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    29/43

    Understanding Mobility in America

    SummaryThis report discusses two aspects ofeconomic mobility in the United States. The rst is the

    question ofintergenerational mobility, or the degree to which the economic success of children is

    independent of the economic status of their parents. A higher level of intergenerational mobility is

    often interpreted as a sign of greater fairness, orequality of opportunity, in a society.

    The second aspect is the short-term question of the amount by which family incomes change from

    year to year. By studyingshort-term mobility we can determine whether incomes are rising or

    falling for families at different points in the income distribution. We can also determine whether

    the size of these income variations, or the level ofannual income volatility, is changing over time.

    Increased volatility is undesirable to the extent that it represents an increase in economic insecurity.

    The key ndings relating to intergenerational mobility include the following:

    Children from low-income families have only a 1 percent chance of reaching the top

    5 percent of the income distribution, versus children of the rich who have about a 22

    percent chance.

    Children born to the middle quintile of parental family income ($42,000 to $54,300)

    had about the same chance of ending up in a lower quintile than their parents (39.5

    percent) as they did of moving to a higher quintile (36.5 percent). Their chances of

    attaining the top ve percentiles of the income distribution were just 1.8 percent.

    Education, race, health and state of residence are four key channels by which

    economic status is transmitted from parent to child.

    African American children who are born in the bottom quartile are nearly twice as

    likely to remain there as adults than are white children whose parents had identicalincomes, and are four times less likely to attain the top quartile.

    The difference in mobility for blacks and whites persists even after controlling for

    a host of parental background factors, childrens education and health, as well as

    whether the household was female-headed or receiving public assistance.

    After controlling for a host of parental background variables, upward mobility varied

    by region of origin, and is highest (in percentage terms) for those who grew up in the

    South Atlantic and East South Central regions, and lowest for those raised in the West

    South Central and Mountain regions.

    By international standards, the United States has an unusually low level of

    intergenerational mobility: our parents income is highly predictive of our incomes

    as adults. Intergenerational mobility in the United States is lower than in France,

    Germany, Sweden, Canada, Finland, Norway and Denmark. Among high-income

    countries for which comparable estimates are available, only the United Kingdom

    had a lower rate of mobility than the United States.

    i

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    30/43

    2 Understanding Mobility in America

    The second kind of mobility we will study is the amount by which family incomes change from

    year to year. By studyingshort-term mobility we can determine whether incomes are rising or

    falling for families at different points in the income distribution. We can also determine whether

    the size of these income variations, or the level ofannual income volatility, is changing over time.

    Increased volatility is undesirable to the extent that it represents an increase in economic insecurity.

    In particular, we will show that the frequency of large negative income shocks has risen markedly

    since the early 1990s. This analysis conrms the ndings of Hacker (forthcoming), but uses a muchlarger and nationally representative dataset, allowing for a more detailed and precise analysis of the

    size and direction of annual income changes at different points in the income distribution. Using the

    annual data we are also able to test for a relation between labor market effort and upward mobility.

    Intergenerational mobility in the United States

    While few would deny that it ispossible to start poor and end rich, the evidence suggests that this

    feat is more difcult to accomplish in the United States than in other high-income nations. This

    claim is based on cross-country comparisons of the intergenerational elasticity of earnings, a

    statistic that measures the percentage difference in expected child earnings that is associated witha one percent difference in parental earnings. Higher elasticities mean less mobility: they imply

    that parental income matters more, or that the children of the poor are more likely to remain poor.1

    Figure 2, below, displays the intergenerational elasticity of earnings between fathers and sons

    for nine upper-income countries, and shows that the United States and the United Kingdom are

    especially immobile.

    Figure 2: International

    Estimates of the Father-Son Earnings Elasticity

    The elasticity is closely related to the intergenerational correlation coefcient, the difference being that the correlatio

    scales the elasticity to take account of any changes over time in the level of inequality.

