struggling with the impossible: sterling, the ...hirm/downloadpapers/middleton...4.2 devaluation,...

54
STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS AND BRITISH ECONOMIC POLICY, 1949–72 * ROGER MIDDLETON University of Bristol ___________________________________________________________________________ §0.1 CONTENTS 1. Introduction 3 2. ‘Stop-Go’, macroeconomic policy and performance 7 2.1 ‘Stop-Go’ defined and characterised 7 2.2 Observations confounded: ‘Stop-Go’ and British official statistics 8 2.3 Growth theory and business cycle theory 13 2.4 The evolution of views about ‘Stop-Go’ 15 3. Sterling and the balance of payments 19 3.1 The ‘great unmentionable’ 19 3.2 Three weaknesses interact 19 3.3 The current account balance of payments 20 3.4 The capital account balance of payments 22 3.5 Sterling as a reserve currency and the foreign exchange reserves 24 3.6 The political economy of the balance of payments 25 4. Exchange rate policy 30 4.1 Assessing exchange rate choices 30 4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable: defending $2.80 37 4.5 Devaluation, 1967 and its aftermath 40 4.6 The decision to float the pound, 1972 43 5. Conclusions 46 6. References 48 §0.2 LIST OF FIGURES 1. Real GDP growth rate (1995 prices) and current account balance of payments, 1948–74 9 2. UK official gold and foreign currency reserves, 1948–74 9 3. Unemployment rate and consumer price inflation rate, 1948–74 10 4. Real GDP growth: Mosley (1984) low-high graph of Economic Trends, annual supplement, rates and ONS (1999) estimates 11 * Address for correspondence: Dr Roger Middleton, Reader in the History of Political Economy, University of Bristol, 13 Woodland Road, Bristol BS8 1TB, United Kingdom. E-mail: [email protected] . This paper – the extreme preliminary nature of which means that it should not be cited without the author’s permission – is inspired but, as yet, not much informed by an ESRC–financed project (ref. R000237856), operated jointly by the Universities of Bristol and Glasgow, to produce a handbook of documents in the Public Record Office (PRO) relating to ‘Economic policy under the Conservatives, 1951–64’. Other members of this project are Professor Rodney Lowe and Dr Neil Rollings (co-directors) and Dr Astrid Ringe (research officer). The formal results of this project are forthcoming in Lowe et al. (2002). This paper does not take account of the criticisms levelled by Booth (2000; 2001a; b) very recently against my and other work which he labels ‘new revisionist’. I should like to thank one of my students Bethan Nolan for permission to reuse (in Figure 5) a dataset she had prepared from Maddison (1995) for her undergraduate dissertation.

Upload: others

Post on 10-Mar-2021

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS AND BRITISH ECONOMIC POLICY, 1949–72* ROGER MIDDLETON University of Bristol ___________________________________________________________________________

§0.1 CONTENTS 1. Introduction 3 2. ‘Stop-Go’, macroeconomic policy and performance 7 2.1 ‘Stop-Go’ defined and characterised 7 2.2 Observations confounded: ‘Stop-Go’ and British official statistics 8 2.3 Growth theory and business cycle theory 13 2.4 The evolution of views about ‘Stop-Go’ 15 3. Sterling and the balance of payments 19 3.1 The ‘great unmentionable’ 19 3.2 Three weaknesses interact 19 3.3 The current account balance of payments 20 3.4 The capital account balance of payments 22 3.5 Sterling as a reserve currency and the foreign exchange reserves 24 3.6 The political economy of the balance of payments 25 4. Exchange rate policy 30 4.1 Assessing exchange rate choices 30 4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable: defending $2.80 37 4.5 Devaluation, 1967 and its aftermath 40 4.6 The decision to float the pound, 1972 43 5. Conclusions 46 6. References 48

§0.2 LIST OF FIGURES 1. Real GDP growth rate (1995 prices) and current account balance of

payments, 1948–74 9

2. UK official gold and foreign currency reserves, 1948–74 9 3. Unemployment rate and consumer price inflation rate, 1948–74 10 4. Real GDP growth: Mosley (1984) low-high graph of Economic Trends,

annual supplement, rates and ONS (1999) estimates 11

* Address for correspondence: Dr Roger Middleton, Reader in the History of Political Economy, University

of Bristol, 13 Woodland Road, Bristol BS8 1TB, United Kingdom. E-mail: [email protected]. This paper – the extreme preliminary nature of which means that it should not be cited without the author’s permission – is inspired but, as yet, not much informed by an ESRC–financed project (ref. R000237856), operated jointly by the Universities of Bristol and Glasgow, to produce a handbook of documents in the Public Record Office (PRO) relating to ‘Economic policy under the Conservatives, 1951–64’. Other members of this project are Professor Rodney Lowe and Dr Neil Rollings (co-directors) and Dr Astrid Ringe (research officer). The formal results of this project are forthcoming in Lowe et al. (2002). This paper does not take account of the criticisms levelled by Booth (2000; 2001a; b) very recently against my and other work which he labels ‘new revisionist’. I should like to thank one of my students Bethan Nolan for permission to reuse (in Figure 5) a dataset she had prepared from Maddison (1995) for her undergraduate dissertation.

Page 2: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

2 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

5. OECD: real GDP average growth rate and variability of growth, 1950–73 12 6. Current account balance of payments as % of GDP, 1870–1997 20 7. Current account balance of payments by sector as % of GDP, 1946–79 21

§0.3 LIST OF TABLES 1. UK and other G-7 states and EU, G-7 and OECD-17 averages: comparative

macroeconomic performance, 1920–38, 1950–73 and 1973–97 4

2. UK and comparators: economic growth performance, 1950–97 6 3. The timing of and signals for ‘Stop-Go’ policies using then current

macroeconomic indicators, 1951–75 10

4. UK and comparators: real GDP growth, average rates and variability, 1920–90

12

5. GDP growth rates and the balance of payments, 1951–73 12 6. Balance of payments statistics (£m), 1951–70 23 7. Hirsch’s (1965) assessment of eight sterling crises, 1947–65 26

§0.4 ABSTRACT The simultaneous attainment of internal and external balance, the core concerns of macroeconomic policy, are here investigated through a case study of British economic policy during what became known – for all of the advanced capitalist countries (ACCs) – as the golden age. Retrospectively, this was an extraordinary quarter century or so of low unemployment, high growth, moderate price inflation and sustainable balance of payments for the ACCs, Britain included. But, in Britain, historically high growth and employment rates coincided with a period of very pronounced relative economic decline, with the growing perception of that decline generating what became an intense and searching national enquiry into what went wrong and the extent to which Britain’s unhappy situation might be remedied by a change in its economic policies.

A central focus of that on-going policy inquest was the ill-effects of ‘Stop-Go’, this the contemporary phrase which described both the conduct of discretionary macroeconomic policies and the presumption that ‘Policy appear[ed] both to cause deviations from trend and (later) to reverse them ... [such] that growth would have been closer to a sustainable trend had it done neither’ (Dow 1998, p. 260 n.27). A very substantial literature (represented most polemically in Pollard 1984) has now developed which links ‘Stop-Go’ to relative decline, as has a (smaller) literature on why in Britain, perhaps more than in other ACCs, political competition created a climate conducive to ‘Stop-Go’. Neither are our direct concern here, although in investigating the political economy of exchange rate and balance of payments policy we necessarily touch upon both. Rather, our purpose is to explore how endemic sterling crises and balance of payments weaknesses contributed to that developing debate about how to halt national economic decline, a key constituent of which was a process of exploration as to how to lessen the external constraint to high growth and employment. This necessarily entails a close study of Britain’s balance of payments situation (one often misunderstood) and a review of current thinking about the key exchange rate policy episodes of the golden age (devaluation in 1949, the radical ROBOT plan of 1951–2 to float sterling, the 1967 devaluation and the eventual decision to float in 1972).

Our survey encompasses official thinking and that of the wider market for economic ideas. Given the binding nature of the external constraint, and that Britain was one of the world’s largest and most open economies during this period, economists (both insiders and outsiders) and officials/politicians should have been particularly receptive to new thinking in international and open economy macroeconomic theory and policy. This paper discusses why in practice such new ideas were largely tangential to the British policy debate and in the process reveals something about both Britain’s political economy and the more general relationship between developments in economics and their diffusion into policy.

