seungmook choi university of nevada, las vegas kookmin … the... · 2017. 1. 31. · jlt approach...

43
The Issuance of Callable, Defaultable Bonds under Information Asymmetry by Seungmook Choi and Mel Jameson Department of Finance University of Nevada, Las Vegas and Mookwon Jung Department of Finance Kookmin University March 25, 2009 * This paper is prepared for the submission to a 2009 Joint symposium with KCMI in Seoul Korea. Please correspond to Seungmook Choi at [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 23-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

The Issuance of Callable, Defaultable Bonds under Information Asymmetry

by

Seungmook Choi

and

Mel Jameson

Department of Finance

University of Nevada, Las Vegas

and

Mookwon Jung

Department of Finance

Kookmin University

March 25, 2009

* This paper is prepared for the submission to a 2009 Joint symposium with KCMI in

Seoul Korea. Please correspond to Seungmook Choi at [email protected]

Page 2: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

i

Abstract

In this paper we reconsider the evidence regarding the signaling theory of callable

bond issuance and the interpretation of that evidence. The data indicate that call spreads

are greater for speculative grade bonds than for investment grade bonds. For the

speculative grades, post-issue performance, as measured by rating changes and

cumulative stock returns, is better for callable than non-callable bonds. Among

investment grade bonds, such differences do not appear. All this might suggest that

callable bonds could serve a signaling function, at least for speculative grade bonds.

However, there is no evidence of a positive market reaction upon issuance of callable

debt.

To suggest a resolution of this apparent paradox, we simulate callable and non-

callable bonds yields for firms which do, or do not, have better than usual prospects, to

characterize the cost and benefits to issuing callable debt. The simulation results

illustrate that, although managers of firms with good prospects do have reason to prefer

to issue callable debt, there is enough noise in the system that this behavior does not

serve as a reliable signal to the market. It is asymmetric information, more than any

signaling effect, that characterizes this market.

Page 3: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

1

1. Introduction

Despite the considerable literature analyzing callable bonds and why they are

issued, there is surprisingly little consensus regarding the empirical evidence on why call

features are employed.

Broadly speaking, theories of call usage fall into two categories: an interest rate

risk hedging tool and a tool to resolve conflicts between issuers and investors. The

interest rate hedging story is attributed to Pye (1966). Under this story use of call

features depends mainly on the properties of the stochastic process driving interest rates,

the availability of alternative instruments to hedge interest rate risk and factors affecting

an issuer’s desire to hedge.

A variety of theories in the second category have been proposed. Their common

feature is a relation between the presence of a call feature and the stochastic process

driving default behavior. Depending on the theory this relation results because presence

of the call option influences the post-issue decisions of management, or because

management’s initial decision to include the call feature results from information about

that process that is not ex ante available to the market.

These stories include: “resolving debt overhang” or “underinvestment” (Boddie

and Taggart 1978; Myers 1977) whereby straight debt would lead managers to neglect

positive NPV projects because part of their benefit would accrue to bondholders; “risk-

shifting” or “asset substitution” (Barnea et.al. 1980; Jensen and Meckling 1976) whereby

straight debt would incentivize stockholders to seek risk-increasing (even if expected

value-decreasing) changes in investment strategy; “removing restrictive covenants” (Vu

1986) whereby a call option limits the potential cost of removing a restrictive covenant

established to relieve some other agency cost of debt; “hedging investment uncertainty”

(Chen, Mao and Wang 2007) whereby the call allows an option to extend financing (or

not) at low transaction costs depending on investment prospects; and “signaling”

(Robbins and Schatzberg 1986, 1988) whereby the call option limits gains accruing to

bondholders when favorable information about the borrower is revealed to the market.

This latter implies managers will favor a call option when their information suggests the

Page 4: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

2

firm’s prospects are better than indicated by publicly available information, potentially

signaling the existence of this information.

The empirical evidence is mixed, with each of the above theories having its

proponents. Each theory postulates a problem addressed by including the call feature.

An operational test selects variables arguably correlated with the presence of that

problem, and tests for their coincidence with use of the call feature. Larger issue size and

longer maturity or duration seem to be associated with call usage (Kish and Livingston

1992; Crabbe and Helweg 1994; Guntay et. al. 2004) as are high interest rates. This is

interpreted by these authors as consistent with the interest rate hedging theory. Chen et al

(2007) report similar results but support the hedging investment uncertainty story.

Smaller firms and first-time issuers are more likely to use calls: Guntay et.al.(2004) take

this to support interest rate hedging, while Chen et al (2007) to support hedging

investment uncertainty. Certain stylized facts seem clear: prior to the 1980s the

overwhelming majority of bonds were callable, since then call usage is lower. Since that

time call usage is more common in speculative grade bonds (Crabbe and Helweg 1994).

Alternatively, evidence of the problem may emerge through events observable

after bond issue. Crabbe and Helweg (1994) find callable bonds are downgraded more

often than straight bonds, which they interpret to contradict agency theory. Vu (1986)

and King and Mauer (2000) find many bonds are called far later than the apparent

optimum and argue the delay is due to transaction cost of exercise.

In this paper, we improve on extant tests in two ways. First, we treat investment

grade and speculative grade bonds separately using a matching sample technique. None

of the theories suggested in the literature are mutually exclusive, nor is there any

compelling a priori reason to believe only one motive would dominate in every case. On

the contrary, most of the stories suggest different impacts across the two classes of bonds

raising the possibility that different considerations govern the two market segments.

Even more significantly, the empirical literature indicates very different patterns in call

usage between the two. Our results confirm that behavior for the two segments of the

bond market is best understood separately.

Our second innovation is to apply a methodology that permits a more explicit link

between the callable bond issuer’s behavior and the market response under information

Page 5: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

3

asymmetry. Jarrow, Lando, and Turnbull (JLT, 1997) develop a method for pricing

defaultable bonds in which there is explicit representation of both the interest rate process

and the default process. Specifically, the latter is represented by means of a transition

matrix describing the probability a bond will pass from one rating category to another

including, ultimately, default. In this paper we adapt the JLT method to include a call

option. This allows us to consider the impact of differences in the transition matrix on

the bond. Thus, it enables us to reflect either viewpoint in the transition matrix, and so to

derive the differing views of market and management regarding bond price as well as the

default premium and the call premium.

In the balance of the paper we use this approach to reconsider the evidence

regarding the signaling story of callable bond issuance. We look first at the available

direct empirical evidence, being careful to distinguish between investment grade and

speculative grade bonds. In order to help us understand these results, we then apply the

JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about

the underlying default process. These simulations also yield values for the default

premium and call premium of the callable bonds. Thus we are able to identify the benefits

and costs explicitly associated with callable bond issuance. Consideration of how these

respond to information about the default process is, often vaguely defined in the literature,

central to determining the viability of the call feature as a signaling mechanism.

In our empirical study, we find that speculative grade callable bonds are more

likely to be upgraded subsequent to issuance than are speculative grade non-callable

bonds by using a matching sample technique. The long-term, post issue stock

performance of firms issuing speculative grade, callable bonds is also better than that of

firms issuing speculative grade non-callable bonds. However, there is no announcement

effect upon the issue of speculative grade callable bonds. This result seemingly

contradicts the empirical finding that the probability of an upgrade is higher after

issuance, suggesting existence of a market inefficiency. We show that this phenomenon

can be explained without violation of market efficiency through the numerical analysis.

In the following section, we describe the data and the empirical results. Section 3

briefly explains the JLT model and the basic set-up adopted for the numerical analysis to

Page 6: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

4

be presented in Section 4, where we discuss how the observed empirical findings can be

explained. Section 5 concludes.

2. Data and empirical evidence

What observable consequences result when a callable bond serves a signaling

function? For signaling to occur, managers must first be asymmetrically better informed

than the market about the firm’s prospects. Those managers with favorable information

would conclude a call option is worth more than its market price and include it in their

debt issue. If market conditions were such that managers with unfavorable information

did not find it advantageous to “mimic” firms with good prospects by also issuing

callable debt, then using a call option would “signal” favorable information to the market.