    Source: Corak (2004)Source: Corak (2004)

    United Kingdom

    United States

    France

    Germany

    Sweden

    Canada

    Finland

    Norway

    Denmark

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6

    0.15

    0.17

    0.18

    0.19

    0.27

    0.32

    0.41

    0.47

    0.5

    Figure 2: International Estimates of theFather-Son Earnings Elasticity

    Source: Corak (2004)

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    31/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    32/43

    The Polarization of Job Opportunities

    in the U.S. Labor MarketImplications for Employment and Earnings

    David Autor, MIT Department of Economics and National Bureau of Economic Research

    April 2010

    istockphoto/mrloz

    istockphoto/pastoor

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    33/43

    he amilton roject | www.hamiltonproject.org 1

    Introduction and summary

    Between December 2007, when the U.S. housing andfinancial crises became the subject of daily news headlines,

    and March of 2010, the latest period for which data are

    available, the number of employed workers in the United

    States fell by 8.2 million, to 129.8 million from 138.0 mil-

    lion. In the same interval, the civilian unemployment rate

    nearly doubled, to 9.7 percent from 5.0 percent, while the

    employment-to-population ratio dropped to 58.6 percent

    from 62.7 percentthe lowest level seen in more than 25

    years. Job losses of this magnitude cause enormous harm

    to workers, families, and communities.1

    A classic study by economists Lou Jacobson, Robert LaLonde,

    and Daniel Sullivan found that workers involuntary displaced

    by plant downsizings in Pennsylvania during the severe reces-

    sion of the early 1980s suered annual earnings losses averag-

    ing 25 percent, even six years following displacement.2 Te

    nonpecuniary consequences of job losses due to the Great

    Recession may be just as severe. Studying the same group of

    workers with the benet of 15 more years of data, labor econ-

    omists Daniel Sullivan and co-author ill Von Wachter3 show

    that involuntarily job displacement approximately doubled

    the short-term mortality rates of those displaced and reduced

    their life expectancy on average by one to one and a half years.

    Tus, long aer the U.S. unemployment rate recedes into sin-

    gle digits, the costs of the Great Recession will endure.

    Despite the extremely adverse U.S. employment situation in

    2010, history suggests that employment will eventually return

    and unemployment will eventually subside. But the key chal-

    lenges facing the U.S. labor marketalmost all of which wereevident prior to the Great Recessionwill surely endure.

    Tese challenges are two-fold. Te rst is that for some decades

    now, the U.S. labor market has experienced increased demand

    for skilled workers. During times like the 1950s and 1960s, a

    rising level of educational aainment kept up with this rising

    demand for skill. But since the late 1970s and early 1980s, the

    rise in U.S. education levels has not kept up with the rising

    demand for skilled workers, and the slowdown in educational

    aainment has been particularly severe for males. Te result

    has been a sharp rise in the inequality of wages.

    A second, equally signicant challenge is that the structure of

    job opportunities in the United States has sharply polarized

    over the past two decades, with expanding job opportunities

    in both high-skill, high-wage occupations and low-skill, low-

    wage occupations, coupled with contracting opportunities in

    middle-wage, middle-skill white-collar and blue-collar jobs.

    Concretely, employment and earnings are rising in both high-

    education professional, technical, and managerial occupa-

    tions and, since the late 1980s, in low-education food service,

    personal care, and protective service occupations. Conversely,

    job opportunities are declining in both middle-skill, white-

    collar clerical, administrative, and sales occupations and in

    middle-skill, blue-collar production, cra, and operative

    occupations. Te decline in middle-skill jobs has been detri-

    mental to the earnings and labor force participation rates of

    workers without a four-year college education, and dieren-

    tially so for males, who are increasingly concentrated in low-

    paying service occupations.

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    34/43

    2 enter for merican rogre | www.americanprogre.org

    he olarization of Job pportunitie in the U.s. abor arket

    Tis paper analyzes the state of the U.S. labor market over

    the past three decades to inform policymaking on two fronts.

