small farms negative

Upload: olddirtyclaire

Post on 14-Apr-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    1/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Small Farms Negative

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    2/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    ***Impact Statement CP***

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    3/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    1NC HR-E-IS Counter-Plan

    The President of the United States federal government should issue an executive order requiring

    a global assessment of the human rights and environmental impact of free trade agreements,including a periodic assessment of trade agreements already in place. The United States federal

    government should require a release of this information to the public during and before the

    finalization of the negotiation process.

    The Counter-Plan solves the AFF

    +Increases accountability in FTAs

    +Assesses INTERNATIONAL environmental and human rights impacts

    +Guarantees public participation in free trade negotiations

    Gonzalez 11 Carmen G. Gonzalez. Associate Professor, Seattle University School of Law. AN

    ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE CRITIQUE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: INDIGENOUS PEOPLES, TRADE

    POLICY, AND THE MEXICAN NEOLIBERAL ECONOMIC REFORMS. University of Pennsylvania Journal of

    International Law. 32 U. Pa. J. Int'l L. 723. Spring, 2011. Accessed Via L.N.

    As the NAFTA case study illustrates, trade liberalization based on comparative advantage often results in serious hu-man rights violations and

    environmental harm because market prices fail to [*790] reflect environmental and social externalities and because the

    communities most affected by trade reforms are not consulted. One legal reform that would facilitate the early identification

    and mitigation of such externalities is legislation requiring ex ante environmen-tal and human rights impact assessment of

    all trade agreements. This assessment should take place as early as possible in the negotiation process, and should be conducted

    in a transparent manner that involves extensive public participation and consultation. Environmental impact assessment emerged as aregulatory tool in the United States with the passage of the National Environmental Policy Act of 1969, n319 and has since been adopted by most countries and by

    international organizations. n320 The objectives of the assessment process are two-fold: to ensure that the possible impacts of a

    proposed project are assessed before a final decision is made; and to inform the public and solicit meaningful public

    input on the costs and benefits of proceeding with the project . n321

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    4/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NCSolvency ExtNAFTA Specific

    The Counter-Plan leads to the reforms necessary to solve EVERY impact NAFTA has on rural

    populations INCLUDING the environmental damage of industrial corn productionGonzalez 11 Carmen G. Gonzalez. Associate Professor, Seattle University School of Law. AN

    ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE CRITIQUE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: INDIGENOUS PEOPLES, TRADE

    POLICY, AND THE MEXICAN NEOLIBERAL ECONOMIC REFORMS. University of Pennsylvania Journal of

    International Law. 32 U. Pa. J. Int'l L. 723. Spring, 2011. Accessed Via L.N.

    In the case of NAFTA, for example, analysis and public disclosure of the negative externalities associated with in-dustrial [*793]

    corn production in the United States and of the positive externalities associated with traditional corn cultivation in Mexico

    might generate public pressure for regulatory reform or some form of financial compensation . Industrial corn production in the

    United States contributes to a wide range of environmental and human health prob-lems, including water pollution, water scarcity, biodiversity loss,

    climate change, pesticide poisoning, and a growing epidemic o f obesity and Type II diabetes due to the presence of high fructose corn syrup in numerous food products. n336 In Mexico,

    by contrast, the biodiverse cultivation techniques of indigenous and rural communities provide positive environmental and

    social externalities. If these issues are discussed in public hearings in Mexico and the United States, it may be possible to create the

    interest convergence necessary to overcome the economic power of agribusiness and to achieve genuine

    reform.Regulatory reform in the United States could involve amending the statutes that currently exempt all but the largest farms

    from the nation's environmental laws or redirecting subsidies away from industrial agriculture and toward healthier and more sustainab le farming practices. n337

    Regulatory reform in Mexico might involve rewarding small farmers for the positive social and environmental

    contributions of traditional corn production by providing payments for ecosystem services. These payments could be funded by tariffs onU.S. corn or by direct payments from the United States for the protection of rural livelihoods and for the conservation of a public good of global significance - Mexico's genetic diversity. n338

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    5/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NCSolvency ExtLaundry List

    Status quo EIS is insufficientReforming the past executive order on this issue is key to assess

    international impacts on human rights, poverty, the environment, and minority populationsGonzalez 11 Carmen G. Gonzalez. Associate Professor, Seattle University School of Law. AN

    ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE CRITIQUE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: INDIGENOUS PEOPLES, TRADE

    POLICY, AND THE MEXICAN NEOLIBERAL ECONOMIC REFORMS. University of Pennsylvania Journal of

    International Law. 32 U. Pa. J. Int'l L. 723. Spring, 2011. Accessed Via L.N.

    In the United States, Executive Order 13,141 (1999) already requires the environmental review of trade agreements. n322 However, the executive order falls

    short of achieving environmental justice in numerous respects. First, while review of environmental impacts in the United States is mandatory,

    review of global and transboundary impacts is discretionary. n323 Second, the executive order does not require the review of

    the human rights impact of trade agreements. n324 Third, the executive order does not provide for the periodic assessment

    of trade agreements already in place. n325 Fourth, the executive order fails to prescribe the timing of the environmental review and does not

    require the [*791] release of information to the public beyond the draft environmental review and the scope of the

    negotiation. n326 Without access to draft negotiating texts, meaningful public participation is difficult to achieve. Moreover, in the absence of specific

    guidance on the timing of the review, there is a danger that the review will be performed too late in the process to permit

    significant public input and consideration of alternatives, including the no-action alternative. n327 Fifth, while the executive orderdoes require that environmental reviews be "made available in draft form for public comment," n328 there is no mechanism to ensure that public comments are taken

    into account - such as requiring agency response to public comments. n329 Sixth, the executive order does not require the disaggregation of

    impacts according to race, gender, ethnic origin, geographic region, or other variables. In order to determine whether trade

    agreements will impose a disproportionate burden on specific segments of the population, disaggregation of data is

    essential. Seventh, the executive order does not create a private right of action in case its terms are violated. n330 Finally, the executive order does not make

    reference to Executive Order 12,898, issued five years earlier, which requires all federal agencies to make environmental justice part of their missions. n331 Executive

    Order 12,898 inexplicably excludes the United States Trade Representative and the State Department from the interagency working group charged with its

    implementation. n332 In order to foster environmental justice at the international level, it [*792] is essential to include

    environmental justice in the mission of these government agencies and to involve them in the interagency dialogue over

    the implementation of this mission.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    6/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NCSolvency ExtPublic Participations Key

    Public participation is key to ensure the most affected populations have a voice in the negotiation

    processGonzalez 11 Carmen G. Gonzalez. Associate Professor, Seattle University School of Law. AN

    ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE CRITIQUE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: INDIGENOUS PEOPLES, TRADE

    POLICY, AND THE MEXICAN NEOLIBERAL ECONOMIC REFORMS. University of Pennsylvania Journal of

    International Law. 32 U. Pa. J. Int'l L. 723. Spring, 2011. Accessed Via L.N.

    Despite the limitations of Executive Order 13,141, ex ante environmental and human rights impact assessments, if

    properly designed, have the potential to provide decision-makers and the public with valuable information about the

    environmental and human rights impacts of trade agreements, to prevent the "capture" of the negotiation process by

    commercial interests, to enhance government accountability, to create a forum for public input, and to democratize trade

    policy by fostering informed and reasoned debate. n333 The participation of rural and indigenous communities in the

    impact assessment process is vitally important so that the assessment will be informed by the knowledge and

    experience of those most affected by agricultural trade policy . Such participation also yields trade agreements that are

    perceived as more legitimate because they are the product of an inclusive political process.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    7/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NCSolvency ExtPeriodic Assessment Key

    Requiring a periodic assessment of FTAs ensures long-term impact of agreements arent

    ignoredGonzalez 11 Carmen G. Gonzalez. Associate Professor, Seattle University School of Law. AN

    ENVIRONMENTAL JUSTICE CRITIQUE OF COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE: INDIGENOUS PEOPLES, TRADE

    POLICY, AND THE MEXICAN NEOLIBERAL ECONOMIC REFORMS. University ofPennsylvania Journal of

    International Law. 32 U. Pa. J. Int'l L. 723. Spring, 2011. Accessed Via L.N.