If issuing a callable bond signals favorable information, the issue should be accompanied

by a favorable market reaction.1 Furthermore, after issuance, these theories imply

callable bonds should perform better than straight bonds.2

We first present empirical evidence on the magnitude of call premiums. While

this does not directly address the signaling hypothesis, it will be of value for purposes of

comparison with the simulation results to follow. We then consider post-issue

performance, as measured by rating changes and cumulative stock performance, and

finally the market response to bond issuance.

a) Data

We use primary market data on callable and non-callable bonds that come from

the New Issue Database of Security Data Corporation (SDC), covering 1981 through

2004. We exclude foreign companies, convertible bonds, Asset Backed Securities,

Gvernment/agency issues and non-fixed coupons, as well as all issues missing

information on the offering date, offering price, maturity, YTM, or initial bond rating.

Those observations for which CRSP data are unavailable were also eliminated, so that ex- 1 Firms that are particularly prone to information asymmetry should tend to favor callable bonds. Guntay et. al. (2004) and Chen, Mao and Wang (2007) report that smaller firms and first-time issuers are more likely to use callable debt. However these authors interpret this as support of interest rate hedging and hedging investment uncertainty, rather than of asymmetric information or signaling. 2 Nayar & Stock (2008) consider a sample of shelf-registered bond issues. They find that the market shows a significant negative reaction to the issue of straight bonds, but no significant reaction to callable bond issues. The difference between the callable and non-callable reaction is significant.

Page 7: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

5

post long-term stock performance for the sample can be estimated. The resulting data are

summarized in Table 1.

(Insert Table 1 around here)

This yields a sample of 2,206 callable bonds and 6,071 straight bonds. We note that

during the early part of the sample period (1981-5) callable bonds predominated. This

was a period of high interest rates. Thereafter straight bonds have consistently been in

the majority. However, speculative grade bonds (BB+ and below) always show a

majority of callable bonds. Kish and Livingston (1992), Crabbe and Helweg (1994) and

Chen et.al. (2007) report similar results regarding speculative grade bonds. Bonds rated

CCC+ or lower are very rare in the sample.

To get an idea of the call premium, we construct a matched sample of callable and

straight bonds. The matching process is particularly critical in this application because

the transition matrix (describing the probability of movements between rating categories

or into default) can be expected to change over the business cycle. The criteria for

matching were: month of issue, industry, maturity (<4 yrs, 4 to 9 yrs, 9 to 14 yrs, 14 to 23

yrs, 23 to 36 yrs, >= 36 yrs), placement method and rating. Given a callable bond,

finding a match with regard to the first four criteria generally presented no difficulty.

Unfortunately, an exact rating match was not generally possible. In such cases we sought

an otherwise matched bond with a rating in the same bucket ( AAA to AA−, A+ to A−,

BBB+ to BBB−, BB+ to D ) This resulted in a total of 400 callable bonds and their

matched sample of 745 straight bonds as shown in Table 2. When a pair-wise

comparison between callable and non-callable bond is necessary, an average over the

values for all straight bonds matched with a given callable bond is used.

(Insert Table 2 around here)

The matches between callable and non-callable bonds are not perfect. However, on

average they are reasonably close. Since there can be more than one non-callable bond

matched to a callable bond, yields of non-callable bonds are averaged to get a

Page 8: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

6

corresponding yield for the non-callable bond. From this table, we can take the

difference in yield at issue of each matched callable and non-callable pair as the measure

of the call premium. The results, segregated by investment/speculative grade appear in

Table 3.

(Insert Table 3 around here)

Note that the call premiums are larger for the speculative grade bonds. However, the

standard deviation of the premiums is also larger for this group.

b) Empirical tests

To compare the rating changes experienced after bond issue, we use the Mergent

FISD data base available through the Wharton Research Data Services (WRDS) to

identify rating changes for bonds in our sample during a five year period following issue.

The first rating change found during this period determined whether the observation was

classified as an upgrade or downgrade. It is highly unusual for the trend of rating

changes to reverse itself. If no further new rating was reported after issuance, the data

was considered a missing observation and was dropped from the sample. One possible

weakness of this approach is that defaults, which really should be counted as downgrades,

are not reported. However, our primary purpose is to compare rating changes of callable

and non-callable bonds within rating categories. If there is any bias in the distribution of

defaults across bond types, it is likely to follow the same pattern as that of downgrades.

Thus the most likely bias introduced by this problem would be against finding a

difference in the frequency of downgrades, particularly in speculative issues.

(Insert Table 4 about here)

Now let us consider the rating changes of the bonds after issuance. Define x=-1

for downgrade, x=0 for no change and x=1 for upgrade. And let F(x) and G(x) be the

cumulative probability distributions of rating change of a callable bond and a non-

callable bond respectively. A strictly better rating for callable bonds after issuance

Page 9: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

7

relative to non-callable bonds implies F(x) < G(x) for all x. It is often stated in the

investment literature that F has first order stochastic dominance over G.

Table 4 reports the empirical rating change results for 5 years after issuance. We

observe there is little difference in the rating changes between callable and non-callable

bonds for investment grade issues. However, among the speculative grade issues the

probability of an upgrade is smaller, and that of a downgrade noticeably higher for a non-

callable, as opposed to a callable bond. This implies that the empirically observed F is

less than the empirically observed G in speculative category. We may argue that F has

first order stochastic dominance over G. However, they are empirical probability

distributions. There is a still chance that even under F(x) = G(x) for all x, empirically

observed F(x) can be less than empirically observed G(x) for all x Thus, it is necessary to

examine the statistical significance of this difference.

For the purpose of testing statistical significance, we use a bootstrapping

technique. Under the assumption that the empirically observed G(x) is the true G(x), the

same number of observations, x, as the non-callable bond observation are drawn from

G(x).3 Define N-1 , N0 and N1 are the number of chosen random numbers for x = -1, x = 0,

and x=1 respectively, where N = N-1 + N0 + N1 . Then we identify which cell in the

following 2-by-2 matrix this bootstrapping result belongs to.

1 0 (0)N N FN

− +≤ 1 0 ( 1)N N F

N− +

> −SUM

1 ( 1)N FN

− ≤ − C11 C12 C13

1 ( 1)N FN

− > − C21 C22 C23

SUM C31 C32 C33

We repeat this procedure 10,000 times so that C33 = 10,000. Note that Cell, for example,

C11 shows how many times the resulting experiments result in the smaller or equal to

3 We first generate a random number, y, from the standard normal distribution, Φ(y). Then we assign x=-1 for Φ(y) < G(-1), x = 0 for G(-1)< Φ(y) <G(0) and x = 1 for Φ(y) > G(1). Accordingly, the assigned x is equivalent to the random drawing from G(x).

Page 10: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

8

empirically observed F(-1) and F(0). If C31/C33 and C13/C33 are less than a given

significance level, we may conclude that distribution F is significantly different from G.

Furthermore, the empirically observed F(-1) < G(-1) and F(0) < G(0), rejection of the

null that F = G implies that we can set the alternative hypothesis as F has first order

stochastic dominance over G. In addition, for this case, we may use C11 as the p-value

for the test of first-order stochastic dominance.

(Insert Table 5 around here)

Table 5 reports the bootstrapping results for the speculative grade case (Panel A),

Investment Grade case (Panel B) and total case (Panel C). For speculative grade case,

C11 shows only 0.24%. Thus we can reject the null that F=G and accept the alternative

that F has first order stochastic dominance over G at the 1% significance level. However,

the bootstrapping results for investment grade case and total grade case suggest that we

cannot reject the null that F=G.

These results are consistent with the story that managers possessing favorable

knowledge about their firm’s prospects that is not known to bond raters systematically

prefer callable bonds. This would be more prominent in a noisier market. Indeed,

speculative bond markets are very noisy as shown in Figure 1.