    Te rst is to rigorously document and place in historical and

    international context the trajectory of the U.S. labor market,

    focusing on the evolving earnings, employment rates, and

    labor market opportunities for workers with low, moderate,

    and high levels of education. Te second is to illuminate the

    key forces shaping this trajectory, including:

    Te slowing rate of four-year college degree aainment

    among young adults, particularly males

    Shis in the gender and racial composition of the workforce

    Changes in technology, international trade, and the inter-

    national oshoring of jobs, which aect job opportunities

    and skill demands

    Changes in U.S. labor market institutions aecting wage set-

    ting, including labor unions and minimum wage legislation

    Te causes and consequences of these trends in U.S. employ-

    ment paerns are explored in detail below, but the main con-

    clusions can be summarized as follows:

    Employment growth is polarizing, with job opportunities

    concentrated in relatively high-skill, high-wage jobs and

    low-skill, low-wage jobs.

    Tis employment polarization is widespread across industri-

    alized economies; it is not a uniquely American phenomenon.

    Te key contributors to job polarization are the automa-

    tion of routine work and, to a smaller extent, the interna-

    tional integration of labor markets through trade and, more

    recently, oshoring.

    Te Great Recession has quantitatively but not qualitatively

    changed the trend toward employment polarization in the

    U.S. labor market. Employment losses during the recession

    have been far more severe in middle-skilled white- and

    blue-collar jobs than in either high-skill, white-collar jobs

    or in low-skill service occupations.

    As is well known, the earnings of college-educated workers

    relative to high school-educated workers have risen steadily

    for almost three decades.

    Less widely discussed is that the rise in the relative earn-

    ings of college graduates are due both to rising real earnings

    for college workers and falling real earnings for noncollege

    workersparticularly noncollege males.

    Gains in educational aainment have not generally kept

    pace with rising educational returns, particularly for males.

    And the slowing pace of educational aainment has contrib-

    uted to the rising college versus high school earnings gap.

    While these points are eshed out in the body of the paper, I

    briey unpack each of them here.

    Employment growth is polarizing into

    relatively high-skill, high-wage jobs and

    low-skill, low-wage jobs

    Secular shis in labor demand have led to a pronounced polar-

    ization of job opportunities across occupations, with employ-

    ment growth concentrated in relatively high-skill, high-wage

    and in low-skill, low-wage jobsat the expense of middle-

    skill jobs. Tis polarization is depicted in Figure 1, which plots

    the change in the share of U.S. employment in each of the last

    three decades for 326 detailed occupations encompassing all of

    U.S. employment.4

    Tese occupations are ranked on the x-axis by skill level fromlowest to highest, where an occupations skill level (or, more

    accurately, its skill rank) is approximated by the average wage

    of workers in the occupation in 1980.5 Te y-axis of the gure

    corresponds to the change in employment at each occupa-

    tional percentile as a share of total U.S. employment during

    the decade. Since the sum of shares must equal one in each

    decade, the change in these shares across decades must total

    zero. Consequently, the gure measures the growth in each

    occupations employment relative to the whole.

    Tis gure reveals a twisting of the distribution of employ-

    ment across occupations over three decades, which becomes

    more pronounced in each period. During the 1980s (1979

    to 1989), employment growth by occupation was almost

    uniformly rising in occupational skill; occupations below the

    median skill level declined as a share of employment, while

    occupations above the median increased. In the subsequent

    decade, this uniformly rising paern gave way to a distinct

    paern of polarization. Relative employment growth was

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    35/43

    ntroduction and summary

    he amilton roject | www.hamiltonproject.org 3

    most rapid at high percentiles, but it was also modestly posi-tive at low percentiles (10th percentile and down) and mod-

    estly negative at intermediate percentiles.

    Fast forward to the period 1999 to 2007. In this interval,

    the growth of low-skill jobs comes to dominate the gure.