    In addition, it would be advisable to require periodic ex post environmental and human rights impact assessments of trade

    agreements several years after their entry into force and to include "sunset clauses" in trade agreements akin to Article 20 of the

    WTO Agreement on Agriculture n334 so as to require renegotiation of trade agreements in light of these ex post impact assessments. n335 The periodic

    assessment and revision of trade agreements will enable decision-makers and the public to identify the long-term and

    indirect impacts of trade agreements and to make sure that these agreements are continuously revised and improved in

    order to promote human rights and environmental protection.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    8/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NCXO Doesnt Link to Politics

    Executive orders solve for the case and avoid Congressional backlash to the policy

    Fleishman , Prof of Law and Policy Sciences and Director of the Institute of Policy Sciences and Public Affairs @Duke ,1976, (Joel L., and Arthur H. Aufses, Research Associate @ Institute of Public Sciences @ Duke, Law and

    Orders: The problem of presidential legislation, Law and Contemporary Problems, Vo. 40, No. 3, pg. 38)

    Several related factors, in particular, make executive orders especially attractive policymaking tools for a President. First isspeed. Even if a President is reasonably confident of securing desired legislation from Congress, he must wait forcongressional deliberations to run their course. Invariably, he can achieve far faster, if not immediate, results by issuing anexecutive order. Moreover, when a President acts through an order, he avoids having to subject his policy to publicscrutiny and debate. Second is flexibility. Executive orders have the force of law. Yet they differ from congressionallegislation in that a President can alter any executive order simply with the stroke of his penmerely by issuing anotherexecutive order. As noted earlier, Presidents have developed the system of classifying national security documents in precisely this manner.209 Finallyexecutive orders allow the President, not only to evade hardened congressional opposition, but also to preempt potential or

    growing oppositionto throw Congress off balance, to reduce its ability to formulate a powerful opposing position.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    9/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    ***Movements Turns***

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    10/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    1NC Movements Disad

    Allowing current bottom up movements to take shape is key to eliminating neoliberalisms hold

    on the regionThe plan is counter-productive and pacifying.Roberts 9. Kenneth Roberts. Professor of Government @ Cornell. Beyond Neoliberalism in Latin America? 2009 pg

    1-7

    In recent years voters in Latin America have elected a series of left-of-center presidents, starting with Venezuela in 1998 and continuing (to date) with Chile,Brazil, Argentina, Uruguay, Bolivia, Nicaragua, Ecuador, and Paraguay. Although this political "left turn" has bypassed a number of countries, and the new

    governments that are part of it comprise a remarkably heterogeneous lot, there seems little doubt that the political winds have shifted in the region. Theturn to the left has followed a decade-and-a-half of free market or "neoliberal" reform, when technocrats throughout the region-with staunch support from the U.S.

    government and international financial institutions-forged a powerful policymaking consensus around the virtues of free trade, deregulated markets, and private

    entrepreneurship. Since it is not clear whether the region's new leftist governments have identified, much less consolidated, viable alternatives to market liberalism, it is

    far too early to claim that Latin America has entered a post-neoliberal era of development. What is clear, however, is that the shift to the left signals a

    "repoliticization" of development issues in Latin America-that is, a demise of the "Washington Consensus" (Williamson 1990)

    for free market capitalism and the onset of a highly contested search for alternatives that lie " beyond neoliberalism ." Inshort, Latin America is no longer (if it ever was) suspended at "the end of politics" (Colburn 2002), where technocratic consensus is complemented (or secured) by a

    combination of social demobilization, political resignation, and mass consumerism. The repoliticization of development has both policy and process dimensions

    On the policy front, it signifies that neoliberalism is no longer the only game in town; although predefined socialist alternatives to capitalism

    have long since evaporated, vigorous debates have emerged around non-neoliberal "varieties of capitalism" that envision a more

    active role for state power in asserting national autonomy, shaping investment priorities, ameliorating inequalities, and

    providing social services and other public goods. In terms of process, repoliticization entails the emergence or revival of popular subjectivities that arecontesting the technocratic monopolization of policymaking space-in some cases at the ballot box, in others on the streets. Repoliticization, therefore, involves a

    reciprocal interaction between the rise of new actors and an expansion of the issue agenda to include a broader range of alternatives. This book tries to make sense of

    these new subjectivities-that is, to identify some of Latin America's new social and political actors and to explain the origins, inspirations, and interests that lie behind

    their activation. In contrast to much of the emerging work on Latin America's left turn, we look beyond the rise of left-leaning governments and their policy choices to

    focus attention on the socioeconomic and cultural terrain in which new political options are being forged. Individual chapters thus explore how neoliberalism has

    shaped and constrained popular subjects by breaking down some traditional actors, transforming others, and providing a stimulus for the emergence of new ones-at leastsome of which bear the seeds of potential social orders beyond neoliberalism. Our approach starts with the recognition that neoliberal "structural adjustment" programs

    represented much more than a simple change in development policies. By slashing tariffs and other trade barriers, privatizing state-owned

    enterprises and social services, and deregulating markets to encourage the free flow of capital, neoliberal reforms

    realigned existing relationships among states, markets, and societies in fundamental ways (Garret6n 2003a). As such, they transformedthe social, political, and cultural landscapes that had developed during the mid-twentieth-century era of state-led import-substitution industrialization (ISI). Initially, this

    meant breaking down the popular collective subjects of the lSI era-in particular, organized labor and labor-based parties-and imposing market discipline over everlarger

    swaths of social life. As labor unions weakened, however,new popular subjects, such as community-based organizations and

    indigenous movements, that rejected the insecurities of market individualism and its commodification of social relationshipsbegan to emerge. Theirdiverse attempts to reweave the social fabric are the primary focus of this volume. The essays included here trace many of the contours of this rapidly evolving,

    neoliberal social and political landscape. Collectively, the essays explore three basic sets of questions. First, what are the new patterns of social interaction generated by

    the process of market restructuring, and how do these reshape the ways in which societal interests and identities are articulated, organized, and represented in the

    political arena? Interests and identities are often redefined as market reforms create new economic niches (or destroy old ones), commodify social relationships, alter

    traditional uses of land, water, or natural resources, and shift the scale or locus of public policymaking. Second, what new social and political actors have emerged, and

    how do they respond to the multifaceted changes associated with market restructuring? Traditional actors may enter into decline, but new ones invariably arise; we must

    ask, then, how these new actors are constituted, how they adapt to market opportunities and insecurities, and what strategies they follow when they try to enter the

    political arena, redefine the policy agenda, and contest public authority. Third, and finally, to what extent do these actors and their responses provide the building block

    for new paths of social, economic, and political development that might be more equitable and inclusive than those that have characterized the neoliberal era? What

    lies "beyond neoliberalism" is unlikely to be determined by grand ideological visions or political blueprints ; instead, it

    will be constructed piece by piece, from below, through the grassroots participation and decentralized experimentation of

    new popular subjects. This volume offers no simple answers to these complex questions, much less a new theory of neoliberal politics. Instead, it offers a series

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    11/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    of portraits written from a variety of disciplinary perspectives about how people adapt and respond-both individually and collectively-when their economic moorings

    shift and the social fabric is torn asunder. These portraits are hardly comprehensive; they do not cover every country in Latin America, much less all the stations in the

    region's heterogeneous and fragmented sociocultural landscape. The editors do not claim that the particular set of actors and issues included in this volume is the best or

    the only one that could have been chosen. Nevertheless, we have selected topics based on their importance and the quality of research they have generated, and we

    believe our portraits jointly illuminate the diverse experiences of social actors during the neoliberal era. These portraits provide compelling evidence that capitalism is,

    as Schumpeter (1950) aptly characterized it, a force of "creative destruction" that simultaneously breaks down and reconfigures various fields of social interaction. Our

    chapters are replete with examples of the dialectical interplay between capitalism's advance and the social, cultural, and political responses it elicits-though not, as will

    become evident, in the manner classically envisioned by Marx. These responses, whether deliberate or reactive,bear the seeds of what may in fact

    lie beyond neoliberalism, a horizon that remains opaque but is increasingly being sketched by a diverse array of popular

    movements in the region. As explained later, the various dimensions of this dialectical interplay lie beyond the scope of any single academic discipline,making an interdisciplinary approach vital to a more comprehensive understanding. An Integral Approach to Economic Reform, Social Change, and Political Response

    Social and political changes in Latin America have long been conditioned by patterns of economic development. This can be seen, for example, in the nineteenth-

    century association between oligarchic politics and agro-export development models, or in the rise of populist social and

    political mobilization during the early stages of industrialization in the middle of the twentieth lower class groups. Thesedemands were typically funneled through the corporatist intermediary channels of mass party and union organizations, which brokered exchanges between states and

    organized societal interests. In short, lSI encouraged groups-defined primarily in terms of class categories-to self-organize in order to advance their interests in a

    policymaking environment where states increasingly penetrated and regulated social and economic relationships, including labor markets and land tenure arrangements

    Together, these two processes encouraged strong labor and, in some cases, peasant movements to develop, which in turn provided a social foundation for Latin

    America's first mass party organizations. The social, cultural, and political construction of popular subjects during the lSI era was

    thus anchored in the favorable combination of rapid industrialization , state interventionism, and social reform.