(Insert Figure 1 around here)

Fig. 1 shows yield curves for different grades on the last business day of

December 1998, available from the Fixed Income Securities Data (FISD), provided by

Mergent, Inc. The yields are a combination of trader quotes and matrix quotes. The

legend T stands for Treasury bonds, and other legends are S&P ratings. If there is a

signaling phenomenon, it is more likely to occur in the low rating bond markets, where

yields for bond of identical ratings vary widely for all maturities. More importantly, the

benefit of signaling (reduction of the market required yields on debts ) for speculative

rating firms would be substantially large relative to the investment grade firms.

Page 11: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

9

We turn now to stock returns as evidence of post-issue performance. These

should be consistent with the bond ratings changes, since whatever information led to the

rating change, should also stimulate a market response. Table 6 reports the five-year

cumulative returns following bond issue.

(Insert Table 6 about here)

For issuers of investment grade bonds, there is little apparent difference in cumulative

returns or their standard deviation between callable and non-callable bonds. For the

speculative grade bonds returns appear to be better, although noisier (greater standard

deviation), for the callable than for the non-callable bonds, consistent with the rating-

change results. The bottom row of Table 6 shows results obtained looking at the

difference in return for the paired bonds. The results are similar. For investment grade

bonds the difference in return is small (actually negative) but statistically significant. For

the speculative grade bonds, the difference is larger, but not statistically significant. The

statistical insignificance may be due to the larger standard deviation. The large standard

deviation for callables relative to non-callables in the speculative group seems natural

even if both issuers face the same migration matrix because the option values change

after migrations are realized. At any rate, the pattern of post-issuance stock performance

is similar to that found for rating changes, and is consistent with the story that managers

with more favorable information than is available to the market tend to prefer callable

bonds.

If managers with favorable information prefer callable bonds, it is natural to

postulate that the announcement of a callable bond issue should convey favorable

information to the market. Table 7 reports the market response observed in a two-day

(0,+1) window at the time of the announcement of debt issuance.4 The table reports

results using both the market model of Brown-Warner (1985) and the market-adjusted

model.

(Insert Table 7 about here)

4 We use the offering date provided in SDC data as the announcement date.

Page 12: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

10

The table reports results for the bonds used in the matching sample. In no case is

there a statistically significant announcement effect. This result is consistent with Nayer

and Stock (2005) who report an insignificant market response to the announcement of

callable debt issues, and of Eckbo (1986) and Lewis et al. (1999) who report an

insignificant response to straight debt issues.5

This is somewhat surprising since there would be a market reaction to callable

bond issuance announcements if callable bonds on average were expected to do better

than non-callable bonds. This would suggest an arbitrage trading strategy of buying a

diversified portfolio of speculative grade callable bond issuing firms’ stocks while

shorting a diversified portfolio of speculative grade non-callable bond issuing firms’

stocks. However, such an arbitrage may be difficult in practice due to transaction cost6

In the succeeding sections we provide theoretical justification for these empirical

results by numerically simulating the values of callable bonds.

3. The Simulation Model

These stories about the choice by asymmetrically informed managers to issue

callable or non-callable debt and why this choice seems to differ between investment

grade and speculative grade bonds depend on how the market values the call feature (and

the default prospects of the bond) given the available information set. In this section we

describe a model that permits us to calculate these values via numerical simulation given

a description of a stochastic process driving interest rates and of one driving bond

defaults. We then show that when the underlying stochastic processes are specified to

produce results that are qualitatively similar to those observed in the data, managers have

an incentive to use callable and non-callable bonds as observed.

Because the potential asymmetry of information mainly concerns the probability

of default, it is important to use a model in which this information enters explicitly. We 5As a check, we also test for the full (unmatched) sample. Again there is no significant announcement effect. 6 Kim, Klein and Rosenfeld (2008) consider the reverse stock split case where arbitrageurs are restricted in their ability to earn abnormal returns even if they correctly anticipated a price decline after reverse stock split, because of short sale restrictions on low-priced stocks.

Page 13: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

11

use the bond valuation model developed by Jarrow, Lando and Turnbull (1997),

(hereafter JLT), in which a migration matrix describes the probability a bond will move

from one state (rating status) to another, with default being an absorbing state. The

model permits this default process to combine with almost any plausible interest rate

process. Adapting the boundary conditions of this model to allow for the exercise of a

call option permits the simulation to generate the desired outputs.

While the choice of a term structure and spot interest rate process may affect

predicted levels of bond prices, our primary interest is in call spreads. Thus the number

of factors in the interest rate process and the current term structure of spot rates are not

central to our objective. As we use discrete time model for our simulation, we briefly

explain the discrete time version of the JLT model. Let Vt be the K-dimensional column

vector of values for bonds in K rating classes, with the K-th element being the value for

the default status which is essentially recovery value. The i-th element, Vt(i), thus,

represents the value of a bond in state i (i-th highest rating) at time t. Then the values of

the bond at time t given information Ωt under the assumption that the migration matrix,

M, is homogeneous in time may be given by

( )~

1 1 |tr tt t t te E M−+ += ⋅ + Ω⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦V V C (1)

where rt is the default-free spot rate over one period, ~

tE is the expectation operator under

risk-neutral world, and Ct is the vector of promised coupons. V0, can be calculated

recursively from maturity time T to time 0, given the terminal values, VT. The callable

bond values are also calculated by a given call decision rule. Since we are interested in

the comparison over different grade bonds, we may consider the callable bonds with the

same call prices, X, and the same call date, T1, for all bonds. Then equations (1) is

replaced by

( ) ~

1 1min , |tr tt t t tX e E M−+ += ⋅ + Ω⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦V V C (2)

for all 1t T≥ .

Let G be a K-1 dimensional vector of recovery rates, g(i), for i=1,..K-1 differently

rated bonds. The recovery rates for each different grade bond may not necessarily be the

Page 14: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

12

same.7 However, this is not important as will be discussed shortly. We assume that the

value of the bond in bankruptcy state, K, at time t depends on the state at time t-1. Thus,

the last element of Vt is assumed to be the recovery rate of the face value with no coupon

payment. However, the recovery rate may differ depending on the state at time t-1. Thus,

in the process of backward induction, the value of a bond, Vt-1(i) for i K≠ , is obtained by

setting the last element of Vt, Vt(K), equal to g(i).

In our simulations we choose a coupon “C” so that the bond in question is priced

at par according to equation (1) (straight bond) or (2) (callable bond). We report the

difference between the two coupon rates as the value of the call option in terms of

percentage point. We use a Ho-Lee interest rate process with a flat term structure at 10%

and a spot rate volatility of 2%. All bonds pay a semi-annual coupon and have a maturity

of seven years. Callable bonds offer three years of call protection, and may be redeemed

at 105% of par thereafter.

Note that the difference between a lower rate bond par yield and a higher rated

bond par yield is the difference in their default risk premiums. Note that because the

identical interest rate process drives all bonds in the simulation, any such difference

reflects differences in the default process, not in the spot rate volatility. Similarly, as

stated earlier, the specifics of the interest rate process and bond specification should not

materially affect our results because these are driven by differences in the default process.

Thus the heart of the model specification is the migration matrix describing the

probability of a rating change or of default. The most natural choice would seem to be to

use historical data describing default behavior over some appropriately chosen time span

for the migration matrix. However, many researchers, e.g., Hull et. al. (2005) and Tsuji

(2005), point out that this choice leads to a “credit spread puzzle” whereby the observed

risk premiums for lower grade bonds exceed values predicted using an historical or “real

world” migration matrix. This discrepancy is attributed to an additional liquidity

premium or non-diversifiable risk premium (associated with the default probability) that

is charged by the market for lower rated bonds. To incorporate this premium, a “risk

7 It is empirically observed that the lower the rating, the lower the recovery rate in the event of default. See Duffie and Singleton (1999) and Moody’s report.