Page 3: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 3 __________________________________________________________________________________________

Full employment, an expanding economy, stable prices and a strong pound; these were the balls which the Chancellor of the Exchequer, like a new Cinquevalli, was expected to keep in the air together.

[Macmillan 1971, p. 3]1

It is surely very irrational indeed to tolerate ‘stop’ measures, lasting two years or more, causing a loss of output of perhaps 3% of national income in the first year and 6% in the second year, merely to correct a deficit amounting to 0.85% of national income. One may go further than saying that this system is irrational; it is positively wrongful in relation to economic welfare. It is high time that this method of correcting adjustments in the balance of payments was put to an end, once and for all. How that should be done is a matter for our consideration. [Harrod 1967, pp. 30–1]

During most of the period ... Chancellors behaved like simple Pavlovian dogs responding to two main stimuli: one was ‘a run on the reserves’ and the other was ‘500,000 unemployed’ – a figure which was later increased to above 600,000. [Brittan 1971, p. 455]

§1. INTRODUCTION

1.1 The simultaneous attainment of internal and external balance, the core concerns of macroeconomic policy, are here investigated through a case study of British economic policy during what became known – for all of the advanced capitalist countries (ACCs) – as the golden age (Marglin and Schor 1990; Armstrong et al. 1991, esp. pt II). Retrospectively, this was an extraordinary quarter century or so (conventionally 1950–73)2 of low unemployment, high growth, moderate price inflation and sustainable balance of payments for the ACCs, Britain included. Indeed, the extraordinary nature of this achievement in terms of the four main macroeconomic policy objectives is clear whether viewed against the record of the troubled interwar years or the more recent period since OPEC I (see Table 1).

1.2 In Britain, however, historically high growth and employment rates during the golden age

coincided with a period of very pronounced relative economic decline, with the growing perception of that decline generating what became an intense and searching national enquiry into what went wrong and the extent to which Britain’s unhappy situation might be remedied by a change – to a lesser but typically to a greater extent – in its economic policies. In recent years economic historians have shown that much of that debate was founded upon a number of misunderstandings concerning the growth process and Britain’s growth potential.3 In particular, once we factor in the subsequent catch-up and convergence literature, which requires that comparative growth rates be interpreted in relation to the absolute starting points of economies in the early postwar period (Feinstein 1990), it becomes obvious that much of that debate operated from overly simplistic readings of growth rates (a relative measure) and the growth league tables which were themselves becoming a staple of economic discourse by the mid-1950s. Indeed, it is now common to distinguish between decline (meaning relative economic decline, as observed from the league tables) and declinism, the latter acquiring the quality of an ideology or obsession with decline which transcends the actuality of the league tables and their implications for comparative national welfare (for example, Budge 1993; English and Kenny 1999).

1.3 A central focus of that on-going policy inquest was the ill-effects of ‘Stop-Go’, this the

contemporary phrase which described both the conduct of discretionary macroeconomic policies and the presumption that – as Dow (1998, p. 260 n.27) now defines it in a major update of his seminal work on early postwar demand management (Dow 1964, p. 284) – 1 Conservative Chancellor of the Exchequer, 1955–7; Prime Minister, 1957–63. 2 For Britain, the ‘golden age’ growth accounting and business cycle reference dates are 1951–73; see

Matthews et al. (1982, pp. xxiii, 4). 3 See, for example, Supple (1994) and Tomlinson (1996); see also Arndt’s (1978) useful but much under-

cited comparative study of the rise and fall of the growth objective since the Second World War.

Page 4: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Table 1 UK and other G-7 states and EU, G-7 and OECD-17 averages: comparative macroeconomic performance, 1920-38, 1950-73 and 1973-97 Averages:

Canada France Germany Italy Japan UK US EUa G-7 OECD-17

A. Annual average real GDP growth rate 1920-38 2.4 2.2 3.7 2.2 2.5 1.9 1.7 2.8 2.4 2.6 1950-73

5.1 5.0 6.0 5.6 9.2 3.0 3.9 4.9 5.4 4.81973-97 2.8 2.1 2.2 2.4 3.3 2.0 2.6 2.6 2.5 2.4

B. Average annual rise in consumer prices 1920-38 (2.3) 3.6 (10.8) 0.3 (0.3) (2.5) (2.0)

(3.1) (2.0) (2.7) 1950-73 2.8 5.0 2.7 3.9 5.2 4.6 2.7 4.2 3.8 4.11973-97 5.8 6.4 3.3 10.1 3.9 8.2 5.4 7.8 6.2 6.0

C. Average annual standardised 1920-38b 11.6 7.0 14.9 n.a. n.a. 13.7 17.3 14.1 12.9 14.0

unemployment rates 1950-73c 4.7 2.0 2.5 5.5 1.6 2.8 4.6 2.9 3.4 2.5

1973-97 9.0 8.6 5.8 9.6 2.5 8.3 6.7 7.7 7.2 6.2D. Average annual current account balance 1920-38 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 1.1 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. of payments surplus as % of GDP 1960-73c (1.0) 0.9 (0.9) 1.0 0.5 (0.1) 0.5 (0.7) 0.1 (0.3)

1973-97 (1.4)(1.9) (0.2)0.1 1.7 (1.0) (0.6)(1.1) (0.4)(1.2)Notes: a Excluding Luxembourg (all periods, except panel D) and (for 1920-38) Greece, Ireland and Portugal and Spain. b Rates in industry; data not available for Austria, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Portugal, Spain and Switzerland. c 1960-73 for Greece, Ireland, New Zealand, Portugal and Spain. d Data not available for 1950s. Sources: Derived as follows: A: Maddison (1995, table C-16) and OECD (1998, annex table 1). B: Maddison (1991, table E.3) and OECD (1998, annex table 16). C: 1920-38: Eichengreen and Hatton (1988, table 1.1); 1950-: Maddison (1991, table C-6) and OECD (1998, annex table 21). D: UK 1920-38: Middleton (1996, figure 7.8A); thereafter OECD (1996, table 6.15; 1998, annex table 52).

Page 5: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 5 __________________________________________________________________________________________

‘Policy appear[ed] both to cause deviations from trend and (later) to reverse them ... [such] that growth would have been closer to a sustainable trend had it done neither.’4 A very substantial literature (represented most polemically in Pollard 1984) has now developed which links ‘Stop-Go’ to relative decline, as has a (smaller) literature on why in Britain, perhaps more than in other ACCs, political competition created a climate conducive to ‘Stop-Go’ (both literatures surveyed in Middleton 1996). None of this is of direct concern in this paper, although it is important in setting the scene to our investigation of the political economy of exchange rate and balance of payments policy where we necessarily touch upon both literatures. Accordingly, we offer Table 2 to indicate the extent to which, from the latest estimates of Britain’s comparative economic performance, relative economic decline has proceeded since the Second World War (the dramatic turnaround in the German and Japanese economies relative to Britain was an especially troublesome comparison, one frequently made in this debate).

1.4 Our backdrop is accordingly and necessarily a literature now thoroughly pervaded by

declinism, one in which British economic history since the Second World War is typically played out as the search for scapegoats responsible for that decline (implicating variously government, business and labour) and/or judged against some implicit blueprint for modernisation, some counterfactual postwar Britain which would have been very different if, at some strategic point (typically 1945 or shortly thereafter, with another opportunity in the early 1960s with the quest for an active consensus on ‘Keynesian plus’ policies),5 an alternative set of policies and attitudes had prevailed (Middleton 2000, p. 22; see Clarke 1996, pp. 401–4 for what might have been). Whether there existed real historical opportunities for a British government to pursue very different policy choices, and whether these would have made a substantive difference is, of course, acutely controversial. While we will never know the outcome of such counterfactuals in any epistemological sense, the question of whether British government economic policies could have been more effective remains a very real one; the bread and butter of political competition as remedies for economic underperformance came to dominate the political and policy agenda and to thereby influence electoral behaviour.