    These linkages between state-led industrialization and grassroots organization were frayed, however, by economic

    pressures and political polarization in the 1960s and 1970s (O'Donnell 1973), and they were largely severed by the debt crisis

    of the 1980s. While neoliberal structural adjustment policies helped restore economic stability in the aftermath of the debt

    crisis, they exacerbated-indeed, they often institutionalized-the social dislocations wrought by the crisis itself. Changes in labormarkets-in particular growing informalization, a greater reliance on subcontracting and temporary labor, and flexible rules for hiring and firing-made collective action

    in the workplace increasingly difficult to sustain, leading to a sharp decline in trade union density in most of the region. Likewise, the parcelization of landholdings and

    the penetration of market relations in the countryside undermined historic patterns of peasant mobilization for land reform in much of the region (Kurtz 2004). The

    retreat of the state subjected new sectors of the economy and society to market discipline, undermining the rationale and effectiveness of collective action aimed at

    eliciting state redress . Historic labor-based parties entered into decline or adapted in part by distancing themselves from labor and other organized mass constituencies.

    This trend that was propelled both by the structural conditions of neoliberal capitalism and by technological advances inpolitical communication (most prominently, television) that rendered mass party organizations increasingly dispensable

    for electoral mobilization. Following the restoration of democratic rule in most of Latin America in the 1980s, U.S.-style media-based advertising andcampaign tactics diffused rapidly across the region, allowing candidates to appeal directly to voters without the mediation of mass membership party organizations.

    Latin America entered the new millennium, then, largely devoid of the mass social and party organizations that dominated the landscape during the populist/lSI era.

    Labor movements had been downsized and politically marginalized, and they were less capable of representing the diverse interests and identities of a precarious and in

    formalized workforce. Likewise, where they survived at all, mass parties were transformed into professionalized or patronage-based electoral machines (see, e.g.,

    Levitsky 2003); elsewhere, they were displaced by independent personalities and populist outsiders. The dominant trends pointed toward a fragmentation and

    pluralization of civil society-with a multitude of interests, identities, and decentralized groups struggling to make their voices heard (Ox horn 1998a)-and a

    deinstitutionalization of political representation, as evidenced by extreme levels of electoral volatility and the rise of personality-based, antiparty candidates. A

    bottom-up perspective is thus essential to understand how the demise of lSI and the transition to neoliberalism realigned the

    social landscape in ways that disarticulated the class-based popular subjects of the lSI era. Such a perspective is also essential, however, for

    explaining popular responses to market liberalization and the openings that eventually emerged for the construction of new types of collective subjects that bear theseeds of what may lie beyond neoliberalism.Neoliberal reforms are directed-indeed, often imposed-by state officials in collaboration

    with (or under the pressure of) transnational power centers, but civil society and grassroots actors are hardly passive bystanders(Arce 2005). These actors invariably seek to exploit, resist, evade, or cope with state initiatives, and their responses often produce outcomes that are quite different from

    those envisioned by policymakers and economic elites. In particular, grassroots actors employ a variety of measures to alleviate material hardships and reduce exposure

    to market insecurities; as Karl Polanyi (1944) argues, there are social and political limits to the commodification of social relationships, and these limits may be quickly

    breached in contexts of egregious inequalities such as those prevailing in contemporary Latin America. Popular responses thus attempt to reweave a social fabric torn

    by economic crisis and market dislocation. These responses are often local, decentralized, and territorially based, building on

    traditions of communitybased organizing, or focused on ethnic and cultural claims rather than the class/corporatist

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    12/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    patterns of interest representation that were hallmarks of the lSI era. Although new popular subjects may not initially target public

    authorities or policymaking arenas, grassroots activism often becomes politicized over time, posing the formidable

    challenge analyzed by Benjamin Goldfrank in chapter three-that of translating local initiatives into nationallevel political

    alternatives. This challenge highlights the importance of a bottom-up perspective in the construction of new popular subjects in the neoliberal era. The primary

    objectives of this volume, then, are to develop an interdisciplinary perspective on the multiple forms of societal responses to market liberalization and to assess theireffects. We do this in four principal fields where neoliberalism has altered the social landscape: electoral politics, ethnic mobilization, environmental governance,

    transnational migration. In each area we explore new patterns of social interaction, identify various responses, and analyze the potential impact of emerging popular

    subjects.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    13/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NC Link ExtensionsMexico

    Government intervention pacifies movements

    Fox & Hernndez 92 Jonathan Fox and Luis Hernndez. Mexico's Difficult Democracy: Grassroots Movements,NGOs, and Local Government. Global, Local, Political , Vol. 17, No. 2 (Spring 1992), pp. 165-208 Published by: Sage

    Publications, Inc. http://www.jstor.org/stable/40644738.[KY]Most social organizations, such as trade unions, peasant organizations, or business associations, have long been controlled by the government. Membership is often

    obligatory, and the leadership is chosen from above. Many different social groups have challenged this official monopoly on

    representation over the last few decades with mixed results. The central state's capacity to control local political and social life has

    always been uneven, but the Mexican state has retained near-total control over the channels that linked it to civil society at the national level- even in the late 1980s. Among the many diverse groups that make up Mexican society, only the Catholic church succeeded in sustaining a powerful, autonomous

    national organization.4 The secret ofthe Mexican state's "success" is its skillful combination of "carrots and sticks." Government

    responses to popular movements for social reform and democracy have typically combinedpartial concessions with

    repression, conditioning access to material gains on political subordination. The state does not always wait to be pressured; its remarkable

    capacity for preemptive measures continues to surprise seasoned observers. One cannot understand Mexico's long-standing relativepolitical stability without looking at both sides of the coin. The state occasionally does give in to some people, some of the time, and usually

    with strings attached. Some of Mexico's rulers specialize in such bargaining, but they operate in the shadow of their colleagues' capacity for fiercerepression in case the negotiations break down. This camouflage is a key component of what noted writer Mario Vargas Llosa called "the perfect dictatorship."5

    http://www.jstor.org/stable/40644738http://www.jstor.org/stable/40644738
  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    14/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    2NC Link ExtensionsLatin America

    US Aid stops reform movementsEmpirics prove

    Dillon 89 Sam Dillon. (Mr. Dillon attended the University of Chicago and received a B.A. degree in history from theUniversity of Minnesota in 1979. He received an M.S. degree in journalism from the Columbia University Graduate

    School of Journalism in 1981.) Dateline El Salvador: Crisis Renewed. Foreign Policy , No. 73 (Winter, 1988-1989), pp.

    153-170. Published by: Washingtonpost.Newsweek Interactive, LLC. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1148882[KY]

    The Reagan administrationused the com- mission's report to fashion an emergency aid package; and when Jos6 Napole6n Duarte was elected

    El Salvador's president in 1984, a previously reluctant Congress approved it.The report recommended more than doubling military

    aid from the 1983 level; Congress complied with $343 million for 1984 and 1985. The report suggested that economic aid be doubled as well. Congress didnot double economic aid, but it did al locate $1.8 billion for the years 1984 through 1988, for a 35 per cent average annual increase over 1983. It has added up to a torrent of dollars averaging

    some $1.1 million per day since 1984. Wash- ington now finances more than one-half of the Salvadoran national budget. Because El

    Salvador was a society in general crisis, the Kissinger commission policy aimed not only at counterinsurgency victory but

    also at social reform, economic revival, and democ- ratization. Although several initiatives ap- peared in conflict--reforming society, liberal-

    izing the economy, and empowering civilians while strengthening the military, and building democracy while waging

    war-the commis- sion sought to reconcile these contradictions with a call to maintain equilibrium among them. For example, the commission wrote:"Vigorous, concurrent policies on both the milita ry and human rights fronts are need- ed.... Policies of increased aid and increased pressure to safeguard human rights would improve both

    security and justice. A slacken- ing on one front would undermine our objec- t ive on the other." 154. In El Salvador, however, the Reagan admin- istration made

    the war its unhesitating priori- ty. The administration's slackening on other fronts has undermined the overall policy, just as

    the commission predicted. The guerrillas have been contained militarily, but the insur- gency's causes have gone largely unaddressed. Despite the impressive amount

    of aid, human misery has increased. American diplomats in El Salvador have urged an end to human rights abuses, but Washington has

    backed their message only feebly. Political killings, which have declined from the early 1980s, are again on the rise. In addition, American officials s ince 1985 haveroutinely criticized the 1980 land and banking reforms as econom- ically unsound, even though the commission's report supported such reforms as necessary moves toward social justice. This

    is not to say that U.S. policy has borne no fruit. Since 1982 El Salvador has conducted five relatively honest national elections after more

    than a decade of frauds. The military has resisted numerous right-wing calls for coups, and the power of the civilian

    presidency, though still circumscribed by the military, has grown. Duarte has opened space for leftist political opposition.