    Employment growth in this period was heavily concentrated

    among the lowest three deciles of occupations. In deciles

    four through nine, growth in employment shares was nega-

    tive. In the highest decile of occupations, employment shares

    were at. Tus, the disproportionate growth of low-educa-

    tion, low-wage occupations becomes evident in the 1990s

    and accelerates thereaer.

    Notably, this paern of employment polarization has a coun-

    terpart in wage growth. Tis may be seen in Figure 2, which

    plots changes in real hourly wages relative to the median by

    wage percentile for all U.S. workers over two time periods:

    1974 to 1988 and 1988 to 2006.6 In the 1974 through 1988

    period, wage growth was consistently increasing in wage per-

    centile; wages at percentiles above the median rose relativeto the median while wages below the median fell. From 1988

    forward, however, the paern was U-shaped. Wages both

    above andbelow the median rose relative to the median.

    In short, wage gains in the middle of the distribution were

    smaller than wage gains at either the upper or lower reaches of

    the wage distribution. Tis simultaneous polarization of U.S.

    employment and wage growth suggests an important theme,

    explored in detail belowlabor demand appears to be rising

    for both high-skill, high-wage jobs and for traditionally low-

    skill, low-wage jobs.

    Employment polarization is widespread across

    industrialized economies

    Te polarization of employment across occupations is not

    unique to the United States, but rather is widespread across

    industrialized economies. Evidence of this fact is presented

    Source: Data are Census IPUMS 5 percent samples for years 1980, 1990, and 2000, and U.S. Census

    American Community Survey 2008. All occupation and earnings measures in these samples refer to

    prior years employment. The gure plots log changes in employment shares by 1980 occupational skill

    percentile rank using a locally weighted smoothing regression (bandwidth 0.8 with 100 o bservations),

    where skill percentiles are measured as the employment-weighted percentile rank of an occupations

    mean log wage in the Census IPUMS 1980 5 percent extract. Mean education in each occupation is

    calculated using workershours of annual labor supply times the Census sampling weight. Consistent

    occupation codes for Census years 1980, 1990, and 2000, and 2008 are from Autor and Dorn (2009a).

    IURE 1

    Smoothed changes in employment by

    occupational skill percentile, 19792007

    Change in employment share

    Skill percentile (ranked by occupational mean wage)

    25%

    20%

    15%

    10%

    5%

    0%

    -5%

    0 6020 8040 100

    19791989 19891999 19992007

    Source: May/OR CPS data for earnings years 1973-2009. Each year comprises a three-year moving

    average (e.g. 1974 contains May/OR data from 1973, 1974, and 1975), with years equally weighted. The

    real log hourly wage is computed by year for each percentile between the 5th and 95th percentiles. In

    every year, real log hourly wages are adjusted such that they equal zero at the respective years median

    (50th percentile). The percent change represents the dierence in the log wages values (relative to the

    median) at each percentile between the relevant years.

    See Data Appendix for more details on treatment of May/OR CPS data.

    IURE 2

    Percent changes in male and female hourly wages

    relative to the median

    Percent change relative to the median

    Hourly earnings percentile

    15%

    10%

    5%

    0%

    -5%

    -10%

    -15%

    19741988 19882006

    5 20 35 50 65 80 95

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    36/43

    ntroduction and summary

    he amilton roject | www.hamiltonproject.org 7

    trade and oshoring, de-unionization, and a falling mini-

    mum wage. Te section that follows further documents that

    the polarization of employment is not unique to the U.S. but

    rather is widespread among European Union economies.

    Te paper then steps back from this detailed portrait of polar-

    ization to explore the overriding role of labor demand shis

    in explaining the sharp changes in earnings and employ-

    ment levels by education and sex. Tis section shows that

    the rising wages of college-educated workers relative to high

    school-educated workers can in large part be explained by

    a long-term, secular rise in the demand for college workers

    coupled with a sharp decline in the entry of new college

    workers in the U.S. labor market starting in the late 1970s.