1.5 Our purpose in this paper is to explore how endemic sterling crises and balance of payments weaknesses contributed to that developing debate about how to halt national economic decline, a key constituent of which was a process of exploration as to how to lessen the external constraint to high growth and employment. This necessarily entails a close study of Britain’s balance of payments situation (one often misunderstood) and a review of current thinking about the key exchange rate policy episodes (a euphemism for crises) of the golden age (principally, devaluation in 1949, the radical ROBOT plan of 1951–2 to float sterling, the 1967 devaluation and the eventual decision to float in 1972). Our survey encompasses official thinking and that of the wider market for economic ideas. Given the binding nature of the

4 According to Jay (1985, p. 132), a professional economist turned Labour minister, the phrase ‘Stop-Go’

was coined in 1955 to describe the politics and economics of the sequence in that year of pre-election tax-remitting budget followed shortly after by a tax raising emergency budget once the governing party had been returned to office. However, as yet we have not found references to the term in economic policy debates of the 1950s (it is not in Shonfield 1958). This term does not appear in the Radcliffe report (HMSO 1959), but it is in the Plowden report (HMSO 1961, p. 9) in the form of a reference to ‘stop-and-go’ public expenditure policies. However, it was routine in political discourse, in the sense of meaning destabilizing stabilization policies, by 1964, appearing for example as a centrepiece in the Labour Party’s general election manifesto of that year and in Brittan’s (1964, p. 208) semi-insider account of macroeconomic policy under the Conservatives, 1951–64. However, Dow (1964) did not use the term, referring instead to ‘“stops and starts” of official policy’ (p. 397); Harrod (1963, p. 84), however, did.

5 The phrase ‘Keynesian plus’ describes the augmentation of ‘classic’ short-term Keynesian demand management techniques and objectives with a range of supply-side initiatives directed at promoting higher growth (see Pemberton 2000; 2001; also Ringe and Rollings 2000).

Page 6: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

6 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

TABLE 2 UK and comparators: economic growth performance, 1950-97 Annual average %

change: OECD-17 ranking:a, c

1950-97

1950

1973

1997b

1950-73

1973-97b

1950-97b

1950

1973

1997b

growth rate b

A. Real GDP (1990 US$) G-7 countries: Canada 96,800 301,880 590,361 5.1 2.8 3.9 7 7 7 4 France 218,409 674,404 1,109,403 5.0 2.1 3.5 3 4 4 9 Germany 213,976 815,138 1,343,236 6.0 2.1 4.0 4 3 3 2 Italy 161,351 570,200 997,932 5.6 2.4 4.0 5 6 6 3 Japan 156,546 1,197,152 2,593,122 9.3 3.3 6.2 6 2 2 1 UK 344,859 674,061 1,051,149 3.0 1.9 2.4 2 5 5 17 US 1,457,624 3,519,224 6,350,209 3.9 2.5 3.2 1 1 1 11 Arithmetic averages:

EU 116,219 333,450 548,162 4.7 2.1 3.4 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. G-7 378,509 1,107,437 2,005,059 4.8 2.5 3.6 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. OECD-17 176,858 512,639 921,043 4.7 2.5 3.6 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.

B. Real GDP per capita (1990 US$) G-7 countries: Canada 7,047 13,644 19,654 2.9 1.5 2.2 5 3 9 12 France 5,221 12,940 18,959 4.0 1.6 2.8 11 7 12 8 Germany 4,281 13,152 20,346 5.0 1.8 3.4 13 6 5 4 Italy 3,425 10,409 17,376 5.0 2.2 3.5 16 16 15 3 Japan 1,873 11,017 20,591 8.0 2.6 5.2 17 14 4 1 UK 6,847 11,992 18,013 2.5 1.7 2.1 6 11 14 14 US 9,573 16,607 23,566 2.4 1.5 1.9 1 2 2 16 Arithmetic averages:

EU 5,225 12,215 18,437 3.8 1.7 2.7 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. G-7 5,467 12,823 19,786 3.8 1.8 2.8 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. OECD-17 5,904 12,745 19,694 3.4 1.8 2.6 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.

C. Real GDP per worker-hour (1990 dollars) G-7 countries: Canada 9.78 19.09 25.32 3.0 1.5 2.3 2 2 8 15 France 5.65 17.77 29.62 5.1 2.7 4.0 10 6 1 5 Germany 4.37 16.64 27.55 6.0 2.7 4.5 12 8 5 2 Italy 4.28 15.58 24.59 5.8 2.4 4.3 13 12 9 4 Japan 2.03 11.15 20.02 7.7 3.1 5.6 16 16 16 1 UK 7.86 15.92 23.98 3.1 2.2 2.7 5 11 11 12 US 12.66 23.45 29.10 2.7 1.1 2.0 1 1 2 16 Arithmetic averages:

EU 5.57 16.41 25.27 4.8 2.3 3.7 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. G-7 6.66 17.09 25.74 4.2 2.2 3.3 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. OECD-16 6.44 16.69 25.04 4.2 2.2 3.3 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. Notes: a OECD-17 comprises G-7 plus Australia, Austria*, Belgium*, Denmark*, Finland*, Netherlands*, New

Zealand, Norway, Sweden* and Switzerland (* indicates an EU member state). b In panel C, terminal year is 1992. c In panel C, OECD-16 ranking. Sources: Middleton (2000, table 1.1).

Page 7: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 7 __________________________________________________________________________________________

external constraint, and that Britain was one of the world’s largest and most open economies during this period, economists (both insiders and outsiders), officials and politicians should have been particularly receptive to new thinking in international and open economy macroeconomic theory and policy. This paper discusses why in practice such new ideas were largely tangential to the British policy debate and in the process reveals something about both Britain’s political economy and the more general relationship between developments in economics and their diffusion into policy.

1.6 The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. In §2 we explore ‘Stop-Go’ policies in

relation to the development and performance of the British economy during the golden age, paying particular attention to the dissonance between actual and perceived performance and to the evolution of thinking about the relationship between the business cycle and economic growth. In §3 we then introduce sterling and the balance of payments, exploring the multiple problems confronting the authorities and the extent to which there have been misconceptions about what those problems were and how these impacted upon the policy space. This prepares us for §4 where we examine in chronological order the most important exchange rate episodes from devaluation in 1949 through to the eventual decision to float sterling in 1972, with attention here devoted to the developing policy debate about how to break free from the external constraint. Some preliminary conclusions are then drawn in §5, with the stress on ‘preliminary’ as we have yet to delve at all deeply into the official records in the PRO and the project to re-examine the political economy of ‘Stop-Go’ is only at its initial stage.

§2. ‘STOP-GO’, MACROECONOMIC POLICY AND PERFORMANCE 2.1 ‘Stop-Go’ defined and characterised 2.1.1 The ‘Stop-Go’ phase of postwar British (and, indeed, American) economic policy has been

likened to ‘a cow wandering back and forth between two electric fences, one of them labelled “excessive unemployment” and the other labelled “excessive inflation” or alternatively “balance of payments crisis”, but moving all the time towards the edge of a cliff labelled “stagnation and hyperinflation”’ (Mosley 1984, p. 116). For Britain the charge sheet against ‘Stop-Go’ is that it both undermined long-term growth potential and contributed to the eventual stagflation of the 1970s, charges which bring us to the heart of two literatures: that on postwar decline and that on the rise and fall of Keynesianism. In its strongest versions (principally Pollard 1984), the condemnation of ‘Stop-Go’ operates at two levels: directly, through cyclical instability generating additional costs and uncertainty which adversely impact upon the marginal efficiency of capital and the inducement to invest; and, indirectly, by conditioning the principal economic and political agents to a level of uncertainty which generated strategic behaviours that lessened the credibility of government and thus the effectiveness of policy, this with important feedback mechanisms to growth and other macroeconomic target variables.

2.1.2 This macroeconomic policy regime, constructed around a system of alternating responses to

triggers or signals which were as much political as economic (i.e. who defined what was ‘excessive’), followed from the dual commitment to full employment and the maintenance of a strong pound. It was conditioned by inflexible labour and goods markets and subject to the external constraint of sterling and the balance of payments. This forced ‘Stops’, that is deflations of demand, whenever the foreign exchange reserves fell to unacceptable levels, with the perception of this, in turn, a function of general foreign confidence in sterling and the absolute position of the current account balance of payments. These were themselves the function of the behaviour of aggregate supply in the face of the previous expansion of

Page 8: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

8 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

demand, in particular the effect of tighter labour markets on wages, and thus prices, and the extent to which additional demand was accommodated by increased domestic supply and not additional imports. ‘Goes’, that is reflations of demand, then followed whenever the previous deflation had reduced demand sufficiently to improve the current account and result in some replenishment of the reserves, which were much conditioned by the course of prices in the down stage of the cycle (Middleton 1996, pp. 575–6). Figures 1–3 provides a general picture of the era of ‘Stop-Go’ cycles with Table 3 providing details of the principal turning-points in policy together with estimates of changes in the four main macroeconomic indicators using the data available to contemporaries.