    http://www.jstor.org/stable/1148882http://www.jstor.org/stable/1148882
  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    15/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    ***NEG Environmental Justice Answers**

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    16/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Risk Assessment Sound

    Commodification arguments are wrong---Economic analysis is the only way to prevent extinction

    Wagner 11Gernot, economist at EDF, where he works in the office of economic policy and analysis, But Will thePlanet Notice? How Smart Economics Can Save the World. Hill and Wang Press, p. 11-12

    The fundamental forces guiding thebehavior of billions are much larger than any one ofus. It's about changing our system,

    creating a new business as usual. And to do that we need to think about what makes our system run. In the end, it comes down to

    markets, and the rules of the game that govern what we chase and how we chase it. Scientists can tell us how bad it will get. Activi sts can make us pay attention to the ensuing instabilities

    and make politicians take note. When the task comes to formulating policy, only economists can help guide us out of this morass and

    save the planet . In an earlier time with simpler problems, environmentalists took direct action against the market's brutal forces by

    erecting roadblocks or chaining themselves to trees. That works if the opposing force is a lumberjack with a chain saw. It might even work for an entire industry

    when the task is to ban a particular chemical or scrub a pollutant out of smokestacks. But that model breaks down when

    the opposing force is ourselves: each and every one of us demanding that the globalized market provide us with cheaper and better food, clothes, and vacations. There is

    no blocking the full, collective desires of the billions who are now part of the market economy and the billions more who want toand

    ought tobe part of it. The only solution is to guide all-powerful market forces in the right direction and create incentives for

    each of us to make choices that workfor all of us. The guideposts we have today for market forces evolved helter- skelterfrom a

    historical process that gave almost no weight to the survival of the planet, largelybecause the survival of the planet was not at stake .

    Now it is . Since we can't live without market forces, we need to guide them to help us keep the human adventure going

    in workable ways , rather than continue on the present path right off the edge of a cliff.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    17/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Forecasting Good

    The inherent unpredictability of social events is all the more reason for creating optimal

    resiliency through scenario planningCochrane 11 John H. Cochrane is a Professor of finance at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business and a

    contributor to Business Class "IN DEFENSE OF THE HEDGEHOGS" July 15 www.cato-unbound.org/2011/07/15/john-

    h-cochrane/in-defense-of-the-hedgehogs/

    Risk Management Rather than Forecast-and-Plan The answer is to change the question, to focus on risk management , as Gardner and

    Tetlock suggest. There is a set of events that could happen tomorrowChicago could have an earthquake, there could be a run on Greek

    debt, the Administration could decide Heavens, DoddFrank and Obamacare were huge mistakes, lets fix them (Okay, not the last one.) Attached to each

    event, there is some probability that it could happen.Now forecasting as Gardner and Tetlock characterize it, is an attempt to

    figure out which event really will happen, whether the coin will land on heads or tails, and then make a plan based on that knowledge.

    Its a fools game. Once we recognize that uncertainty will always remain, risk management rather than forecasting is

    much wiser. Just the step of naming the events that could happen is useful. Then, ask yourself, if this eventhappens, lets make sure we have a contingency plan so were not really screwed . Suppose youre counting on diesel generators to

    keep cooling water flowing through a reactor. What if someone forgets to fill the tank? The good use offorecasting is to get a better handle

    on probabilities, so we focus our risk management resources on the most important events. But we must still pay attention to events, and

    buy insurance against them, based as much on the painfulness of the event as on its probability. (Note to economics techies:

    what matters is the risk-neutral probability, probability weighted by marginal utility.) So its not really the forecast thats wrong, its what

    people do with it. If we all understood the essential unpredictability of the world, especially of rare and very costly events, if we got rid

    of the habit of mind that asks for a forecast and then makes plans as if that were the only state of the world that could o ccur; if we instead focused on

    laying out all the bad things that could happen and made sure we had insurance or contingency plans, both personal and

    public policies might be a lot better.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    18/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Pesticide Defense

    Pesticide Studies are Unscientific, Overblown, and UnprovenPrefer the ev because its from a

    toxicologistSolomon 01 (Dr. Keith, Professor of Environmental Biology at the University of Guelph and a Director for the Centre of

    Toxicology, writing in the Parry Sound Beacon Star, Pesticides are Safe: Proving the Improbable

    http://www.24d.org/newsarticles/Solomon-Parry-Sound-2001.pdf)As a scientist who practices the scientific method, I am, in part, to blame. As a scientist, I cannot offer absolute and irrefutable proof that pesticides are safe. All that

    science can do is say that one thing is more likely to happen and another, much more or much less likely, but never 100 percent for certain. No matter how

    well designed an experiment, no matter how many mice or fish are used, the scientist will always report the result with

    some uncertainty. This means that, even if there is no real effect of the substance on the liver, in some experiments a very small adverse effect will be seen,

    while in others, a non-adverse effect will occur. This is because of natural variability and random events. The average of all

    these is close to zero but for those who believe that an adverse effect should exist, the positive studies will

    be absolute proof. The scientific method, the test of the null hypothesis, is designed to keep scientists honest and detached from whatever their beliefs may be.No scientist is pleased to find that nothing is happening; it is much more exciting and satisfying to find interesting responses and effects. As was pointed out nearly four

    centuries ago by Francis Bacon, the father of the scientific method , it is human nature to diminish negative evidence and

    exaggerate the significance of positive evidence. Because of this, we tend to ignore the negative evidence and focus on the positive, evidencethat is, in the analogy described above, essentially anecdotal. Some people believe in ghosts, the paranormal and in visitations of aliens, despite the countless years of

    study that have failed to show any evidence in support of these phenomena. They do so because they choose to believe in anecdotal evidence. The media are

    of little help because the possibility that some facet of our daily life may cause injury or worse is the

    substance of headlines and increased circulation. This is a likely reason for the common misperception

    that pesticides cause all types of diseases in humans. As discussed above, a study may report an association (link) between pesticide use

    and a disease such as cancer in humans. However, one positive study does not prove a cause-and-effect between the pesticide

    use and disease. Only if most studies consistently show this linkage and other lines of evidence alsosupport the conclusion would this association be accepted as showing causality. Pesticides are one of many tools in pestmanagement toolbox. They may be more efficient than other methods, but they are not absolutely necessary. As someone who does not live in Halifax, or in other

    towns where bans have been proposed, I do not care one way or the other if they choose not to use pesticides. However, I do care when this is done in the name of

    science and concern for health effects when, realistically, these do not exist. If the town councils and the citizens do not want pesticides used in their homes and

    gardens, then all I ask is that they have the courage to admit that they do this for reasons of belief or politics, not on the basis of science.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    19/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Endocrine Distruption Defense

    Endocrine disruption is a mythit came from one study that had no evidence and was only

    believed because of media hypeGordon 97 (Peter, contributor to the Cato Institute, Endocrine Disruptors, Politics, Pesticides,

    http://www.ohiopma.org/pdfs/insight/ed/pub_id=6844.pdf )

    And find it, she did. She collected every paper that described any abnormality in wildlife that live on or around the Great Lakes

    and concluded that synthetic chemicals were mimicking the effects of hormones. They were causing every

    problem in the literature, whether it was homosexual behavior among gulls, crossed bills in other birds, cancer in fish, or increases or decreases in any

    wildlife population. The chemicals that have those activities were called "environmental estrogens" or "endocrine disrupters.