Page 15: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

13

neutral” migration matrix is used to generate the simulation data. The relation between

the two migration matrices is given by:

where:

Q = one-year real world migration matrix

Q = one-year risk-neutral world migration matrix

I = Identity matrix

Π = Diagonal matrix with the last diagonal element equal to 1

Under the assumption that the migration matrix is homogeneous in time, per-period

migration matrix in our simulation is obtained by first converting Q to its generator

matrix, ~

M = logm(Q) and then taking the matrix exponential, ~

1exp m ( )i iM M t t −⎛ ⎞= ⋅ −⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

for per-period risk-neutral world migration matrix. The matrix Π is interpreted as

reflecting the liquidity risk premium relative to the normalizing element set equal to 1.

To resolve the credit spread puzzle, these diagonal elements must increase as the

corresponding bond ratings become lower. Consistent with this, our simulations assume

the diagonal element of Π increases by .06 with each change of bond rating category.

The simulation also assumes a 50% recovery rate from all bonds entering default. This

assumption will not affect the results unless there is a higher recovery rate for lower rated

bonds.

It will turn out that understanding the relation between the call premium and bond

rating is important to understanding the use of call features. Thus, that relation is a

central object of our initial simulation. A priori, the nature of that relation is not clear. A

lower bond rating could mean more volatility in the future upward movements (upgrades)

of the bond. More volatility implies greater option value. Alternatively, a lower rating

increases probability of default, lowering option value. We have seen in Table 3 that the

data suggest that, in fact, call option value increases as bond rating decreases. An

important object of our initial simulation is to determine characteristics of the risk neutral

migration matrix such that this is the case.

~Q I Q I⎡ ⎤− = Π −⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

Page 16: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

14

(Insert Table 8-a and 8-b about here.)

Table 8-a and Table 8-b show the associated one-year real world migration matrix

and its generator matrix respectively, based on (modified) data, from Moody’s Special

Report (2005).8 Using this real world migration matrix by setting Π = I generates the call

spreads (call option values of callable bonds ) illustrated in the upper figure of Figure 2.

In this figure, we omit the resulting yields for grade 17 that is, in fact, the sum of all

grades below 16 in the Table 1. This is done because our empirical data does not include

such low grades. Note that the call spreads decreases and then increases for lower rated

bonds. It is not immediately clear why this is so.

(Insert Figure 2 about here)

The difference between the Z-spread and OAS or “option adjusted spread” is often

understood as a call spread. The Z-spread is the additional yield of a callable, defaultable

bond over a comparable Treasury bond, and OAS is the additional yield of a callable,

defaultable bond over a hypothetical callable Treasury bond. We generate these spreads

for the par yields of a callable bond given by the model and that predicted for a callable

Treasury bonds having the same specification and calling decision, with the sole

exception of defaultability. We include it here for purposes of comparison. As shown in

all subsequent figures, the call spread thus obtained (Z-spread minus OAS) always

decreases as rating goes down. This implies that it always underestimates the true call

value. The OAS calculation ignores the default chance for a given par yield of a callable,

defaultable bond. Thus, the OAS value is inflated for the greater default chance, resulting

in lower call spread. For this reason, it is not relevant for comparisons with empirical call

spreads.

8 We modified the Moody’s one-year migration matrix as follows. We take the original one-year migration matrix and convert it to its generator matrix. Since the conditions to be a generator matrix must be met, where the sum of each row of the resulting generator matrix is equal to 0 and all off-diagonal elements must be non-negative, we modify the original one-year migration probabilities over each grade in a smoothing trend manner until the generator matrix satisfies the conditions.

Page 17: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

15

To allow for the liquidity/non-diversifiable risk premium we also conduct the

simulation using the risk-neutral generator matrix. The resulting call spreads are shown in

the bottom figure of Figure 2. These are qualitatively similar to those generated by the

historical data, and the call spreads are smoothly increasing as rating goes down. Table 9

summarizes the results, comparing the call spread and also the default premiums for

investment grade and speculative grade bonds in the two cases. Using the real world

migration matrix produce a ten-fold difference in the default premium between the two

classes, but little difference in the call premium. By contrast, the risk neutral migration

matrix also produces larger call spreads for speculative grade bonds. This latter case

seems more in conformity with the data reported in Table 3. More generally, these

results show that the call spreads generated do depend on the assumptions about the

choice of Π. It should be noted in Table 9 that the spread between callable bond yield

and treasury yield results mainly from the default risk premium. Moody’s special report

documents that the default risk premium ranges historically from 300 to 800 basis points

for speculative bonds. This fact is important for our later simulation that examines the

signaling mechanism, because it tells us the magnitude of the effects of the default risk

premium and the call spread on migration. As a caveat we note that, because the

migration matrix used here includes all types of firms and all types of bonds issued at all

points in the business cycle, the results may not be completely comparable to those

reported in the data section.

4. Call option values and use of callable bonds

In this section we conduct simulations similar to those of the previous section.

Here the goal is to understand the empirical results by considering when a manager of a

speculative grade firm has an incentive to issue callable bonds, and when this issue

conveys information to the market. In these simulations we compare the behavior of a

“typical” or “normal” speculative grade firm, that is to say one whose true migration

matrix conforms to that expected by the market, with that of a “good” speculative grade

firm, whose true migration matrix reflects better prospects. However, these better

Page 18: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

16

prospects are not apparent to the market. If this “good” information is realized, we

assume that this will be reflected in a manner of positive rating changes.

To examine the robustness of the results, we conduct two versions of the

simulation under very different assumptions about the default process driving the

“typical” firm. In both cases, the qualitative results are the same: managers of firms

whose prospects are better than typical prefer to issue callable bonds. However, this may

not convey information to the market, because of the noise resulting from the behavior of

the other firms.

We first consider the case in which the typical (normal) speculative grade firm

faces a migration matrix such that the value of a call option tends to decline as the bond

rating gets lower. Accordingly, the call value is relatively small for callable bonds issued

by such firms. A contrasting or “good” speculative grade firm has a more favorable

transition matrix, resulting in relatively large true option value. The situation of the

typical firm is in contrast to the situation indicated by the data and simulated in Section 3.

However, we consider this case because the strongly marked contrast between the two

kinds of firms would seem to offer the best chance for the market to discern the

difference between them. Subsequently we consider the arguably more realistic case in

which the “typical” speculative firm also faces a market-perceived migration matrix such

that its call value is increasing as bond rating declines. Here the “good” speculative firm

has an even better chance of an upgrade so that its call option value will be higher than

that of the typical firm.

The simulation approach is as described in Section 3. However the number of

bond rating categories has been consolidated to four, G1 (highest grade) through G4

(lowest grade) to streamline the procedure, while all other specifications remain the same.

Table 10-1 shows Case 1. The upper panel is the one-year migration matrix faced by the

“typical” firm that belongs to grade G4 initially, and the lower panel is the matrix faced

by a “good” firm that belongs to grade G4. These are the probabilities of the given

transition during the course of one year. The key observation is that the “good” firm has

a higher than typical probability of moving from a bad state to a better one.

(Table 10-1 about here)

Page 19: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

17

The one year transition matrix is derived from a generator matrix that reflects transition

probability densities that are reported in Table 10-2. Here one sees clearly that transition

probabilities are the same for G1 through G3. They differ only for the G4 grade firms;

one with “typical” and one with “good” prospects.

(Table 10-2 about here)

Figure 3-1 reports the par yield and call spreads for the “typical” firm in this

scenario. We note that this is the case where the call premium does, indeed, decline as

the bond rating worsens.

(Insert figures 3-1 and 3-2 here)

Figure 3.2 provides the same information for the “good” firm. Here the call spread does

increase as bond rating declines.