2.2 Observations confounded: ‘Stop-Go’ and British official statistics 2.2.1 This use of contemporary data in Table 3 is particularly important. Postwar national accounts

and much other economic data are subject to an ongoing process of revision, such that the latest estimates frequently differ – and sometimes substantially so – from the data with which contemporaries had to work in framing policy and assessing its effectiveness. This poses real problems for the economic historian, ones insufficiently appreciated by most practitioners. Thus, Mosley (1984, pp. 241–3), using successive volumes of the Economic Trends annual supplement (a core macroeconomic data resource), has calculated that during the 1960s and 1970s the average range of variations in this process of constant revision amounts to 1.2 per cent for the annual growth rate of real GDP and £268 million for the current account balance of payment. Moreover, there has been a tendency for ‘revisions in the statistics to make our view of the economy look rosier with hindsight than it looked at the time’, such that the revisions were upward for the former in 17 out of the 20 years enumerated and improvements in the latter in eighteen of these years. He observed an important implication and identified at least one policy episode critically affected:

namely that the overly pessimistic estimate of these target variables available at the moment of decision may provoke the government into deflationary measures which might never have been considered necessary had the ‘true’ value of those target variables been known at the time. A case in point is 1966, in which serious deflationary measures occurred which punctured the Labour government’s hopes of achieving the growth targets of the 1964 ‘National Plan’ .... The principal cause of these deflationary measures was the state of the balance of payments, which according to statistics published shortly after the end of the year was in deficit over the year to the tune of £61 m. It is now estimated to have been in overall surplus to the tune of £113 m. [Mosley 1984, pp. 243–4]6

2.2.2 Mosley (1985) has also estimated that on average between 1951–84 the Treasury

underestimated the public sector financial deficit by 0.5 per cent of GDP, this being about half the average amount by which Chancellors sought to fine-tune demand through the budget, and this with no tendency for the accuracy of forecasting (fiscal marksmanship) to improve through time (see also Balacs 1972). As a former Permanent Secretary to the Treasury has indicated when asked to reflect on the golden age years:

Anyone trying to recount the history of a period in which he was active, relying on memory and the material available at the time, would be totally astonished to find that most of the figures for the same period produced by other people twenty or thirty years later were quite unrecognizable. The most important instrument lacking was a position-finder to tell us exactly where we were at any given moment. Nearly all statistics, and especially those made on the basis of trends, are subsequently changed and yield quite a different picture with the passage of time. It might well be, therefore, that many of the things that happened in the 1960s took place because of inadequate guidance and information. [Croham 1992, p. 92]7

6 The onward march of revisions has now produced a current account surplus for 1966 of £218 million

(ONS 1999, table 1.18) as against the original estimate of a £61 million deficit. 7 Formerly Douglas Allen, entered Treasury, 1948; Permanent Secretary, 1968–74.

Page 9: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 9 __________________________________________________________________________________________

FIGURE 1 Real GDP growth rate (1995 prices) and current account balance of payments, 1948-74

-4.0

-2.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

1948 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974

Source: Calculated from ONS (1999, tables 1.2, 1.3, 1.18).

% g

row

th ra

te o

n pr

evio

us y

ear

-4.0

-2.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

% o

f GD

P

Real GDP growth rate (LHS)

Current account balance (RHS)

FIGURE 2 UK official gold and foreign currency reserves, 1948-74

-2,000

-1,000

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

1948 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974

Source: Calaculated from CSO (1981, p. 142).

£m, c

hang

e on

pre

viou

s yea

r

Page 10: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

10 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

FIGURE 3 Unemployment rate and consumer price inflation rate, 1948-74

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

1948 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974

Sources: Denman and McDonald (1996, tables 1-2); Middleton (2000, figure 2.4).

%

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

14.0

16.0

%

Inflation rate (RPI) (RHS)

Unemployment rate (LHS)

TABLE 3 The timing of and signals for ‘Stop-Go’ policies using then current macroeconomic indicators, 1951-75 Current Change in Real GDP Annual average Change in account foreign exchange growth rate unemployment RPI balance of reserves on previous rate in year on previous payments on previous Year Policy phase year (%) of policy action year (%) (£ millions) year (£ millions) 1951 Stop 3.5 1.2 11.8 (425) (344)1952 Go .. 2.0 6.7 170 (175)1956 Stop 2.0 1.2 3.3 209 421958 Go - 2.1 1.5 345 2841962 Go (0.5) 2.0 2.7 115 (183)1965 Stop 3.3 1.4 4.7 (49) 2461968 Stop 4.1 2.4 4.8 (271) (114)1971 Go 1.5 3.6 9.3 1,040 1,3481975 Stop 0.0 3.9 24.2 (1,732) .. Source: Derived from Mosley (1984, tables 4.1, 5.3)

2.2.3 The deficiencies of official statistics are a hardy perennial of policy discourse, with all Chancellors and their officials lamenting that, as a recent Chancellor put it, ‘trying to make policy on the basis of current statistics it like trying to drive a car by the rearview mirror ... [a] mirror so cracked and dirty you can’t even see where you have been’ (Lamont 1999, p. 34).8 It is particularly important for this discussion, however, since it is probable that the biases affecting the core growth rate and balance of payments instrumental targets stemmed from the same cause: the tendency of imports to be recorded at once and exports only after a lag. We have then the inevitable question of the extent to which, in some sense, ‘Stop-Go’ was avoidable and an urgency that economic historians shift their gaze from its current

8 Conservative Chancellor of the Exchequer, 1990–3.

Page 11: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 11 __________________________________________________________________________________________

exclusive preoccupation with policy-making and, in addition, examine the machinery for collecting data and compiling short-term forecasts. In short, applied economics matters and our current state of knowledge about the development of postwar official statistics and their uses is woeful.9 We will return to this problem in §3.3 in our treatment of balance of payments statistics. Meanwhile, Figure 4 charts the range of variations in real GDP growth rates between 1960–80 compiled by Mosley (1984) together with the current ONS estimates.

FIGURE 4 Real GDP growth: Mosley (1984) low-high graph of Economic Trends , annual supplement, rates and ONS (1999) estimates

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980

Source: Mosley (1984, Table A.5); ONS (1999, table 1.2).

% g

row

th ra

te o

n pr

evio

us y

ear

ONS (1999) revised estimates

(4.0)

(2.0)

2.2.4 We have a further empirical problem which stems from the very phrase ‘Stop-Go’: the

reputation that Britain’s golden age years have as ones of cyclical instability. In fact, historically such a depiction is quite unwarranted. As Table 4 shows, in reality the golden age years were ones of exceptional stability (as well as exceptionally high growth) with the UK experiencing a much smaller average amplitude of output fluctuations than was the case during either the interwar years or the post-1973 era.10 Indeed, the golden age is exceptional for being free of a genuine recession (that is these were positive, growth cycles), as against the two serious recessions experienced between the wars (1920–1, 1929–32) and the three since OPEC I (1973–5, 1979–82 and 1989–93) (see Dow 1999). Moreover, this record of

9 Middleton (1998, pp. 257–61, 273) provides an abbreviated account of what we currently know about

British official statistics in relation to policy during the golden age. This can now be supplemented by the insider accounts of Holmans (1999, esp. ch. XI) and Bretherton (1999, esp. pp. 61–75) which cover demand management between 1953–64. Much, much more needs to be done although the Treasury documents referred to by Holmans and Bretherton provided a suitable starting point. Unfortunately, Peden’s recent history of the Treasury and public policy has very little to say about the development of the national accounts and economic forecasting, whilst in any case he ends his account in 1959 (Peden 2000, p. 454).