    There was no more evidence to link them to every abnormality in wildlife than there had been in the

    1960s to link every human cancer to chemicals. The absence of evidence wasn't much ofa problem. Colborn and

    her colleagues believed that chemicals were the culprit, and the press and much of the public, nutured on the idea that

    chemicals were bad, didn't require evidence. Even so, Colborn had a problem that EPA faced in its early days. Soon after EPA wasestablished, the agency leaders realized that protecting wildlife and the environment might be a good thing, but that Congress might not decide to lavish funds on such

    activities. They were sure, however, that Congress would throw money at programs that were going to protect

    human health from environmental risks.(3) Whether Colborn knew that history or not, she apparently realized that any real splash for endocrinedisrupters depended on tying them to human health effects. Using the same techniques she'd used to catalogue the adverse effects of endocrine disrupters on wildlife,

    she reviewed the literature about human health effects that someway or another might be related to disruption of hormone activity. The list was long, including cancers,

    birth defects, and learning disabilities, but the big hitter on the list was decreased sperm counts. According to Colborn and other's analyses of sperm counts made in

    different parts of the world under different conditions of nutrition and stress and at different time periods, sperm counts had decreased by 50 percent in the post-World

    War II period. If there's anything that catches the attention of Congress, it's risks to males. Congress banned leaded

    gasoline after EPA released a report that said atmospheric lead was a cause of heart attacks in middle-aged men . The reported decrease in sperm

    counts leaped up for attention, and attention it got. Congressional hearings were held, magazine articles were written, experts opined

    about endocrine disrupters and sexual dysfunctions. And then it fell apart. Scientists found large geographical variations in spermcounts that have not changed over time. Those geographical variations and poor study designs accounted

    for the reported decrease. That scare went away, but endocrine disrupters were here to stay.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    20/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Monoculture Defense

    Monoculture isnt more susceptible to disease wheat proves

    4ICSC, 2004(Fourth International Crop Science Congress, Wheat monoculture is sustainable, September 27,

    http://www.cropscience.org.au/icsc2004/a/media/cs040927_mono.htm)

    Cultivation of the same crop in the same field year after yeara practice called monoculturehas long been regarded as

    unsustainable because of declines in yields after about three years. The yield loss is generally attributed to soil-borne

    pathogens that infect the roots of that crop, but that die out while the field is planted to a different crop. However, recent

    researchat Washington State University (WSU) has documenteda remarkable and apparently widespread

    microbiological control of a root disease in wheat and barley when these crops are grown continuously in the same

    location.The root-associated microbes are responsible for the well-documented decline of the diseasetake-all and a correspondingincrease in yields following one or more outbreaks of the disease, said R. James Cook, interim dean of WSUs College of Agricultural, Human, and Natural Resource Sciences. Dr Cook is a st rong advocate for crop rotation

    for many reasons, but points out that crop monoculture also has advantages and can be achieved sustainably with the help of soil microbes. Cook and his colleague David M. Weller studied the pathogens responsible for four

    major root diseases of wheat and barley grown in the inland Pacific Northwest. Breeding for host plant resistance has provided only useful tolerance for management of one of these, Fusarium crown rot, and no useful

    resistance or tolerance to take-all, Rhizoctinia root rot and Pythium root rot, Cook said. Considering the fact that the forebears ofmodern wheat evolved as a

    virtual monoculture, the lack of genes for resistanceto root diseases implies that some other defence mechanism

    exists. Such protection develops against take-all with wheat monoculture. He said that wheat and barley selectively

    stimulate and support populations of antagonistic microorganisms in the root zone. Often four to six consecutive

    crops are required before the onset of take-all decline, but the exact number of consecutive crops may vary.

    Even if diversity loss occurs, seed banks solve the impact

    Rissing, 2008

    (Steve, Biology professor at Ohio State University, Seed banks protect crops from growing list of threats, March 11,

    http://www.dispatch.com/live/content/science/stories/2008/03/11/sci_rissing11_ART_03-11-

    08_B5_A99I7L6.html?type=rss&cat=&sid=101)The first several million seeds for the long-planned Global Seed Vaultarrived last month. Their new home, in the frozen

    side of a mountain 700 miles from the North Pole, cost $8 million to build. The vaultjoins 1,400 other banks of various

    kinds that preserve seeds and other tissues of crop plants. Indeed, the vault exists partly to restockany of those

    banks after disastersthat might befall them. Civil unrest in Afghanistan and Iraq, for example, resulted in destruction of

    seed banks there, according to a recent report in The New York Times. The world depends on a shrinking group of crop

    plants attacked by a growing number of parasites, predators and pathogens.In the 1970s, a previously unknown variety of

    grassy stunt virus appeared in rice crops around the world. A variety of insect, also previously unknown, spread the virus.

    A search for plants resistant to the virus found a single, wild rice relative in a seed bank operated by the International Rice

    Research Institute. Botanists bredthat resistance intoa line ofrice just in time to avert a global collapse in rice

    production. A similar situation occurred in the summerof 1970 whena previously unknown variety of Southern cornleaf blight destroyed 15 percent of the U.S. corn crop. Genetic uniformity of the corn permitted the fungus to spread

    through the Corn Belt like wildfire, according to later studies.

    Monoculture is both natural and sustainable

    Avery, 2003

    (Dennis T., MimickingNature to Eat Well, April 30,

    http://www.hudson.org/index.cfm?fuseaction=publication_details&id=2841)

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    21/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Dr. Michael Altieri of the University of California at Berkeley claims that monocultures are ecologically unstable. He says they provide optimalconditions for unhampered growth of weeds, insects, and diseases because many ecological niches are not filled by other organisms.But why use tropical biodiversity

    as a model? Evolutionist Charles Darwin praised the huge kelp beds of the southern Atlantic, a natural monoculture. Darwin said, The

    number of living creatures of all Orders whose existence intimately depends on the kelp is wonderful. Another virtual species monopoly, blue grama

    grass, used to cover thousands of square miles of the central United States, supporting a rich web of wildlife ranging from hugebison and mammoths to prairie dogs, birds, and grasshoppers.Dr. Donald Wood, a plant resource expert who has worked in India, Kenya, and the West Indies, saysMother Nature offers other plant growth models that had more to do with the evolution of todays farming than tropical forests, including natural grasslands and the

    flood plains of river valleys.He says the common belief that cereals arose as weeds on the fringes of human campsites is not

    valid. As recently as a century ago, wild rice dominated the riverbanks in what is now Bangladesh. African wild rice was

    historically harvested on a massive scale across Africa from southern Sudan to the Atlantic Ocean. Dr. Wood says these mono-

    dominant stands of plant species led to wet rice cultivation, the single most important cropping system in the developing world.Perhaps thestrongest evidence of the natural mono-dominant pattern is wheat. Dr. Wood says that plant explorers have found wheat throughout the Near East in massive stands

    covering many square kilometers, with up to three hundred plants per square meter. Sorghum can be found in mono-dominant stands on the

    extensive tall-grass savannas of Sudanand Chad.Dr. Woods says that environmentally buffeted areas such as flood-prone river valleys, salt marshes,fire-prone prairies, and regions with highly seasonal rainfall usually have few species. Cereal grasses have grown wild there for millennia, defying Altieris claim that

    monocultures are unstable.Man simply extended the area of natural mono-dominant ecosystems to support more people on

    less land. Instead of waiting for floods to fertilize crops, modern farmers mimic nature by adding industrial fertilizer to the soil; instead of waiting for huge prairiefires to renew cereal stands, they plow.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    22/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Genetic Diversity Defense

    Big ag increases plant variety

    Holmen, 2006(Hans, Associate professor in Social and Economic Geography, working as Senior Lecturer in Geography at the Tema

    Institute, Linkoping University, Sweden, Mytsh about Agriculture, Obstacles to Solving the African Food Crisis,

    European Journal of Development Researche, Sept., Vol. 18, Issue 3)

    Also the claim that modern or scientific agriculture offers only a handful of uniform varieties (de Grassi and Rosset,

    2003: 33), or even a few varieties of afew crops (Shiva, quoted in Pringle, 2003: 37), does not stand the test of closer

    scrutiny. Transnational agri-business corporations may have an interest in limiting the number of varieties released,

    since this could enhance profit.However, such restrictions do not apply topublicly owned crop research.Maredia et al.

    (1998) report that, in Africa alone, public maize researchprogrammes released nearly 300 new varieties between 1966 and

    1990. This equals more than a handful of new varieties per year. Evenson and Gollin (2003:3) found that from public

    crop research programmesin Latin America, Asia andAfrica, by 2000, . . . more than 8000 modern varieties had beenreleased in 11 crops studied. They also showed that both the diversity and the rate of releases increase over time.