Since we are examining two firms that belong to G4 under information

asymmetry, we summarize their corresponding yields associated with callable and

noncallable bonds in Figure 3-3. If the typical firm issues a non-callable bond, the market

yield on the bond is located at (). If the firm issues a callable bond, the market requires

the yield at (o), paying an extra yield, distance A, which could be viewed as the call

option cost. Note that the distance is very small as intended for Case 1. The manager of a

good firm knows the prospects better than the market, and if he successfully conveys the

information to the market, a non-callable bond can be issued at (*), which is much lower

than the typical firm’s yield (). If the issuance of the callable bond is necessary in order

to signal to the market, then the firm must pay the higher yield (x). Of course in this case

the true option cost(distance B) is now much larger than that of the typical firm (distance

A).

(Insert Figure 3-3 here)

Page 20: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

18

Because only managers, not potential equity or bond investors, know which firms

are good, the market requires the typical yield () for non-callable debt. If issuing

callable debt works as a signal to distinguish a good firm, the market would require the

higher yield (x) for callable debt. In that case a manager of a “typical” firm would not

wish to issue callable debt, because the market would want to charge more than its fair

price. The manager of a good firm, however, would indeed wish to issue callable debt.

Even though the total cost of the debt is higher, the price of the call option is fair,

meaning that the firm will recoup it, on average, when the call is exercised. Thus C is

also the resulting benefit to the firm. This is just the value of having the market truly

assess default risk. If these were the only two kinds of firms in the system and there were

no other sources of noise to confuse the market, then a separating equilibrium would be

sustainable in which “good” firms issued callable debt and “typical” firms did not. In this

case, issuance of callable debt signals to the market that the issuer is a “good” firm

conferring a benefit of C to the firm. Therefore, the issuance announcement of a callable

bond will have a positive effect on the issuing firm’s stock price. However, this might

not be immediately apparent, since one could observe only that non-callable bonds offer

the typical yield () while callable debt yields (x). The difference between the two is not

the call spread for either type of firm, although it might erroneously be interpreted as

such.

It should be noted that the migration matrix that the market perceives is assumed

to be the one faced by the “typical” firm. If the market did not take callable debt to be a

signal of a good firm, managers of “good” firms would still prefer to issue callable debt

because now it is underpriced to them by the market. Managers of typical firms would be

indifferent between the two. Would “good” firm like to pay (x) which is more than

market requires to signal? The choice would depend on the size of immediate under-

valued benefit (distance D-A) with no signal and the size of immediate stock market

reaction benefit with signal at the additional cost, distance D-A. The empirically

observed absence of stock market reaction to callable bond issuance announcement

supports the former choice. Also, the data suggest that this is the less realistic of the two

cases we are considering. Allowing a multiplicity of firm types could also confound the

market’s ability to sort cleanly into a separating equilibrium. We take the key lesson of

Page 21: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

19

this exercise to be that, even in this case in which they are most strongly differentiated

from typical firms, good firms prefer to issue callable bonds.

In Case 2, prospects of the “good” firm remain the same as in the previous case.

However, those of the “typical” firm are now somewhat more favorable, as can be seen in

the one-year migration and generator matrices reported in Tables 11-1 and 11-2.

(Insert Tables 11-1 and 11-2 about here.)

Now the call spread generated from the migration matrix faced by the “typical” firm

show the more usual pattern of increasing as bond rating declines.

(Insert Figure 4.1 about here)

As in the previous case, being identified as a “good” firm results in a reduced default risk

premium. However now, the difference in magnitude of the two call spreads is smaller.

As illustrated in Figure 4-2, this may lead to a situation in which the callable yield for a

“good” firm lies below that of a “typical” firm.

(Insert Figure 4-2 about here)

Unlike the previous case, the simple act of issuing callable debt does not immediately

result in the penalty of higher borrowing costs for the typical firm. However, even if

issuing callable debt does not work as a signal, meaning the market treats all debt issues

as “typical”, managers of “good” firms will prefer callable debt when the situation is as

illustrated. If the firm issues non-callable debt, the market overcharges by C, the

difference in the default premium. Issuing callable debt adds a cost equal to the call

spread for a “typical” firm, but ultimately confers a benefit equal to the call spread for a

“good” firm. Although the good firm can not prevent itself from being overcharged by

the market, it can reduce the amount of this overcharge from C to D. Since the market

always charges the price appropriate to typical firms, these are indifferent between

callable and non-callable debt. If, for some reason, the market did treat callable debt as a

Page 22: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

20

signal of a “good” firm, the good firms would be all the more eager to issue callable debt.

Of course in the situation illustrated, the typical firms would also issue callable debt and

investors would lose money to them. In this case, “good” firms all prefer to issue callable

bonds, but the value of this act as a signal is lost, because nothing prevents “typical”

firms from issuing callable bonds as well.

Two key points emerge from these illustrations. The first is that “good” firms

generally have an incentive to issue callable bonds whether or not there is any signaling

effect. This is because their assessment of the benefit of the call feature derives from

their (asymmetrically favorable) knowledge of the firm’s prospects, which may not be

fully reflected in market pricing. The managers of “good” firms systematically prefer

callable debt is consistent with the empirical evidence that firms issuing callable debt

perform better post issue with respect to ratings upgrades and cumulative stock

performance. However, the illustrations also show that it is easy to devise circumstances

under which managers of typical firms are also happy to issue callable debt. This, in

combination with the general level of noise found in the data for speculative grade bonds,

suggests that it should not be all that surprising if the market is unwilling to draw a strong

conclusion from the fact of callable bond issuance. For these reasons, the absence of a

market response to the issuance of callable debt need not be considered surprising.

5. Conclusion

In looking at the data, we find that call spreads are greater for speculative grade

bonds than for investment grade bonds. In addition, for the speculative grades, callable

bonds are more likely to be upgraded and less likely to be downgraded following issue

than non-callable bonds, and they show better post-issue cumulative stock return

performance. Among investment grade bonds, evidence of such differences generally

does not appear. One might expect that these differences in post issue performance

would lead to a positive market reaction upon announcement of issue of callable debt.

However, this is not the case. We explain this puzzling effect by simulation. This

simulation approach plays an important role in identifying any benefits and costs

explicitly.

Page 23: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

21

The results of the simulation examples point toward a resolution of this apparent

paradox. They illustrate that, although managers of “good” firms do have reason to

systematically prefer to issue callable debt, there is enough noise in the system that this

behavior does not serve as a reliable signal to the market. It is asymmetric information,

more than any signaling effect that seems to drive this behavior.

Page 24: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

22

Table 1: Initial sample of bonds for callable and non-callable bonds Primary market data on callable and non-callable bonds come from the New Issue Database of Security Data Company (SDC). The data covers the period from 1981 to 2004. We exclude foreign companies, convertible bonds, ABS, Government/agency issues and non-fixed coupons, as well as all issues missing information on the offering date, offering price, maturity, YTM, or initial bond rating. The reported rating categories are from S&P and ratings in the parentheses are from Moody’s. AAA through BBB- are considered to be investment grades and BB+ and below speculative grades.

Ratings

(S&P)

Total

1981-

1985

1986-

1990

1991-

1995

1996-

2000

2001-

2004

Callable 428 124 114 58 86 46 AAA to AA-

(Aaa to Aa3) Non-

callable 1,144 51 188 269 422 214

Callable 692 172 181 67 130 142 A+ to A-

(A1-A3) Non-

callable 2,951 62 283 999 1,252 355

Callable 299 40 73 54 49 83 BBB+ to BBB-

(Baa1-Baa3) Non-

callable 1,612 19 93 514 775 211

Callable 787 17 41 133 315 281 BB+ and below-

(Ba1 and blow) Non-

callable 364 6 15 109 169 65

Callable 2,206 353 409 312 580 552 Total

Non-

callable 6,071 138 579 1,891 2,618 845

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10Investment Grades AAA

(Aaa) AA+

(Aa1) AA

(Aa2)AA-

(Aa3)A+

(A1)A

(A2)A-

(A3)BBB+ (Baa1)

BBB (Baa2)

BBB-(Baa3)

11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20BB+

(Ba1) BB

(Ba2) BB-

(Ba3)B+

(B1)B

(B2)B-

(B3)CCC+(Caa1)

CCC (Caa2)

CCC- (Caa3)

CC(Ca)

21 22 23 24

Speculative Grades

C (C)

DDD (D) DD D

Page 25: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

23

Table 2: Matched sample

Descriptive statistics for 400 callable bonds are grouped according to their initial bond ratings. Maturity is the time to maturity of the callable bond. Industry groups are the industries to which the issuer belongs. Private bonds are the bonds offered privately to selected individuals and institutions. Public bonds are the bonds offered to the public. The data for 745 non-callable bonds matched for each rating category are in parenthesis.