10 For a long-term perspective, see Matthews et al. (1982, table 10.1) which should be supplemented by Britton (1986) for postwar Britain; for long-term international comparisons, see Backus and Kehoe (1992) – this important empirical work but alas it models a ‘postwar’ period which does not incorporate a pre- and post-OPEC I break –, Bordo (1993) and Maddison (1991, ch. 4). Maddison’s work is particularly important because he was one of the first economists who, basing his work on empirical study of the major OECD economies, ventured the opinion that ‘The maintenance of high and steady levels of demand has ... been a major condition for the vastly improved performance of the European economies as compared with the past ... [and] The fact that in the United Kingdom demand has continually had to be interrupted by deflationary measures to right the balance of payments is one of the major reasons why that country has grown more slowly than the rest of Europe’ (Maddison 1964, p. 49); see also Maddison (1960).

Page 12: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

12 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

TABLE 4 UK and comparators: real GDP growth, average rates and variability, 1920-90 Average growth ratesa Average % deviationb

1920-38 1950-73 1973-90 1920-38 1950-73 1973-90 UK 2.0 2.9 1.9 3.3 1.4 2.6 Other countries: US 1.6 3.7 2.6 9.9 2.6 1.6 France 2.2 5.1 2.5 7.2 1.4 1.4 West Germany 4.3 5.9 2.2 8.0 5.2 2.2 Italy 2.2 5.5 2.6 3.3 1.5 1.7 Japan 3.5 9.3 4.0 3.2 2.8 0.9 Canada 2.5 5.1 3.5 6.8 1.7 1.4 Sweden 3.3 4.0 2.0 3.2 2.6 1.4 Aggregation for 7 countries 2.2 4.8 2.9 7.5 1.8 1.3 Notes: a Fitted logarithmic trend of real GDP for each period. b Average % deviation from the fitted logarithmic trend of GDP for each period. Source: Dow (1999, table 2.10). TABLE 5 GDP growth rates and the balance of payments, 1951-73

Current account balance of Real GDP growth rates (%) payments (as % of GDP): Averages High Low Range Averages High Low Range

1951-5 2.9 4.3 0.4 3.9 0.3 1.7 (2.0) 3.6 1955-60 2.5 5.4 0.4 5.0 0.8 1.9 (0.7) 2.6 1960-4 3.5 5.5 1.2 4.2 0.1 0.9 (0.8) 1.6 1964-8 2.7 5.5 1.9 3.5 (0.2) 0.6 (0.8) 1.4 1968-73 3.5 7.3 2.1 5.3 0.7 2.2 (1.2) 3.4

1951-73 3.0 7.3 0.4 6.9 0.5 2.2 (2.0) 4.2 Source: As Figure 1.

FIGURE 5 OECD: real GDP average growth rate and variability of growth, 1950-73

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

7.0

8.0

9.0

10.0

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4

Instability measureCoefficient of variation

Trend growth rate (%)

Source: Data from Maddison (1991, tables C-16) as calculated by Beth Nolan.

UK

J

DI

CF

US

1.6

Page 13: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 13 __________________________________________________________________________________________

relative stability is confirmed when we examine the experience of other G-7 economies, a characteristic noted by many contemporary commentators but one often finessed in the stronger versions (e.g. Pollard 1984) of the ‘Stop-Go’ and slow growth literature.11 We should note, however, that the impression of British instability might have been stronger than it ought to have been because the business cycle phase with the highest amplitude (1955–60) was also that with the slowest average growth (see Table 5) and was coincident with, first, the beginnings of that policy inquest into relative decline and, second, following the proximity of an (unwarranted) expansionary budget and the 1955 general election, the accusations that ‘Stop-Go’ had assumed the character of political business cycles.

2.2.5 Using as our measure of cyclical instability the coefficient of variation of annual deviations

of real GDP from trend growth we situate the British case in Figure 5: with the X and Y axes crossing at the average of the two summary indicators Britain appears in the south west quadrant: the slowest growing economy of the OECD during the golden age and the eighth most stable. Given these facts, how then should we understand ‘Stop-Go’ in relation to growth performance. This is the vital preliminary question. If ‘Stop-Go’ was inimical to higher long-term growth, we can proceed to the second question: could ‘Stop-Go’ have been moderated by pursuit of different policies, and if so, what were these policies, and in particular what scope was there in exchange rate policy to achieve governmental macroeconomic policy goals, higher growth included.

2.3 Growth theory and business cycle theory 2.3.1 Until recently macroeconomists typically studied long-term growth and the business cycle as

two separate, largely independent phenomena. Thus growth theorists characteristically worked with models in which short-term shocks have no impact on the economy’s long-run growth rate (which is determined by productivity improvements which define the ‘natural’ path of aggregate activity), whilst business cycle theorists generally treated long-term growth as an exogenous trend (business cycles thereby having no long-run impact upon productivity potential). However, the advent of endogenous growth theory, and the growing reaction against the dominance of new classical macroeconomics’ views on the ineffectiveness of stabilization policies, has more recently led some economists to revisit the ways in which short-term cycles in potential output and long-run growth are related with theoretical perspectives resulting in which there can be positive or negative relationships between them.12 In this new literature, the sign of the relationship depends upon the mechanisms operating at the origin of growth, namely whether productivity enhancing activities (PEAs) constitute a substitute or a complement to production: • substitutes: this hypothesises that, since the opportunity cost of PEAs falls in recessions

(promoting inter-temporal substitution of such activities), a larger (smaller) amplitude and frequency of business cycle fluctuations may have a positive (negative) effect on long-run productivity and production;

• complements: this hypothesises that, the greater the amplitude and frequency of business

11 The two most important and widely cited studies were Whiting (1976) and NEDO (1975), but see also

Wilson (1966) which first introduced some rigour into the measurement side of the debate, albeit that his results tended more to emphasise relative British instability because his enumeration period (1950–63) was more unstable than that for the golden age as a whole. Thus we should expect the early empirical studies to be more pessimistic about British cyclical stability because of the higher weight that they accord to the 1955–60 cycle, the most disturbed of the golden age and that with the slowest average growth rate (see Table 5).

12 My reading of the relationship between these two fields of theory relies upon Saint-Paul’s (1997) survey and the recent empirical work on the postwar OECD economies of Martin and Rogers (2000) and Li (2000).

Page 14: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

14 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

cycle fluctuations, the greater the potential adverse long-term impact upon productivity growth and production, and has a particular salience for our subject as one strand to this literature concerns growth that is generated by learning-by-doing, as for example in stabilisation policies that can have a positive impact on human capital accumulation, such that a counter-cyclical policy that smoothes the impact of shocks on employment can be growth promoting.

2.3.2 Whilst the majority of macroeconomists continue to reject the idea that demand shocks have

a long-run impact on productivity performance and thus growth, this irrespective of whether the relationship between them be positive or negative, the opportunity cost hypothesis (of productivity growth as a substitute for production) is not inconsistent with the aggregate empirical evidence and it is clear that more research is required into which sorts of PEAs are counter-cyclical and how quantitatively significant they might be (Saint-Paul 1997, p. 152). Endogenous growth theory thus offers much potential to reinterpret Britain’s golden age performance, with preliminary work by Broadberry and Crafts generating a ‘new orthodoxy’ that whilst the macroeconomic policy framework adopted after the Second World War was understandable and quite effective in ameliorating short-term adjustment problems, it was harmful in its longer-term supply-side implications for the growth of productive potential, with failures in government industrial policy and the unwillingness to tackle issues of necessary institutional reform particularly identified.13 However, this growing body of work has not as yet looked at golden age growth in relation to ‘Stop-Go’, and thus much remains to be done and particularly in relation to incentive structures and investment, core concerns of the endogenous growth literature.