    With more funding for public agricultural research, thesefigures could be substantially higher. Hence, neither externally

    nor withinagriculture is it inevitable that modernisation or scientisation of agriculturewill lead to genetic erosion. 12

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    23/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Biodiversity Defense

    Increased knowledge of big farms has decreased biodiversity loss

    Avery, 2003(Dennis T., director of the Hudson Institute's Center for Global Food Issues, Species Extinction rate lowest in 500

    Years, August 28, http://www.hudson.org/index.cfm?fuseaction=publication_details&id=3021)

    The world is losing wild species only half as rapidly as a hundred years ago, and the rate of extinctions is now the lowest

    in five hundred years. Moreover, mankind[humanity] now has enough knowledge of high-yield farming, and forest and

    wildlife management that we shouldn't have to suffer massive wild species losses in the future. This is the good news

    according to Dr. Mark Collins, a top expert at the UN Environmental Program. The number of extinctions (twenty) among

    birds, mammals and fish in the last third of the twentieth century was only half as great as in the extinctions (forty) in the last

    third of the nineteenth and no greater than the rate of extinctions in the sixteenth century, according to the UNEP's recentlypublished World Atlas of Biodiversity. The Atlas totals 675 known wild species lost in the last 400 years, though the count of 83 mammals and 128 fish and birds gone

    forever is more accurate than the estimate of extinct plants and insects.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    24/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    ***NEG Movements Answers***

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    25/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    No Movements

    No political crises

    Stelzer 9 Irwin Stelzeris a business adviser and director of economic policy studies at the Hudson Institute, Death ofcapitalism exaggerated, http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,26174260-5013479,00.html

    A FUNNY thing happened on the way to the collapse of market capitalismin the face of the worst economic crisis since the

    Great Depression. It didn't. Indeed, in Germany voters relieved Chancellor Angela Merkel of the necessity of cohabiting with a left-wing party, allowing her to form

    a coalition with a party favouring lower taxes and free markets. And in Pittsburgh leaders representing more than 90 per cent of the world's GDP

    convened to figure out how to make markets work better, rather than to hoist the red flag . The workers are to be

    relieved, not of their chains but of credit-card terms that are excessively onerous, and helped to retain their private property - their homes. All of this is contrary to

    expectations. The communist spectre that Karl Marx confidently predicted would be haunting Europe is instead haunting

    Europe's left-wing parties, with even VladimirPutin seeking to attract investment by re-privatising the firms he snatched. Which

    raises an interesting question: why haven't the economic turmoil and rising unemployment led workers to the barricades,

    instead of to their bankers to renegotiate their mortgages? It might be because Spain's leftish government has proved less

    able to cope with economic collapse than countries with more centrist governments. Or because Britain, with a leftish government, is

    now the sick man of Europe, its financial sector in intensive care, its recovery likely to be the slowest in Europe, its prime credit rating threatened. Or it

    might be because left-wing trade unions, greedily demanding their public-sector members be exempted from the pain they want others to share, have

    lost their credibility and ability to lead a leftward lurch. All of those factors contribute to the unexpected strength of

    the Right in a world in which a record number of families are being tossed out of their homes, and jobs have been disappearing by the million. But even

    more important in promoting reform over revolution are three factors: the existence of democratic institutions; the

    condition of the unemployed; and the set of policies developed to cope with the recession. Democratic institutions give the aggrievedan outlet for their discontent, and hope they can change conditions they deem unsatisfactory. Don't like the way George W. Bush has skewed income distribution? Toss

    the Republicans out and elect a man who promises to tax the rich more heavily. Don't like Gordon Brown's tax increases? Toss him out and hope the Tories mean it

    when they promise at least to try to lower taxes. Result: angry voters but no rioters, unless one counts the nutters who break windows at McDonald's or storm banks in

    the City. Contrast that with China, where the disaffected have no choice but to take to the streets. Result: an estimated 10,000 riots this year protesting against joblosses, arbitrary taxes and corruption. A second factor explaining the Left's inability to profit from economic suffering is

    capitalism's ability to adapt , demonstrated in the Great Depression of the 1930s . While a gaggle of bankers and fiscal

    conservatives held out for the status quo, Franklin D. Roosevelt and his experimenters began to weave a social safety net. In Britain, William Beveridge produced a

    report setting the stage for a similar, indeed stronger, net. Continental countries recovering from World War II did the same. So unemployment no longer dooms a

    worker to close-to-starvation. Yes, civic institutions were able to soften the blow for the unemployed before the safety net was put in place, but they could not cope with

    pervasive protracted lay-offs. Also, during this and other recessions, when prices for many items are coming down, the real living

    standard of those in work actually improves. In the US, somewhere between 85 per cent and 90 per cent of workers have kept their jobs, and now see

    their living costs declining as rents and other prices come down. So the impetus to take to the streets is limited. Then there are the steps taken by

    capitalist governments to limit the depth and duration of the downturn. As the economies of most of the big industrial countries imploded,policy went through two phases. The first was triage - do what is necessary to prevent the financial system from collapse. Spend. Guarantee deposits to prevent runs on

    banks and money funds, bail out big banks, force relatively healthier institutions to take over sicker ones, mix all of this with rhetorical attacks on greedy bankers - the

    populist spoonful of sugar that made the bailouts go down with the voters - and stop the rot. Meanwhile, have the central banks dust off their dog-eared copies of

    Bagehot and inject lots of liquidity by whatever means comes to mind. John Maynard Keynes, meet Milton Friedman for a cordial handshake. Then came more

    permanent reform, another round of adapting capitalism to new realities, in this case the malfunctioning of the financial

    markets. Even Barack Obama's left-wing administration decided not to scupper the markets but instead to develop rules to

    relate bankers' pay more closely to long-term performance; to reduce the chance of implosions by increasing the capital

    banks must hold, cutting their profits and dividends, but leaving them in private hands; and to channel most stimulus spending through private-sector companies.

    This leaves the anti-market crowd little room for manoeuvre as voters seem satisfied with the changes to make

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    26/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    capitalism and markets workbetter and more equitably. At least so far. There are exceptions. Australia moved a bit to the left in the last

    election, but more out of unhappiness with a tired incumbent's environmental and foreign policy. Americans chose Obama, but he had promised to

    govern from the centre before swinging left. And for all his rhetorical attacks on greedy bankers and other malefactors of

    great wealth, he sticks to reform of markets rather than their replacement, with healthcare a possible exception. Even in these

    countries, so far, so good for reformed capitalism. No substitutes accepted.

    Movements are getting smothered out of existenceno alternative economic system

    Jones 11Owen, Masters at Oxford, named one of the Daily Telegraph's 'Top 100 Most Influential People on the Left'

    for 2011, author of "Chavs: The Demonization of the Working Class", The Independent, UK, "Owen Jones: Protest

    without politics will change nothing", 2011, www.independent.co.uk/opinion/commentators/owen-jones-protest-without-

    politics-will-change-nothing-2373612.html

    My first experience of police kettling was aged 16. It was May Day 2001, and the anti-globalisation movement was at its

    peak. The turn-of-the-century anti-capitalist movement feels largely forgotten today, but it was a big deal at the time. To a

    left-wing teenager growing up in an age of unchallenged neo-liberal triumphalism, just to have "anti-capitalism" flash up

    in the headlines was thrilling. Thousands of apparently unstoppable protesters chased the world's rulers from IMF to

    World Bank summitsfrom Seattle to Prague to Genoaand the authorities were rattled.

    Today, as protesters in nearly a thousand cities across the world follow the example set by the Occupy Wall Street

    protests, it's worth pondering what happened to the anti-globalisation movement. Its activists did not lack passion or

    determination. But they did lack a coherent alternative to the neo-liberal project. With no clear political direction, the

    movement was easily swept away by the jingoism and turmoil that followed 9/11, just two months after Genoa.

    Don't get me wrong: the Occupy movement is a glimmer of sanity amid today's economic madness. By descending on the

    West's financial epicentres, it reminds us of how a crisis caused by the banks (a sentence that needs to be repeated until it

    becomes a clich) has been cynically transformed into a crisis of public spending. The founding statement of Occupy

    London puts it succinctly: "We refuse to pay for the banks' crisis." The Occupiers direct their fire at the top 1 per cent, and

    rightly soas US billionaire Warren Buffett confessed: "There's class warfare, all right, but it's my class, the rich class,that's making war, and we're winning."The Occupy movement has provoked fury from senior US Republicans such as Presidential contender Herman Cain whopredictablylabelled it "anti-American".

    They're right to be worried: those camping outside banks threaten to refocus attention on the real villains, and to act as a catalyst for wider dissent. But a coherent

    alternative to the tottering global economic order remains, it seems, as distant as ever. Neo-liberalism crashes around,

    half-dead, with no-one to administer the killer blow.There's always a presumption that a crisis of capitalism is good news for the left. Yet in the Great Depression, fascism consumed much of Europe. The economic crisis

    of the 1970s did lead to a resurgence of radicalism on both left and right. But, spearheaded by Thatcherism and Reaganism, the New Right definitively crushed its

    opposition in the 1980s.This time round, there doesn't even seem to be an alternative for the right to defeat. That's not the fault of the

    protesters. In truth, the left has never recovered from being virtually smothered out of existence . It was the victim of a perfect

    storm: the rise of the New Right; neo-liberal globalisation; and the repeated defeats suffered by the trade union movement.