    Tis section highlights that a major proximate cause of this

    slowdown is the sharp deceleration in the rate of college

    aainment among young males starting in the late 1970s, thereasons for which are only poorly understood.

    Te nal section explores earnings by education level in

    greater detail to document that the simple college versus

    high school earnings dichotomy masks a highly consequen-

    tial development: Te rising demand for education appears

    to be limited to very high levels of education. Workers with

    less than a four-year college education, and particularly non-

    college males, experienced stagnant or in some cases declin-

    ing earnings over the past three decades. I link these striking

    wage developments to the polarization of employment, argu-

    ing that declining opportunities in middle-skill jobs help

    to explain why wages are rising for highly educated work-

    ers whiles wages for middle- and low-educated workers are

    growing less rapidly and, moreover, converging toward one

    another. Te paper then oers concluding observations.

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    37/43

    10 enter for merican rogre | www.americanprogre.org

    he olarization of Job pportunitie in the U.s. abor arket

    Sex differences in job polarization

    Te polarization of employment into low- and high-skill

    occupations has unfolded with increasing velocity over the

    past two decades. But this polarization did not occur evenly

    among the sexes, as is shown in Figure 4.

    Te rst set of columns in Figure 4 plot the change between

    1979 and 2007 in the share of employment in high-, middle-,

    and low-skill occupations among each sex. Te share of male

    employment in middle-skill occupations dropped by 7.0 per-

    cent. For females, the fall was even larger at 15.8 percent. Yet

    this hollowing out of the occupational distribution had dif-

    ferent consequences for the sexes. Females moved dramati-

    cally upward in the occupational distribution as they departed

    the center. Male employment instead moved in roughly equal

    measures to the tails of the distributionthat is, to high-wage, high-skill and low-wage, low-skill jobs.

    Te second set of bars in Figure 4 breaks these paerns by edu-

    cation group, showing that the share of males with no more

    than a high school education employed in middle-skill occupa-

    tions dropped by 3.9 percent between 1979 and 2007. More

    than the entirety of this decline is accounted for by a corre-

    sponding rise in employment in low-skill service occupations.

    Simultaneously, the share of employment among males with

    some college education declined in both middle- and high-

    skill occupations. Even among males with a four-year col-

    lege degree, employment in high-wage occupations declined

    noticeably, with the slack taken up approximately evenly by

    middle- and low-skill occupations.

    Some portion of this occupational shi is arguably mechani-

    cal. As the share of workers with higher educations rises, it

    is inevitable that some subset will take traditionally noncol-

    lege jobs. Put simply, when a third of the workforce is college

    educated, not all college-educated workers will be managers

    or professionals. Nevertheless, the decline of middle-skill

    jobs has clearly displaced males toward the tails of the occu-pational distribution. And the net eect is an increase in the

    share of males in low-skill occupations compared to the share

    of males in high-skill occupations.

    Figure 4 paints a more encouraging picture for females.

    Women with less than a four-year college degree experienced

    Source: May/OR CPS data for earnings years 1979-2007. See note to igure 12. The 10 broad occupations are classied as belonging to one of three broad skill groups.

    IURE 4

    Changes in occupational employment shares by education and sex, 19792007

    Males

    Females

    Percentage change in occupational employment shares

    -20%

    -16%

    -12%

    -8%

    -4%

    0%

    4%

    8%

    12%

    16%

    20%

    All

    Low

    Occupation skill group Occupation skill group Occupation skill group Occupation skill group

    Medium High Low Medium High Low Medium High Low Medium High

    High school or less Some college College +

    Definitions of skill groups

    High skill: Managerial, professional, and technical occupations

    Medium skill: Sales, office/admin, production, and operators

    Low skill: Protective service, food prep, janitorial/cleaning, personal care/services

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    38/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    39/43

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    40/43

    Into the Eye of the Storm:

    Assessing the Evidence on Science and Engineering

    Education, Quality, and Workforce Demand

    October 2007

    B. Lindsay Lowell

    Georgetown [email protected]

    Hal Salzman

    The Urban [email protected]

    An earlier version of this paper was presented at the meetings of the Association for Public PolicyAnalysis and Management, October 2006. We would like to thank the session participants for their

    feedback. We also benefited from review of an earlier version of this paper by Michael Feuer, Richard

    Freeman, Richard Fry, Chris Hill, Robert Lerman, David Mandel, Steve Merrill, and Mark Regets.