2.3.3 Observations about the separateness of growth and business cycle theory during the 1970s,

1980s and much of the 1990s might, but should not necessarily, be taken to imply that these fields coexisted in a more unified fashion for the early postwar years.14 Laidler’s (1992) survey of business cycle theory before the new classical macroeconomics, which emphasises the importance of empirical content to progress in theory building, does make solid connections between the two fields in terms of early postwar multiplier-accelerator theory which, via Harrod-Domar, posits the conditions for Keynesian stabilization policies to smooth the cycle and manipulate the economy’s warranted growth path so as to coincide with the economy’s natural growth path. Real business cycle models predominated at this time in the sense that economists generally conceived of the cycle as driven by real aggregate demand, principally unstable investment activities, with monetary factors playing a subordinate role and the supply-side setting the constraints which acted to determine business cycle turning-points. However, although the influence of Keynes’s General theory can clearly be detected in this research programme, and whatever the merits of multiplier-accelerator models, they ceased to be a focus of active research by the early 1960s as the dominance of Keynesian macroeconomics resulted in a shift of attention from business cycle phenomena to the development of methods and policies which could produce accelerated economic growth (Snowdon et al. 1994, p. 239).

13 This literature is now quite extensive, but also contested. On the potential of endogenous growth theory to

underpin a reinterpretation of golden age performance, see Crafts (1996) and Bean and Crafts (1996); and on the broader political economy see the exchanges between Broadberry and Crafts (1996; 1998) and Tomlinson and Tiratsoo (1998).

14 For example, the Rockefeller Foundation-funded RES-AEA surveys of economic theory included a contribution on growth theory (Hahn and Matthews 1964), which had little to say about the cycle, but not one on business/trade cycle theory. Matthews’ Trade cycle (1959), written as a Cambridge economic handbook, might be taken as an exemplar of an Anglo-American synthesis in this field. This had two chapters on the relationship between the trend and the cycle, dealing with matters theoretical and of policy concern. However, Matthews (1959) was written just prior to the British policy debate moving into its new phase of growing concern about growth and how to promote it.

Page 15: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 15 __________________________________________________________________________________________

2.3.4 A culmination of this process might to be taken to be the much cited 1967 conference which produced the volume, Is the business cycle obsolete? (Bronfenbrenner 1969). Although the title implies an optimism which actually belies the verdicts of most of the papers discussed at that conference, it is particularly noteworthy that the British paper (Matthews 1969a) was amongst the least pessimistic. Matthews’ (1969, pp. 130, 131–2) conclusion is worth citing at length as it connects to so many of our themes and provides a convenient bridge to consider the development of views about ‘Stop-Go’:

Whether the overall effect of government policy has been stabilizing or destabilizing (a complicated question to define, let alone answer) ..., it cannot be denied that government policy did differ considerably from what it ought to have been if the objective had been to maintain activity at a stable and consistent level. It is difficult to believe that the reasons for this lay primarily in faulty forecasting of trends in demand, or of the effects of instruments chosen to affect it. Over the past fifteen years, techniques of forecasting and controlling demand have made great advances; the data available for the purpose have improved greatly; both civil servants and cabinet ministers have developed a better understanding of the principles involved. Yet fluctuations have, if anything, become more severe. There have been some wrong forecasts, and also some wrong judgements about the balance of demand and supply; but the main fault of policy has been the infirmity of purpose about the level of demand to be aimed at. Lacking effective policy instruments to act directly on the balance of payments, the authorities have had to aim not at the level of activity ideally desirable, but at the best level compatible with avoiding a balance of payments deficit. Their judgements of what this level is have not been consistent. The ‘waves of optimism and pessimism’ of old-fashioned business cycle theory have played a role in the postwar British cycle – not (or not only) in the attitudes of businessmen, but in the attitude of the authorities about what level of activity the balance of payments would stand. Had a consistent view been adopted about this, steps would have had to be taken to prevent either the upswings or the downswings or both from proceeding to the lengths they did. These inconsistencies of view were influenced, though not wholly determined, by the electoral timetable, and also, of course, by the state of the reserves... They have tended to become progressively worse, because the underlying balance of payments problems have been getting more acute and at the same time the pressure of opinion in favor of growth-oriented policy has been getting stronger. That is what has offset the potential good effects of the improvements in technical economic expertise. ... How much have the cycles mattered? ... my tentative answer would be that they have not mattered much. Cycles have had a markedly disturbing influence on certain individual industries, such as the motor industry. For the rest, they have caused more concern to the authorities than to the public.

2.4 The evolution of views about ‘Stop-Go 2.4.1 Matthews’ verdict has an obvious connection to his twin contemporaneous theses (Matthews

1968; 1969b): first, that full employment since the war owed less to the spending activities of government (in the form of Keynesian deficit-finance) than to the high spending propensities of the private sector operating through what we now identify as a golden age system characteristic, a high rate of physical capital formation;15 and, second, that there was ‘no particular difficulty in explaining the low British growth rate’, but rather the British economic problem that needed to be explained and addressed was sustained and long-standing low levels of productivity, for which the remedy lay outside of the realm of macroeconomic policies in improving general efficiency and attitudes (Matthews 1969b, p. 268).

2.4.2 For Matthews then the ‘infirmity of purpose’ absolved ‘Stop-Go’ from direct responsibility

for slow growth, while in any case slow growth per se was not the central policy problem and the focus upon macroeconomic policy was ‘somewhat off the mark’ (Matthews 1969b, p. 268; see also Matthews 1971). At this point it may be possible to detect something of a difference in emphasis between British and American economists’ assessments of Britain’s economic problem, at least as expressed in the first Brookings study of the British economy (Caves et al. 1968) and the response from British (mainly, but not exclusively, Cambridge 15 Of course, a further system characteristic was that high golden age growth owed something to

macroeconomic policy success in promoting buoyant demand and containing inflationary pressures in conditions of very high demand (Maddison 1991, ch. 6).

Page 16: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

16 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

and National Institute) economists that this produced (Cairncross 1971).16 The Brookings study was much preoccupied with ‘Stop-Go’ (especially the Musgraves’ chapter on fiscal policy), concluding that whilst ‘We have not been able to measure the costs imposed by periodic demand restraint ... we believe them to have been substantial ... [and that consequently] relaxing the balance-of-payments constraint on the management of aggregate demand seems a tactical necessity for securing better domestic performance’ (Caves et al. 1968, p. 488).

2.4.3 In the chapter specifically on economic growth, Denison (1968) updated his well-known

growth accounting exercise to confirm that slow growth hitherto was still explicable, while future growth would ‘depend decisively upon the group of income determinants whose effects are combined in the measure of “residual efficiency”’, what we would now call TFP growth. His account of why TFP might underperform in the future, of why in modern parlance the British economy might not attain the potential catch-up bonus, then proceeded to invoke the usual supply-side suspects responsible for the X-inefficiencies which, on this diagnosis, lay at the heart of Britain’s economic problem. Unsurprisingly, the advantages of enhanced competition in factor and goods markets were extolled in this respect, and consequentially he saw the decision to initially stand aloof from the EEC as mistaken, but much more surprisingly Denison (1968, p. 277) floated the idea of a:

partial and temporary substitute designed to achieve a one-time gain would be to permit a recession of depth and duration sufficient to create a real fight for markets, to force enterprises to eliminate labor redundancy and adopt cost-cutting practices, and to eliminate the least efficient enterprises by bankruptcy or merger. Greater unemployment might also improve workers’ performance on the job ...

2.4.4 Here is an antecedent of the opportunity cost approach to PEAs, and thus the possibility that

far from ‘Stop-Go’ constraining growth, because it had generated too wide an amplitude of business cycle fluctuations, the converse might actually have been the case: there had been no slump and thus no potential ‘cleansing effect’ (Caballero and Hammour 1994). Given that there had very nearly been negative output growth between 1957–8 (contemporary statistics showed that there had been output losses, and especially in manufacturing) it may well be that this idea has an even earlier existence, and we will need to research this. Whatever the case for the late 1950s, Denison’s idea was not well received a decade later. Reviewing Britain’s economic prospects for the Economic Journal, Worswick (1969a, p. 119) described the suggestion that a recession be engineered as ‘a somewhat antiquated mouse to emerge from such a Himalaya of arithmetic’.17

2.4.5 Denison’s suggestion was, in any case, vulnerable to Matthews’ (1971) criticism that low

growth and low productivity long predated the postwar period and were thus invariant to the

16 This is qualified by Caves’ (1971, p. 212) ‘second thoughts’ in which, in reviewing the conference

proceedings that resulted in the Cairncross (1971) volume, he observed: ‘Certain central conclusions of the Brookings study might be summarized as saying that the potential gains in real growth from changes in demand management have been overestimated and the extent to which the attainable growth rate has been constrained by inefficiency underestimated. We ascribed revelatory force to neither proposition, but felt ourselves at some variance with the “average opinion” that we detected in the past decade’s discussion of economic policy in Britain. “High-level opinion” reflected in the preceding papers, however, seems to be in agreement.’