    But, above all, it was the aftermath of the collapse of Communism that did for the left . As US neo-conservative Midge Decter triumphantly put it:"It's time to say: We've won. Goodbye." From the British Labour Party to the African National Congress, left-wing movements across the world hurtled

    to the right in an almost synchronised fashion. It was as though the left wing of the global political spectrum had been sliced off. That's

    why, although we live in an age of revolt, there remains no left to give it direction and purpose.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    27/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Market Key

    Market incentives are keyThe affs movements alone wont solve

    Barnhizer 6 -- Professor of Law, Cleveland State University. (David, Waking from Sustainability's "ImpossibleDream": The Decisionmaking Realities of Business and Government, 18 Geo. Int'l Envtl. L. Rev. 595, Lexis)Medieval alchemists sought unsuccessfully to discover the process that would enable them to turn base metal into gold--assigning the name "Philosopher's Stone" to what they sought. The quest was doomed to failure. Just as a "sow's ear" cannot become a "silk purse,"

    base metal cannot become gold.Sustainability is impossible for the same reasons. It asks us tobe something we are not, both individually and as a political and

    economic community. It is impossible to convert humans into the wise, selfless, and nearlyomniscient creaturesrequired to build and

    operate a system that incorporatessustainability. Even if it were ultimatelypossible (and it is not), it would take manygenerations to achieve and we are running

    out of time. There is an enormous gap among what we claim we want to do, what we actually want to do, and our ability to achieve our

    professed goals. I admit to an absolute distrust ofcheap and easy proclamations of lofty ideals and commitments to voluntary

    or unenforceable codes of practice. The only thing that counts is the actor's actual behavior. For most people, that behavior is shaped by self-interest

    determined by the opportunity to benefit or to avoid harm. In the economic arena this means that if a substantial return can be had without a high risk of

    significantnegative consequences, the decision will be made to seek the benefit. It i s the reinvention of Hardin's Tragedy of the Commons. n1 This essay explores the nature of humandecisionmaking and motivation within critical systems. These systems in clude business and governmental decisionmaking with a focus on environmental and social areas of emerging crisis where the consequence of acting unwisely or failing to act wisely produces

    large-scale harms for both human and natural systems. The analysis begins by suggesting that nothing humans create is "sustainable." Change is inevitable and [*597] irresistible whether

    styled as systemic entropy, Joseph Schumpeter's idea of a regenerative "creative destruction," orNikolai Kondratieff's "waves" of economic and social

    transformation. n2Business entities and governmental decisionmakers play critical roles in both causing environmental and

    social harms and avoiding those consequences. Some have thought that the path to avoiding harm and achieving positive benefits is to develop codes of practice that by th eir language promise that decisionmakers

    will behave in ways consistent with the principles that have come to be referred to as "sustainability." That beliefis a delusion--an "impossible dream." Daniel Boorstin once asked: "Have we been doomed to

    make our dreams into illusions?" n3 He adds: "An illusion . . . is an image we have mistaken for reality. . . . [W]e cannot see it i s not fact." n4 Albert Camus warns ofthe inevitability offailing toachieve unrealistic

    goalsand the need to become more aware of the limited extent of our power to effect fundamental change. He urges that we

    concentrate on devisingrealistic strategies and behaviors that allow us to be effective in our actions. n5As companies are expected to implement global codes of conduct

    such as the U.N. Global Compact and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development's (OECD) Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises, n6 and governments [*598] and multilateral inst itutions supposedlybecome more

    concerned about limiting the environmental and social impacts of business decisionmaking, it may be useful to consider actual behavior related to

    corporate and governmental responses to codes of practice , treaties, and even national laws. Unfortunately,business, government, and multilateralinstitutions have poor track records vis-a-vis conformity to such codes of practice and treaties .Despite good intentions, empty dreams and

    platitudes may be counterproductive. This essay argues that the ideal of sustainability as introduced in the 1987 report of th e Brundtland Commission and institutionalized in the form of Agenda 21 at the 1992 Rio Earth

    Summit is false and counterproductive. The ideal ofsustainability assumes that we are almost god-like , capable of perceiving, integrating, monitoring,

    organizing, and controlling our world. These assumptions create an "impossible" character to the "dream" of sustainability in business and governmental decisionmaking.Sustainabilityof the Agenda 21

    kind is a utopian vision that is the enemy of the possible and the good. The problem is that while on paper we can always sketch elegant

    solutions that appear to have the ability to achieve a desired utopia, such solutions work "if only" everyone will come together and behave in the way laid

    out in the "blueprint." n7 Humans should have learned from such grand misperceptions as the French Enlightenment's failure to accurately

    comprehend the quality and limits of human nature or Marxism'sflawed view of altruistic human motivation that the "if only" is an

    impossibly utopian reordering of human nature we will never achieve . n8 [*599] A critical defect in the idea of sustainable development is that it continues the flawed assumptionsabout human nature and motivation that provided the foundational premises of Marxist collectivism and centralized planning authorities. n9 Such perspectives inject rigidity and bureaucracy into a system that requires monitoring, flexibility, adaptation, and

    accountability. But, in criticizing the failed Marxist-Leninist form of organization, my argument should not be seen as a defense of supposed free market capitalism. Like Marxism, a true free market capitalism does not really exist. The factors ofgreed and self

    interest, limited human capacity, inordinate systemiccomplexity, and the power of large-scale driving forces beyond ourabilityto control

    lead to the unsustainability of human systems.Human self-interest is an insurmountable barrier that can be affected to a

    degreeonly by effective laws, the promise of significant financial or careerreturns, or fear of consequences. The only way to

    change the behavior of business and governmental decisionmakers is through the use of the "carrot" and the "stick." n10 Yeteven this approach can only be achieved incrementally with limited positive effects.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    28/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    You should prefer pragmatic solutionsThe affs movements are impossible and ensure mass

    suffering

    Barnhizer 6David R. Emeritus Professor at Cleveland State Universitys Cleveland-Marshall College of Law;

    Waking from Sustainability's "Impossible Dream": The Decisionmaking Realities of Business and Government. 2006

    Georgetown International Environmental Law Review. 18 Geo. Int'l Envtl. L. Rev. 595 L/NWe face a combination of ecological, social, and economic crises. These crises involve the ability to fund potentially conflicting obligations for the provision of social

    benefits, health care, education, pensions, and poverty alleviation. They also include the need for massive expenditures to "fix" what we have already broken. n59 Part

    of the challenge is that in the United States and Europe we have made fiscal promises that we cannot keep. We also have vast economic needs for [*620]

    continuing wealth generation as a precondition for achieving social equity on national and global levels. Figuring out how toreduce some of those obligations, eliminate others, and rebuild the core and vitality of our system must become a part of any honest social discourse. Even Pollyanna

    would be overwhelmed by the choices we face. There will be significant pain and sacrifice in any action we take. But failing to take prompt and effective action will

    produce even more catastrophic consequences.

    The scale of social needs, including the need for expanded productive activity, has grown so large that it cannot be shut off

    at all, and certainly not abruptly. It cannot even be ratcheted down in any significant fashion without producing serious

    harms to human societies and hundreds of millions of people. Even if it were possible to shift back to systems of local

    self-sufficiency, the consequences of the transition process would be catastrophic for many people and even deadly to thepoint of continual conflict, resource wars, increased poverty , and strife. What are needed are concrete, workable,

    and pragmatic strategies that produce effective and intelligently designed economic activity in specific contexts and,

    while seeking efficiency and conservation, place economic and social justice high on a list of priorities. n60The imperative of economic growth applies not only to the needs and expectations of people in economically developed societies but also to people living in nations

    that are currently economically underdeveloped. Opportunities must be created, jobs must be generated in huge numbers, and economic resources expanded to address

    the tragedies of poverty and inequality. Unfortunately, natural systems must be exploited to achieve this; we cannot return to Eden. The question is not how toachieve a static state but how to achieve what is needed to advance social justice while avoiding and mitigating the most destructive consequences of our behavior.

    Many developing country groups involved in efforts to protect the environment and resist the impacts of free trade on their communities have been concerned with the

    harmful effects of economic change. Part of the concern is the increased scale of economic activity. Some concerns relate to who benefits and who loses in the changing

    context imposed by globalization. These concerns are legitimate and understandable. So are the other deep currents running beneath their political positions, including

    those of resistance to change of any kind and a [*621] rejection of the market approach to economic activities. In the system described inaccurately as free market

    capitalism, economic activity not only breaks down existing systems, it creates new systems and--as Joseph Schumpeter observed--

    continually repeats the process through cycles of "creative destruction." n61 This pattern of creative destruction unfolds as necessarily and relentlessly as

    does the birth-maturation-death-rebirth cycle of the natural environment. This occurs even in a self-sufficient or autarkic market system

    capable of managing all variables within its closed dominion. But when the system breaks out of its closed environment,

    the ability of a single national actor to control the system's dynamics erodes and ultimately disappears in the face of

    differential conditions, needs, priorities, and agendas.Globalization's ability to produce wealth for a particular group simultaneously produces harms to different people and interests and generates unfair resource

    redistribution within existing cultures. This is an unavoidable consequence of globalization. n62 The problem is that globalization has altered the rules of

    operation of political, economic, and social activities, and in doing so multiplied greatly our ability to create benefit and

    harm. n63 While some understandably want the unsettling and often chaotic effects of globalization to go away, it can only be dealt with, not reversed.