Maturity Industry group Private/Public Rating category

No obs (Yr) Industrial Finance Utility Private Public

75 13.4 37 36 2 0 75AAA to AA-(131) (9.81) (68) (60) (3) 0 (131)

201 14.7 132 59 10 0 201A+ to A-(432) (13.70) (287) (124) (21) 0 (432)

53 17.7 42 7 4 3 50BBB+ to BBB-(96) (18.30) (84) (8) (4) (4) (92)

BB+ to B- 71 8.9 67 1 3 49 22 (86) (9.00) (82) (1) (3) (61) (25)

400 13.8 278 103 19 52 347Total(745) (13.10) (521) (193) (31) (65) (680)

* No data below B- Table 3: Yield differences between callable and non-callable bonds This table is obtained from the matched sample: 400 obs of callables and 745 obs of noncallables. In the case that there is more than one non-callable bond matched for a callable bond, yields of non-callable bonds are averaged to get the yield difference.

Ratings Nobs Min Median (%)

Mean (%)

SD (%) Max (%)

Investment 329 -2.540 0.145 0.179 0.644 3.973

Speculative 71 -1.875 0.626 0.991 1.423 5.944

Total 400 -2.540 0.194 0.323 0.891 5.944

Page 26: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

24

Table 4: Rating changes of the matched sample after issuance The number of observations is further reduced due to the lack of rating change information. If we drop the observations from the sample when any one of the matched pair is not known for rating changes after issuance, we get 224 pairs for investment grades and 46 pairs for speculative grades. However, no qualitative difference is found.

Migration in 5 years (%) Samples Type Initial Grade Up Grade No Change Down Grade Nobs

Investment Grade 22.34 37.11 40.55 291 Speculative Grade 28.00 36.00 36.00 50

Non Callable Total 23.17 36.95 39.88

341

Investment Grade 18.65 35.32 46.03

252 Speculative Grade 33.85 45.15 20.00 65

Matched Callable Total 21.77 37.54 40.69

317

Page 27: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

25

Page 28: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

26

Table 5: Bootstrapping results Panel A: Speculative Grades

CumP(No

Change)<65.15% CumP(No

Change)>65.15% SUM CumP(Down)<20.00% 24 0.24% 14 0.14% 38 0.38%CumP(Down)>20.00% 1,324 13.24% 8,638 86.38% 9,962 99.62%SUM 1,344 13.44% 8,652 86,52% 10,000 100.00% Panel B: Investment grade

CumP(No

Change)<81.35% CumP(No

Change)>81.35% SUM CumP(Down)<46.03% 9,005 90,05% 570 5.70% 9,575 95.75%CumP(Down)>46.03% 305 3.05% 120 1.20% 425 4.25%SUM 9,310 93.10% 690 6.90% 10,000 100.00% Panel C: Total

CumP(No Change)<78.23%

CumP(No Change)>78.23%

SUM

CumP(Down)<40.69% 4,858 48.58% 1,134 11.34% 5,992 59.92%CumP(Down)>40.69% 2,164 21.64% 1,844 18.44% 4,008 40.08%SUM 7,022 70.22% 2,978 29.78% 10,000 100.00%

Page 29: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

27

Table 6 : Five-year cumulative stock returns ( ) is the difference between medians of callable and non-callable groups. The standard deviation for the row of “pairwise difference in returns” is the standard deviation of the mean.

Investment Grade (224) Speculative Grade (46) Total (270) Median Mean STD Median Mean STD Median Mean STD

Callables 0.685 0.664 0.492 0.707 0.557 1.242 0.689 0.646 0.678Non-callables 0.745 0.747 0.475 0.395 0.238 1.075 0.664 0.661 0.646

-0.033 0.391 0.003Pairwise Difference (-0.060)

-0.083 0.046(0.312)

0.319 0.242(0.025)

-0.015 0.057

Page 30: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

28

Table 7: Bond Issuance Announcement effect on abnormal stock returns The table reports results using both the market model (carmm) of Brown-Warner (1985) and the market-adjusted model (carmar). For callable bond firms, 400 observations are used, and for non-callable bond firms, 745 observations are used.

Total(%) Investment Grade(%) Speculative Grade(%)

Median Mean t-value Median Mean t-value Median Mean t-value carmm -0.044 -0.088 -0.57 -0.046 -0.093 -0.65 -0.009 -0.062 -0.11

Callables carmar -0.186 -0.108 -0.7 -0.18 -0.149 -1.02 -0.349 0.082 0.15

carmm -0.259 0.011 0.11 -0.26 -0.046 -0.51 0.12 0.446 0.83 Non- callables carmar -0.252 0.028 0.27 -0.256 -0.028 -0.31 0.022 0.458 0.87

Page 31: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

29

Table 8-a : Modified Moody’s one-year transition matrix The Moody’s one-year transition matrix based on 1983-2004 rating changes is modified so that the generator matrix obtained by taking matrix-logarithm on one-year transition matrix satisfies the condition for generator matrix. Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa1 D Aaa 0.8961 0.0615 0.0290 0.0043 0.0060 0.0022 0.0008 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa1 0.0206 0.8082 0.0852 0.0663 0.0152 0.0027 0.0005 0.0010 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa2 0.0067 0.0332 0.8160 0.0917 0.0326 0.0129 0.0050 0.0010 0.0006 0.0001 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa3 0.0010 0.0062 0.0385 0.8184 0.0930 0.0312 0.0070 0.0023 0.0010 0.0008 0.0002 0.0001 0.0000 0.0001 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000A1 0.0005 0.0010 0.0048 0.0581 0.8073 0.0821 0.0301 0.0073 0.0021 0.0007 0.0026 0.0016 0.0003 0.0007 0.0005 0.0001 0.0001 0.0001A2 0.0004 0.0004 0.0035 0.0079 0.0546 0.8019 0.0789 0.0306 0.0091 0.0049 0.0029 0.0007 0.0015 0.0008 0.0007 0.0002 0.0006 0.0003A3 0.0005 0.0013 0.0008 0.0019 0.0191 0.0712 0.7738 0.0719 0.0352 0.0131 0.0047 0.0014 0.0016 0.0018 0.0003 0.0005 0.0007 0.0003Baa1 0.0004 0.0004 0.0014 0.0018 0.0024 0.0220 0.0692 0.7590 0.0813 0.0326 0.0099 0.0046 0.0022 0.0068 0.0009 0.0009 0.0026 0.0018Baa2 0.0006 0.0011 0.0004 0.0017 0.0023 0.0065 0.0363 0.0602 0.7708 0.0742 0.0180 0.0057 0.0071 0.0055 0.0034 0.0013 0.0038 0.0013Baa3 0.0005 0.0001 0.0003 0.0008 0.0019 0.0042 0.0071 0.0323 0.0862 0.7300 0.0646 0.0281 0.0182 0.0068 0.0047 0.0024 0.0073 0.0042Ba1 0.0003 0.0000 0.0001 0.0003 0.0026 0.0023 0.0058 0.0103 0.0336 0.0928 0.6923 0.0553 0.0497 0.0171 0.0123 0.0087 0.0097 0.0068Ba2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0004 0.0004 0.0004 0.0021 0.0012 0.0040 0.0088 0.0271 0.0978 0.6777 0.0845 0.0287 0.0340 0.0117 0.0145 0.0064Ba3 0.0000 0.0002 0.0002 0.0001 0.0005 0.0015 0.0015 0.0022 0.0022 0.0071 0.0276 0.0615 0.6922 0.0714 0.0547 0.0302 0.0241 0.0228B1 0.0002 0.0000 0.0002 0.0002 0.0006 0.0012 0.0008 0.0006 0.0024 0.0022 0.0051 0.0316 0.0641 0.6689 0.0907 0.0520 0.0484 0.0307B2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0003 0.0003 0.0003 0.0012 0.0023 0.0009 0.0026 0.0035 0.0077 0.0190 0.0749 0.6308 0.0893 0.1073 0.0591B3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0008 0.0000 0.0004 0.0008 0.0008 0.0012 0.0012 0.0015 0.0012 0.0039 0.0065 0.0348 0.0580 0.6056 0.1798 0.1033Caa1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0001 0.0005 0.0001 0.0005 0.0005 0.0024 0.0005 0.0043 0.0076 0.0105 0.0465 0.7193 0.2071D 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000