17 See also Worswick (1969b), an extended version of this review which was incorporated into Britain’s economic prospects reconsidered (Cairncross 1971). There may have been also an important subtext to Worswick’s critique of Denison’s growth accounting exercise, namely – and with apologies to Einstein – that not everything that counts can be counted and not everything that can be counted counts; hence: ‘One cannot but be impressed by Denison’s determination to put numbers down in each of his analytical boxes, but one does get the feeling that his exhaustive enumeration proved something of a strait-jacket when he comes to considering prescriptions for faster growth’ (Worswick 1969a, p. 119). Do we here detect some resistance to the Americanisation of applied economic analysis?

Page 17: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 17 __________________________________________________________________________________________

average level of demand, although in all fairness it ought to be observed that it was normal in the 1960s to see Britain’s economic decline as largely post-1945 in origin (and thus with policy failures automatically a strong candidate in any explanations thereof) because contemporaries did not yet have historical national accounts estimates which would demonstrate the much longer-term nature of this process.18 Thus at this time potential readings of ‘Stop-Go’ and its effects depended much upon a historical perspective which was telescoped relative to that we now enjoy. A further consideration, potentially dividing British and American economists, was that the commitment to full employment in Britain came to mean a maximum level which approximated to the minimum level attained in the US, this in effect limiting the British policy space in a way which many American economists clearly found hard to rationalise on economic as against political grounds. Thus, during the 1940s and 1950s unemployment was perceived as bringing forth greater potential political penalties in Britain than in America, with the consequence that British (American) policy makers took more risks with inflation (unemployment) than with employment (prices). Thus the Okun discomfort index (inflation plus unemployment rates) for 1950–73 was almost identical for both, but in terms of the inflation-unemployment trade-off they were at different ends of the long-run Phillips curve. The political incentives to take greater risks with the goods market than with the labour market was, of course, always tempered by the weakness of the balance of payments and the foreign exchange reserves. However, the extraordinarily low rate of unemployment achieved in the 1950s, which surpassed all expectations, not least those of Keynes and Beveridge, not only reinforced these perceptions of potential penalties but created a climate in which over-optimistic growth targets could flourish (Croham 1992, p. 86). Such was the consent for the resulting excess demand amongst politicians of both parties and the mass of professional economists that those few academics (for example, Paish 1962; 1970) who argued for a larger margin of productive potential were vilified as reactionaries, as the modern day incarnation of those who had favoured wage cuts and opposed public works between the wars.19

2.4.6 Paish is, of course, noteworthy also for his stalwart opposition to the opinion that long-run

British growth would have been faster had it not been for the recurrent balance of payments crises (see especially Paish 1968). That ‘Stop-Go’ was the child of the external constraint was, however, common territory. What else was common territory; in particular, can we identify the emergence by the late 1960s of a consensus on our first question: the relation between ‘Stop-Go’ and British growth performance? An answer depends upon whether, pace Caves, we are interested in average or high-level opinion. This, in turn, requires that we acknowledge the particularly complex and competitive nature of the market for economic expertise in Britain and its implications for the policy debate. Suppliers of those claiming economic expertise are unusually diverse; much has been claimed for the institutional nexus of City-Bank of England-Treasury relations, and how this has privileged the needs of finance over manufacturing capital (this a central part of Pollard’s thesis); while the degree to which academic expertise is valued and heard over that of other suppliers of economic knowledge (in particular in relation to what Henderson 1986 calls do-it-yourself-economics) can be shown to depend crucially on whether Britain is at war and, if not, the state of party competition.

2.4.7 There is now a large literature on these interconnected themes (surveyed in Middleton 1998),

one unsurprisingly producing few settled answers. Nonetheless, the following summary is attempted. First and foremost, politicians were more critical than economists of ‘Stop-Go’ in relation to its impact upon growth, in part because economists were more sceptical than 18 Such data was, of course, being developed by Matthews and his colleague Feinstein (1972), culminating in

Matthews et al. (1982). 19 This draws upon Middleton (1998, pp. 274–5). Such was the sensitivity about unemployment that during

the golden age the unemployment rate was regularly reported to two decimal places.

Page 18: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

18 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

politicians about what was possible in terms of raising the growth rate and particularly so in relation to the short-term time horizon with which politicians operated. Secondly, ‘Stop-Go’ was an easy political target in an adversarial two-party political system (Gamble and Walkland 1984, ch. 2), a conclusion which connects to our current understanding that the adoption of Keynesianism in postwar economic policy was compromised in certain critical respects which limited the macroeconomic policy space, such that in practice prewar concerns with the primacy of the exchange rate and the balance of payments were never challenged.

2.4.8 Thirdly, in retrospect so much of the ‘Stop-Go’ debate appears confused, with divisions as

much motivated by competing schools on inflation (whether, in the terminology of the time, it was cost-push or demand-pull)20 as on growth and the balance of payments. Fourthly, the zeitgeist remained one of optimism about the potential of macroeconomic policy if only its conduct could be improved, available policy instruments widened and better forecasting achieved. During the 1950s very few of the complaints against ‘Stop-Go’ were directed against the idea of demand management, or even fine tuning, and whilst such complaints grew in the 1960s they were still minority voices until the very end of that decade. However, the economists’ optimism was severely battered by the Wilson years (1964–70), such that not only was the potential of demand management somewhat downgraded but the assumption of benign and capable government, that which had underpinned the postwar consensus of the managed-mixed economy, was subject to serious revision as the crisis of Keynesian conventional wisdom gathered pace. But before this happened, the final breakdown of the Bretton Woods system offered the prospect of a floating exchange rate and thus, for many, at last the means of escape from the external constraint.

2.4.9 Fifthly, and notwithstanding Caves’ observations about British high-level economic opinion,

there were always prominent figures within the British economics profession who subscribed to the stronger versions of the ‘Stop-Go’ and slow growth thesis. Obviously, Dow is prominent here, for he refined his opinions to produce in retirement his Major recessions (1998) (upon which see the symposium, Artis et al. 2000). Others at the National Institute were of a similar vein (for example, Blackaby), while more generally figures as diverse as Beckerman, Harrod and Kaldor can be invoked, as can economists in key international economic organisations.21 Sixthly, it may well be that macroeconomists were generally less critical of ‘Stop-Go’ than those with direct industry interests, notably in the motor industry which was assumed to be particularly affected and to be a microcosm of Britain’s deeper economic problems.22

2.4.10 Of course, before 1967, and indeed for some time after, what also divided the economists and

the politicians, was what difference a devaluation of sterling would have made and to what extent other balance of payments issues were pressing constraints, these matters to which we now turn.

20 Upon which, see Jones (1987, chs 5–7). 21 On the evolution of economists’ views, see Hutchison (1968), Cohen (1971), Stewart (1977) and Blackaby

(1978), the last of these the successor National Institute volume to Dow (1964). Notable reports by international agencies include UN Secretariat of the Economic Commission for Europe (1964, ch. VI, pp. 23–32) and Hansen’s (1969) fiscal policy report for the OECD; see also Yeager (1966, p. 394).

22 It is noteworthy that recent research finds the motor vehicle industry’s problems of the 1950s and 1960s to have been so serious that, whilst ‘Stop-Go’ was not helpful, it was not decisive in explaining the long-term decline in its competitiveness (see Foreman-Peck et al.1995, esp. pp. 203–4).