    Funding for this research came from the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation and the National Science Foundation

    (Human and Social Dynamics Program, SES-0527584). Research assistance was provided by Everett

    Henderson, Daniel Kuehn, and Katie Vinopal.

    Copyright October 2007. The Urban Institute. All rights reserved. Except for short quotes, no part of

    this report may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical,

    including photocopying, recording, or by information storage or retrieval system, without written

    permission from the Urban Institute.

    The Urban Institute is a nonprofit, nonpartisan policy research and educational organization that examines

    the social, economic, and governance problems facing the nation. The views expressed are those of the

    authors and should not be attributed to the Urban Institute, its trustees, or its funders.

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    41/43

    ii

    Abstract

    Several high-level committees have concluded that current domestic and global trends are

    threatening Americas global science and engineering (S&E) preeminence. Of the challenges

    discussed, few are thought to be as serious as the purported decline in the supply of high quality

    students from the beginning to the end of the S&E pipelinea decline brought about by

    declining emphasis on math and science education, coupled with a supposed declining interest

    among domestic students in S&E careers.

    However, our review of the data fails to find support for those presumptions. Rather, the

    available data indicate increases in the absolute numbers of secondary school graduates and

    increases in their math and science performance levels. Domestic and international trends

    suggest that that U.S. schools show steady improvement in math and science, the U.S. is not at

    any particular disadvantage compared with most nations, and the supply of S&E-qualified

    graduates is large and ranks among the best internationally. Further, the number of

    undergraduates completing S&E studies has grown, and the number of S&E graduates remains

    high by historical standards. Why, then, is there a purported failure to meet the demand for S&E

    college students and S&E workers?

    Analysis of the flow of students up through the S&E pipeline, when it reaches the labor market,

    suggests the education system produces qualified graduates far in excess of demand: S&E

    occupations make up only about one-twentieth of all workers, and each year there are more than

    three times as many S&E four-year college graduates as S&E job openings. So it is not clear,

    even if there were deficiencies in students average S&E performance, that such deficiencies

    would necessarily be insufficient to meet the requisite S&E demand. While improving average

    math and science education at the K12 level may be warranted for other reasons, such a strategy

    may not be the most efficient means of supplying the S&E workforce.

    Workforce development and education policy requires a more thorough analysis than appears to

    be guiding current policy reports. The available evidence points, first, to a need for targeted

    education policy, to focus on the populations in the lower portion of the performance

    distribution. Second, the seemingly more-than-adequate supply of qualified college graduates

    suggests a need for better understanding why the demand side fails to induce more graduates

    into the S&E workforce. Third, public and private investment should be balanced between

    domestic development of S&E workforce supply and global collaboration as a longer-term goal.

    Policy approaches to human capital development and employment from prior eras do not address

    the current workforce or economic policy needs.

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    42/43

    32

    not increased notably from the 1980s to the present day, albeit about one-tenth of college

    freshman require science and one-fifth require some math remediation (NSF 2006, table 2).