Page 32: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

30

Table 8-b : Modified Moody’s Generator matrix This generator matrix is obtained from the modified Moody’s one-year transition matrix of Table 7-a. Aaa Aa1 Aa2 Aa3 A1 A2 A3 Baa1 Baa2 Baa3 Ba1 Ba2 Ba3 B1 B2 B3 Caa1 D Aaa -0.1107 0.0717 0.0302 0.0003 0.0058 0.0019 0.0007 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa1 0.0238 -0.2163 0.1030 0.0755 0.0125 0.0005 -0.0002 0.0011 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa2 0.0073 0.0403 -0.2082 0.1097 0.0332 0.0120 0.0046 0.0006 0.0005 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000Aa3 0.0009 0.0065 0.0466 -0.2074 0.1129 0.0324 0.0049 0.0015 0.0008 0.0008 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000A1 0.0005 0.0009 0.0040 0.0711 -0.2220 0.0997 0.0327 0.0058 0.0010 0.0000 0.0030 0.0019 0.0000 0.0008 0.0006 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000A2 0.0004 0.0003 0.0039 0.0070 0.0666 -0.2292 0.0978 0.0343 0.0074 0.0043 0.0030 0.0004 0.0016 0.0006 0.0008 0.0000 0.0006 0.0002A3 0.0005 0.0015 0.0006 0.0010 0.0210 0.0884 -0.2663 0.0908 0.0398 0.0132 0.0045 0.0009 0.0013 0.0017 0.0000 0.0005 0.0005 0.0001Baa1 0.0004 0.0003 0.0015 0.0018 0.0009 0.0239 0.0870 -0.2851 0.1025 0.0375 0.0102 0.0046 0.0010 0.0087 0.0000 0.0006 0.0027 0.0014Baa2 0.0007 0.0012 0.0003 0.0018 0.0019 0.0050 0.0432 0.0750 -0.2710 0.0964 0.0194 0.0045 0.0073 0.0059 0.0035 0.0007 0.0037 0.0004Baa3 0.0006 0.0000 0.0003 0.0008 0.0019 0.0041 0.0047 0.0384 0.1117 -0.3274 0.0872 0.0353 0.0197 0.0063 0.0038 0.0015 0.0081 0.0030Ba1 0.0004 0.0000 0.0000 0.0002 0.0031 0.0019 0.0059 0.0096 0.0379 0.1278 -0.3808 0.0754 0.0651 0.0188 0.0120 0.0094 0.0088 0.0047Ba2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0005 0.0005 0.0001 0.0023 0.0004 0.0036 0.0073 0.0287 0.1402 -0.4015 0.1170 0.0324 0.0436 0.0101 0.0127 0.0021Ba3 0.0000 0.0003 0.0002 0.0000 0.0005 0.0016 0.0015 0.0022 0.0012 0.0061 0.0333 0.0864 -0.3800 0.0986 0.0724 0.0364 0.0203 0.0191B1 0.0003 0.0000 0.0002 0.0002 0.0007 0.0013 0.0007 0.0002 0.0028 0.0015 0.0022 0.0423 0.0902 -0.4172 0.1328 0.0690 0.0499 0.0229B2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0004 0.0003 0.0001 0.0014 0.0030 0.0005 0.0030 0.0036 0.0078 0.0223 0.1108 -0.4770 0.1359 0.1390 0.0485B3 0.0000 0.0000 0.0011 -0.0001 0.0005 0.0010 0.0008 0.0015 0.0013 0.0017 0.0006 0.0042 0.0056 0.0484 0.0892 -0.5199 0.2665 0.0976Caa1 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0005 0.0003 0.0032 0.0000 0.0052 0.0084 0.0118 0.0697 -0.3396 0.2400D 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Page 33: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

31

Table 9: Simulated Call Spreads This summarizes Figure 2.

Real world Transition Risk-neutral world Transition

Grades Default premium Call spread

Default Premium Call spread

Investment 39 56 (53) 56 56 (54)

Speculative 342 55 (44) 693 92 (49)

Page 34: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

32

Table 10-1: One-year migration matrix for simulation Typical G 1 G 2 G 3 G 4 DG 1 0.8179 0.1589 0.0163 0.0012 0.0057G 2 0.0349 0.7534 0.1759 0.0205 0.0153G 3 0.0004 0.0183 0.7003 0.2172 0.0638G 4 0 0.0001 0.0053 0.871 0.1236D 0 0 0 0 1 Good G 1 G 2 G 3 G 4 DG 1 0.8179 0.1589 0.0164 0.0012 0.0057G 2 0.0353 0.754 0.1765 0.0186 0.0156G 3 0.0064 0.0274 0.71 0.1879 0.0683G 4 0.0598 0.0915 0.1019 0.5821 0.1647D 0 0 0 0 1 Table 10-2: Generator matrix for simulation

Typical G1 G2 G3 G4 D

G1 -0.205 0.2 0.0000 0 0.005G2 0.04 -0.26 0.21 0 0.01G3 0 0.02 -0.29 0.22 0.05G4 0 0 0.005 -0.105 0.1D 0 0 0 0 0

Good G1 G2 G3 G4 D

G1 -0.205 0.2 0.0000 0 0.005G2 0.04 -0.26 0.21 0 0.01G3 0 0.02 -0.29 0.22 0.05G4 0.06 0.09 0.1 -0.4 0.15D 0 0 0 0 0

Page 35: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

33

Table 11-1: One-year migration matrix for simulation

Typical G1 G2 G3 G4 D

G1 0.8179 0.1589 0.0164 0.0012 0.0057G2 0.0349 0.7534 0.1765 0.0197 0.0155G3 0.0004 0.0194 0.71 0.2045 0.0658G4 0.0002 0.0112 0.1017 0.7441 0.1427D 0 0 0 0 1

Good G 1 G 2 G 3 G 4 D

G 1 0.8179 0.1589 0.0164 0.0012 0.0057G 2 0.0353 0.754 0.1765 0.0186 0.0156G 3 0.0064 0.0274 0.71 0.1879 0.0683G 4 0.0598 0.0915 0.1019 0.5821 0.1647D 0 0 0 0 1

Table 11-2: Generator matrix for simulation

Typical G1 G2 G3 G4 D

G1 -0.205 0.2 0 0 0.005G2 0.04 -0.26 0.21 0 0.01G3 0 0.02 -0.29 0.22 0.05G4 0 0.01 0.1 -0.23 0.12D 0 0 0 0 0

Good G1 G2 G3 G4 D

G1 -0.205 0.2 0 0 0.005G2 0.04 -0.26 0.21 0 0.01G3 0 0.02 -0.29 0.22 0.05G4 0.06 0.09 0.1 -0.4 0.15D 0 0 0 0 0

Page 36: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

34

Fig 1: Yield curves This plots yields vs maturities of bonds as of the last business day of December 1998, available from the Fixed Income Securities Data (FISD), provided by Mergent, Inc. The yields are a combination of trader quotes and matrix quotes (predominantly trader quotes). The legend T stands for Treasury bonds, and other legends are moody’s ratings.