    The system in which we live and work is no longer closed. There are few contexts not connected to the dynamics of some aspect of the extendedeconomic and social systems resulting from globalization. This means the wide ranging and incompatible variables of a global economic,

    human rights, and social fairness system are resulting in conflicts and unanticipated interpenetrations that no one fully

    understands, anticipates, or controls. n64 Local [*622] self-sufficiency is the loser in this process. It can remain a

    nostalgic dream but rarely a reality . Except for isolated cultures and niche activities, there is very little chance that anyone will be unaffected by this

    transformational process. Change is the constant, and it will take several generations before we return to a period of relative stasis. Even then it will only be a respite

    before the pattern once again intensifies.

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    29/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    Squo Structurally Improving

    The squo is structurally improving

    Goklany 9Worked with federal and state governments, think tanks, and the private sector for over 35 years. Workedwith IPCC before its inception as an author, delegate and reviewer. Negotiated UN Framework Convention on Climate

    Change. Managed the emissions trading program for the EPA. Julian Simon Fellow at the Property and Environment

    Research Center, visiting fellow at AEI, winner of the Julian Simon Prize and Award. PhD, MS, electrical engineering,

    MSU. B.Tech in electrical engineering, Indian Institute of Tech. (Indur, Have increases in population, affluence and

    technology worsened human and environmental well-being? 2009,

    http://www.ejsd.org/docs/HAVE_INCREASES_IN_POPULATION_AFFLUENCE_AND_TECHNOLOGY_WORSENE

    D_HUMAN_AND_ENVIRONMENTAL_WELL-BEING.pdf)

    Although globalpopulation is no longer growing exponentially, it has quadrupled since 1900. Concurrently, affluence (or GDP per capita) has sextupled,global economic product (a measure of aggregate consumption) has increased 23-fold and carbon dioxide has increased over 15-fold (Maddison 2003; GGDC 2008;

    World Bank 2008a; Marland et al. 2007).4 But contrary to Neo- Malthusian fears, average human well-being, measured by any objective indicator,

    has never been higher. Food supplies,Malthus original concern, are up worldwide. Global food supplies per capita increased from 2,254 Cals/day in

    1961 to 2,810 in 2003 (FAOSTAT 2008). This helped reduce hunger and malnutrition worldwide. The proportion of the population

    in the developing world, suffering from chronic hunger declined from 37 percent to 17 percent between 196971 and 20012003

    despite an 87 percent population increase (Goklany 2007a; FAO 2006). The reduction in hungerand malnutrition, along with

    improvements in basic hygiene, improved access tosafer water and sanitation, broad adoption of vaccinations, antibiotics,

    pasteurization and other public health measures, helped reduce mortality and increase life expectancies. These improvements

    first became evident in todays developed countries in the mid- to late-1800s and started to spread in earnest to developing countries from the 1950s. The infant

    mortality rate in developing countries was 180 per 1,000 live births in the early 1950s; today it is 57. Consequently, global life expectancy,

    perhaps the single most important measure of human well-being, increased from 31 years in 1900 to 47 years in the early 1950s to 67 years today (Goklany

    2007a). Globally, average annual per capita incomes tripled since 1950. The proportion of the worlds population outside of

    high-income OECD countries living in absolute poverty (average consumption of less than $1 per day in 1985 International dollars adjusted forpurchasing power parity), fell from 84 percent in 1820 to 40 percent in 1981 to 20 percent in 2007 (Goklany 2007a; WRI 2008; World Bank 2007). Equally

    important, the world is more literate and better educated. Child labor in low income countries declined from 30 to 18 percent

    between 1960 and 2003. In most countries,people are freer politically, economically and socially to pursue their goals as they see fit.

    Morepeople choose their own rulers, and have freedom of expression. They are more likely to live under rule of law, and

    less likely to be arbitrarily deprived of life, limb and property.Social and professional mobility has never been greater. It

    is easier to transcend the bonds of caste, place, gender, and other accidents of birth in the lottery of life. People work fewer hours, and

    have more money and better health to enjoy their leisure time (Goklany 2007a). Figure 3 summarizes the U.S. experience over the 20th centurywith respect to growth of population, affluence, material, fossil fuel energy and chemical consumption, and life expectancy. It indicates that population has multiplied

    3.7-fold; income, 6.9-fold; carbon dioxide emissions, 8.5-fold; material use, 26.5-fold; and organic chemical use, 101-fold. Yet its life expectancy increased

    from 47 years to 77 years and infant mortality (not shown) declined from over 100 per 1,000 live births to 7 per 1,000. It is also important

    to note that not only are people living longer, they are healthier. The disability rate for seniors declined 28 percent between

    1982 and 2004/2005 and, despite better diagnostic tools, major diseases (e.g., cancer, and heart and respiratory diseases) occur811 years laternow than acentury ago (Fogel 2003; Manton et al. 2006). If similar figures could be constructed for other countries, most would indicate qualitatively similar trends, especially

    after 1950, except Sub-Saharan Africa and the erstwhile members of the Soviet Union. In the latter two cases, life expectancy, which had increased following World

    War II, declined after the late 1980s to the early 2000s, possibly due poor economic performance compounded, especially in Sub-Saharan Africa, by AIDS, resurgence

    of malaria, and tuberculosis due mainly to poor governance (breakdown of public health services) and other manmade causes (Goklany 2007a, pp.6669, pp.178181,

    and references therein). However, there are signs of a turnaround, perhaps related to increased economic growth since the early 2000s,although this could, of course, be a temporary blip (Goklany 2007a; World Bank 2008a). Notably, in most areas of the world, the healthadjusted life expectancy

    (HALE), that is, life expectancy adjusted downward for the severity and length of time spent by the average individual in a less-than-healthy condition, is greater now

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    30/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    than the unadjusted life expectancy was 30 years ago. HALE for the China and India in 2002, for instance, were 64.1 and 53.5 years, which exceeded their unadjusted

    life expectancy of 63.2 and 50.7 years in 19701975 (WRI 2008). Figure 4, based on cross country data, indicates that contrary to Neo-Malthusian fears,both life

    expectancy and infant mortality improve with the level of affluence (economic development) and time, a surrogate fortechnological

    change (Goklany 2007a). Other indicators ofhuman well-being that improve over time and as affluence rises are: access to safe water and sanitation(see below), literacy, level of education, food supplies per capita, and the prevalence of malnutrition (Goklany 2007a, 2007b).

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    31/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    ***NEG Solvency Answers***

  • 7/29/2019 Small Farms Negative

    32/51

    Trinity 2012 MG

    US AID Fails

    No solvencywont listen to experts only people of similar social location

    Wainer, immigration policy analyst for Bread for the World Institute, in 11[Andrew, Development and Migration In Rural Mexico, Bread for the World Institute, Brief

    No. 11, January]

    The apple growers were inclined to grow as many apples as they could with little regard for quality. This would give

    them enough money to survive, but little more . The 2008 World Development Report describes the challenges in providing pathways out of rural poverty for ri sk-averse smallfarmers, The

    inability [of small producers] to cope with shocks induces households to adopt low-risk, low-return activities. 47 Thus, the first stage

    of the For a Just Market project trained the smallholder apple farmers how to access the apple market on better terms while also transmitting new techniques for producing higher-quality apples.In order to train the apple

    farmers how to most profitably work with the apple market, CRS hired a Washington state agronomist who visited the

    farmers in Chihuahua and trained them how to monitor the Mexican apple markets on the Internet. With better knowledge of the market, the smallfarmers could increase the income generated by their orchards by selling the apples when their price was peaking. In addition to the market analysis training, CRS facilitated the transmission of state-of-the-art apple orchardist techniques. Beginning in 2005, an

    exchange program was created between the Chihuahua apple farmers and BroetjeOrchards Mexican immigrant agricultural laborers. After decades of working on the cutting edge of apple farming in the United States, the immigrants

    knew how to produce the most valuable apples for market . The techniques they introduced to the Chihuahua farmers included tree pruning and trimming, drip-irrigation, tree spacing strategies, andhow to use anti-hail netting. In January 2006 a group of Chihuahua apple farmers visited Broetje Orchards to learn from the Me