    Still, students with low achievement may lead to low postgraduate transition and retention rates,

    which could be consistent with the findings of S&E education suffering from poor pedagogy,

    inadequate educational systems, or simply a surfeit of low performers who somehow make it into

    S&E fields of study. Table 3 examines the possibility that large numbers of S&E graduates have

    poor grades and, despite having a degree in hand, are not adequately prepared to either continue

    further S&E studies or take S&E employment. It shows that slightly higher performing students

    continue on an S&E pathway after graduation, but there is no dramatic change between 1995 and

    2001. Only about a quarter of S&E bachelors students with less than a 2.75 GPA stay on an

    S&E trajectory, while about a third of those with better GPAs stay the course. Similarly, about

    half of S&E masters students with less than a 2.75 GPA stay on an S&E trajectory, while nearly

    two-thirds of those with better GPAs stay the course. However, for those who enter the job

    market at each stage, a greater proportion of low-GPA graduates find S&E employment than do

    high-GPA students. The lower rate of job entry by high GPA graduates is due, in part, to higher

    GPA students continuing their education rather than entering the job market. However, the lower

    rate may also be the result of higher GPA students entering other, non-S&E careers (a point we

    are examining in current research). A low GPA is apparently not a bar to finding S&E

    1995 2001 1995 2001 1995 2001

    Bachelors 698,200 758,300 28.8 33.4 71.2 66.53.754.0 83,400 116,900 36.2 35.7 63.8 64.42.753.74 524,300 566,100 28.3 33.6 71.8 66.3Less than 2.75 89,400 74,400 25.4 28.6 74.8 71.4

    Masters 146,300 160,100 62.1 62.8 37.9 37.13.754.0 33,600 41,800 68.4 66.2 31.7 33.82.753.74 100,600 109,200 60.6 62.4 39.5 37.7Less than 2.75 11,300 8,300 55.3 51 44.7 49

    SOURCE: Adapted from National Science Foundation, Division of Science Resources Statistics, National Survey of Recent

    College Graduates, 1995 and 2001, special tabulations, Table 2-9, 2003. Science & Engineering Indicators 2004. Due to

    rounding percents may not add to one hundred

    Degree level & GPA

    1995 and 2001

    Table 3. Employment and Education Status of S&E Degree Recipients by Degree and GPA

    Graduates

    % In S&E

    (Employed or Continuing in S&EMajor in School)

    % Employed in S&E

    (of those employed)

  • 8/8/2019 Presentation 9-21-10

    43/43

    graduates in all fields may not perceive their education as highly related to their occupation, and

    thus additional measures are needed to better understand the specific contribution of an S&E

    education to employment in non-S&E fields.

    In short, the U.S has been graduating more S&E students than there have been S&E jobs; hence,

    there are 15.7 million workers who report at least one degree in an S&E field but 4.8 million

    workers in an S&E occupation. There is, rather obviously, high attrition from school to work,

    and it simply cannot be explained by underachieving S&E graduates failing to qualify for jobs.

    At the same time, many of the S&E graduates outside of a formal S&E job may benefit from

    their training, but the simple indicators used here suggest that such training is not central to their

    current employment. This evidence suggests that the school-to-work attrition is neither due to

    poor educational preparation or, more optimistically, to the failure of formal occupational

    classifications to capture the extent to which S&E training is used in the labor market. Something

    else appears to be going on.

    The S&E Job Market: What is the Nature of the Demand?

    The pathway from high school student to college graduate has a number of transition points that

    are the primary focus of current policy initiatives. The goal of these initiatives is to increase theflow into, and retention within the S&E education pipeline. However, the data we have reviewed

    suggest that secondary and higher education systems are providing more than adequate supply

    for industrys hiring needs. Of course, these are aggregate numbers, so there still could be

    shortages for particular occupations or industries; targeted initiatives to increase the flow of

    underrepresented demographic and income groups are warranted to increase workforce

    opportunity and workforce diversity. But overall, addressing the presumed labor market

    problems through a broad-based focus on the education system seems a misplaced effort.

    Whether increasing the supply of S&E educated workforce entrants would have any significant

    impact on workforce supply (given a graduate pool already 50 percent larger than annual

    openings) is a question that requires a better understanding of the labor market for these

    graduates. Moreover, increasing the education supply with such low yields seems a highly