Rating OBS Mean STD

Treasury T 66 5.7759 0.1191

Aaa 48 6.2531 0.1499

Aa 196 6.2581 0.2465

A 666 6.4097 0.1936

Investment Grades Baa 522 6.6603 0.2635

Ba 297 8.0283 0.8683

B 833 9.3677 1.2148

Speculative Grades C 86 11.6089 2.2503

Figure 1 is summarized in the table.

Page 37: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

35

Fig 2: Simulated Call spreads The call spreads in the top figure are generated by using the Table7-b one-year generator matrix associated with Π = Ι. In the bottom figure the diagonal elements in Π increases by 0.06 for each lowering bond grade. Bond grade 0 means default-free grade and the numbers for grades are associated with the grade numbering in Table 1.

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 1640

45

50

55

60

65

70Par Yields

Bond Grades

Bas

is points

Call spreadZ spread-OAS

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 1620

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180Par Yields

Bond Grades

Bas

is points

Call spreadZ spread-OAS

Page 38: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

36

Fig 3-1: Call spreads with migration matrix faced by “typical” firm (Case 1)

0 1 2 3 410

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18Par Yields

Bond Grade

Par

Yie

lds

(%)

Non callableCallable

0 1 2 3 48.5

9

9.5

10

10.5

11

11.5

12

12.5

13

13.5Call Spreads

Bond Grade

Spr

eads

(bas

is p

oint

)

Call - NoncallableZ spread - OAS

Fig 3-2: Call spreads with migration matrix faced by “Good” firm (Case 1)

0 1 2 3 410

12

14

16

18

20Par Yields

Bond Grade

Par

Yie

lds

(%)

Non callableCallable

0 1 2 3 40

20

40

60

80

100

120Call Spreads

Bond Grade

Spr

eads

(bas

is p

oint

)

Call - Non-callZ spread - OAS

Page 39: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

37

Fig 3-3: Signaling benefits and costs (Case 1)

Grade 3 Grade 416

16.5

17

17.5

18

18.5

19

Callable Yield (Typical)Noncallable Yield (Typical)Non-callable Yield (Good)Callable Yield (Good)

CB

AD

Page 40: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

38

Fig 4-1: Call spreads with migration matrix faced by “typical” firm (Case 2)

0 1 2 3 410

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19Par Yields

Bond Grade

Par

Yie

lds

(%)

Non callableCallable

0 1 2 3 45

10

15

20

25

30

35

40Call Spreads

Bond Grade

Spr

eads

(bas

is p

oint

)

Call - NoncallableZ spread - OAS

Figure 4-2: Signaling benefits and costs (Case 2)

Grade 416

16.5

17

17.5

18

18.5

19

Bond Grade

Par

Yie

ld (%

)

Callable Yield (Typical)Noncallable Yield (Typical)Noncallable Yield (Good)Callable Yield (Good)

DA

C

B

Page 41: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

39

Reference Altman, Brady, Resti and Sironi, 2005, “The link between Default and Recovery Rates: Theory, Empirical evidence, and Implications,” Journal of Business, vol. 78 no. 6 2203-2227 Asquith, P. and D. Mullins, 1986, Equity issues and offering dilution, Journal of

Financial Economics 15, 61-89. Barnea, A., Haugen, R., Senbet, L., 1980, “A rationale for debt maturity structure and call

provisions in the agency theoretic framework,” Journal of Finance 35, 1223-1234. Bodie, Z., Taggart, R., Jr., 1978, “Future investment opportunities and the value of the

call provision on a bond,” Journal of Finance 33, 1187-1200. Brown, S. and J. Warner, 1985, Using daily stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 14, 3-31. Chen, Z., C. Mao and Y. Wang, 2007, “Why Firms Issue Callable Bonds: Hedging Investment Uncertainty,” Temple University, Working paper. Crabbe, L., Helwege, J., 1994. Alternative tests of agency theories of callable corporate bonds. Financial Management 23, 3-20. Duffie, Darrell and Kenneth J. Singleton, 1999 “Modeling Term Structures of

Defaultable Bonds” The Review of Financial Studies 12, 687-720 Eckbo, B. E., 1986, Valuation effects of corporate debt offerings, Journal of Financial

Economics 15, 119-151. Guntay, L., Prabhala, N., Unal, H., 2004 “Callable bonds, interest-rate risk, and the

supply side of hedging,” University of Maryland Finance Working Paper, July 2004.

Hull, J., M. Predescu, and A. White, 2005 “The Relationship Between Credit Default

Swap Spreads, Bond Yields, and Credit Rating Announcements” Journal of Banking and Finance.

Jarrow, Robert A. and S. M. Turnbull, 1995,”Pricing Derivatives on Financial Securities

Subject to Credit Risk,” Journal of Finance, Vol L, No. 1, 53-85 Jarrow, Roberet A., David Lando, and Stuart M. Turnbull, 1997, “A Markov Model for

the Term Structure of Credit Risk Spreads”, The Review of Financial Studies 10, 481- 523

Page 42: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

40

Jarrow, Robert A., Haitao Li, Sheen Liu, and Chunch Wu, 2006 ,”Reduced-form Valuation of Callable Corporate bonds: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming . Jensen, M., Meckling, W., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360. Kim, Seoyoung, April Klein and James Rosenfeld, 2008, “Return Performance Surrounding Reverse Stock Splits: Can Investors Profit?”, Financial management, Summer, 173-192 King, T.-H., Mauer, D., 2000. Corporate call policy for nonconvertible bonds. Journal of Business 73,403-444. Kish, R. and Livington, M., 1992. Determinants of the call option on corporate bonds. Journal of Banking & Finance 16, 687-703. Lando and Skodeberg, 2002, “Analyzing Rating Transitions and rating Drift with Continuous Observations,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 423-444 Lewis, C.M., R.J. Rogalski, and J.K. Seward, 1999, Is convertible debt a substitute for

straight debt or for common equity? Financial Management 28(3), 5-27. Longstaff, Mithal and Neis, 2005, “Corporate Yield Spreads: Default Risk or Liquidity? New Evidence from the Credit-Default Swap Market,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 60, No. 5, 2213-2254 Mikkelson, W. H. and M. M. Partch, 1986, Valuation effects of security offerings and the

issuance process, Journal of Financial Economics 15, 31-60. Myer, S. and N. Majluf, 1984, Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms

have information that investors do not have, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.

Moody’s Investors Service, 2005, “Default and Recovery rates of Corporate Bond Issuers,

1920-2004, Speacil Comment, Global Credit Research Myers, S., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5,

147-175. Nayer, Nandu and Duane Stock, 2008, “Make-whole Call Provisions: A Case of much ado about nothing?” Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 387-404 Pye, G., 1966. The value of the call option on a bond. Journal of Political Economy 74,

200-205.

Page 43: Seungmook Choi University of Nevada, Las Vegas Kookmin … The... · 2017. 1. 31. · JLT approach to simulate the behavior of callable bonds given various assumptions about the underlying

41

Robbins, E., Schatzberg, J., 1986, “Callable bonds: a risk-reducing signaling

mechanism,” Journal of Finance 41, 935-949. Robbins, E., Schatzberg, J., 1988, “Callable bonds: a risk-reducing signaling mechanism-

-a reply,” Journal of Finance 43, 1067-1073. Tsuji, Chikashi, 2005, “The Credit Spread Puzzle,”, Journal of International Money and

Finance, 24, 1073-1089 Vu, J., 1986. “An empirical investigation of calls of non-convertible bonds,” Journal of

Financial Economics, 16, 235-265.