Page 19: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 19 __________________________________________________________________________________________

§3. STERLING AND THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS 3.1 The ‘great unmentionable’ 3.1.1 Between 1964 and 1967 the Wilson government struggled desperately to manage the

unmanageable and to avoid the unavoidable, namely to deliver on its manifesto commitment to engineer a higher growth path for the British economy whilst maintaining the sterling exchange rate parity of $2.80.23 Although Wilson, and his chancellor, Callaghan, tried hard to make the topic of devaluation the ‘great unmentionable’ within Whitehall, they obviously could not control the broader debate outside of government. Even so, something of a self-denying ordinance of sorts was attained within the City and the media.24 Indeed, the press displayed a patriotism which is unimaginable today, so much so that for much of the period ‘open advocacy of devaluation was ... the next worse thing to publishing obscene literature’ (cited in Browning 1986, p. 5).25

3.1.2 Much macroeconomic and financial discourse was thus tacit, although quiescence and

deference should not be overstated because, on closer examination, whilst the financial press and indeed academic economic journals did not often mention the unmentionable, there were a steady number of books published on sterling and its predicament which did.26 However, with the permissible discourse being defined as it was, much of the arguments had to be presented as radical and polemical rather than as routine and inescapable.

3.2 Three weaknesses interact 3.2.1 We take as typical Hirsch’s The pound sterling: a polemic (1965).27 In reality, less a polemic

and more a measured analysis of Britain’s predicament, Hirsch identified (p. 24) three potential sources of pressure upon sterling, noting that ‘Sterling’s fundamental trouble is that since the war it has been vulnerable at all three points simultaneously’, to the extent that

23 General surveys of sterling and the balance of payments for all of our period are provided by Strange

(1971), Sinclair (1985), Foreman-Peck (1991) and Thirlwall and Gibson (1992). For a modern assessment of the particular problems of the Wilson years, see Woodward (1993); for assessments of contemporary thought by those professional economists involved, see Beckerman (1972), a locus classicus of the school that the 1964 failure to devalue fatally compromised Labour’s ability to deliver on its growth and modernising strategy, and Cairncross (1996a). Beckerman was an ‘irregular’ in George Brown’s Department of Economic Affairs, 1964–5, and then the Board of Trade, 1967–9 (upon which see his illuminating account in Beckerman 2000, pp. 165–79) while Cairncross was Economic Adviser to HM Government, 1961–4 and then Head, Government Economic Service, 1964–9.

24 By the 1960s media freedom was much extended and it is a salutary reminder that as late as 1955 the government sought to impose a rule on the BBC that its programmes would not deal with any topical issue for fourteen days preceding its debate in Parliament (Seymour-Ure 1991, pp. 62, 165–7). This rule was used by Shonfield (1965, p. 401) with great effect, in his magnificent comparative political economy of postwar European economic policies, to explore the peculiarities of the British system and situation.

25 Browning was the Treasury’s chief press officer. This episode forms one of the three case studies in Middleton (1998, pp. 253–68). Since this was published little new work has appeared, but see Bale (1999). Cairncross and Eichengreen (1983, pp. 159–60) refer also to a ‘conspiracy of silence in relation to devaluation ...economists hesitated to state publicly the case for devaluation, recognizing that, the more convincingly the case for devaluation was stated, the more difficult it would be for the government to bring it about smoothly and without speculative surges. In practice, as in time became evident, opinion formed itself without professional debate and enormous speculative positions were taken on assessments that rested on simple probabilities rather than economic diagnoses.’ Brittan (1971, ch. 8), one of the journalists with insider knowledge, was later to regret being a party to suppression of debate on patriotic grounds.

26 An incomplete listing of the most important includes Macrae (1963, esp. ch. XI ‘The curse of sterling’s status’), McMahon (1964), Hirsch (1965), Brandon (1966), Conan (1966) ***.

27 He was then Financial Editor, the Economist, 1963–6, from whence he moved to become Senior Advisor, IMF Research Department. Interestingly, the dust jacket front cover carries a sub-sub title (not reproduced on the book’s title page) ‘Devaluation: the issues’.

Page 20: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

20 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

when operating in unison they produced a statis in British economic policy:

• a purely trading deficit; • a net capital outflow; and • a run on what he termed the ‘sterling bank’, namely the weak foreign exchange reserves

position. 3.2.2 What mattered was the interaction of these three weaknesses; hence: ‘The continued deficit

or threatened deficit on trade and investment together has itself exposed the inadequacy of the reserves, making sterling less safe as a banking currency.’ Examining each of these weaknesses in turn, we begin with a longer-term perspective on Britain’s current account balance of payments, for too often contemporary discussions did not appreciate two historically distinctive characteristics of Britain’s golden age situation.

3.3 The current account balance of payments 3.3.1 We chart in Figure 6 the current account balance since 1870, from which the first of these

characteristics is immediately evident: Britain’s historic deficit on visible trade was much smaller than before the Second World War, and it was thus the diminished surplus on invisibles which underlay the overall deterioration in the current account. In any case, the narrowness of the amplitude of cyclical fluctuations in the current account balance, and the fact that this summary measure in an economy as open as that of Britain’s is the difference between two very large numbers, themselves subject to wide (but variable) margins of error, suggests not that the current account was in chronic deficit but that it was in approximate balance. Admittedly, on average the current balance was stronger in the 1950s than in the 1960s;28 yet, contemporary policy discourse, and particularly the ‘Stop-Go’ debate, was preoccupied with the ‘trade gap’ and thus operated with an overly simplistic notion of whether Britain paid its way, itself a discourse which more often than not was unhelpful in understanding the cause of Britain’s economic difficulties and the stock of remedies available.

FIGURE 6 Current account balance of payments as % of GDP, 1870-1997

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

1870

1880

1890

1900

1910

1920

1930

1940

1950

1960

1970

1980

1990

Source: Calaculated from Feinstein (1972, tables 3, 15); and ONS (1999, tables 1.3, 1.18).

% o

f GD

P

Visible trade balance Invisibles trade balance Current account balance

Struggling with the impossible, 1949-72

28 The point should be reiterated that the data in Figure 6 (and 7) are the most recent and thus the current

account appears stronger than it did to contemporaries (see §2.2.1***).

Page 21: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 21 __________________________________________________________________________________________

FIGURE 7 Current account balance of payments by sector as % of GDP, 1946-79

-4.0

-3.0

-2.0

-1.0

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

1946 1948 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978

Source: Middleton (1996, figure 12.1).

% o

f GD

P

Private sector Public sector Current account balance

3.3.2 This leads to the second characteristic which again must qualify our notion of chronic balance

of payments weakness during the golden age. As Figure 7 shows, from the end of the Korean War through to the Barber boom (1971–3), it was the substantial deficit on government’s international transactions account which was responsible for the overall current account balance dipping into deficit in times connected to, but not necessarily coincident with, the ‘Stop-Go’ cycle. Again, this fact was well-known in the policy community, as was its cause in Britain’s unwillingness to adjust its geo-political aspirations and obligations to match its diminished economic capacity which had been fatally compromised by relative economic decline and two ruinous world wars (which also transformed the UK’s balance of external assets and liabilities with consequent feedbacks from the capital to the current account balance of payments). There was accordingly no deficit on the private sector current account balance of payments until OPEC I.29

3.3.3 It is easy, indeed too easy, in retrospect to dismiss much of the contemporary preoccupation

with the balance of payments as ill-founded. It is, however, important why the ‘trade gap’ became something of a fetish, and equally why sterling’s value became a national virility symbol (it is important also that the very public struggle to defend the parity 1964–7 heightened its symbolic importance, upon which see Blaazer 1999). We have, therefore, to understand the symbolism and in particular to ground these issues within the developing preoccupation with economic decline. As Manser (1971, pp. 178–9) argued in an important and influential assessment which made the necessary connections:

The balance of payments is the English sickness. This is not because the British have a balance of payments that is any different from any other. It is because only the British make it a point of national conscience. ... The UK’s self-revulsion over the balance of payments is only part of a larger, and more long-lived process. For many years, since the 1939 war, and probably the war before that, Britain has felt herself to be on a gentle slide.... Confusedly, they saw in all the signs of greater power around them, evidence of failing ability and shrinking strength in themselves. Nothing, of course, could be farther from the truth. Objectively seen, Britain’s problem was that, through no fault of her own, the world had grown into

29 All of the polemical volumes on sterling published in the 1960s stressed this second characteristic. Strange

(1971, ch. 6) provides an excellent political economy assessment of why and with what consequences government overseas transactions impinged upon Britain’s balance of payments.

Page 22: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

22 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

dimensions beyond her own; she remained no less effective by her own standards ... But Britain persisted in the belief that she was in absolute decline ... Into this atmosphere erupted, for reasons of subtly similar causation, the postwar balance of payments problem. This, as though pre-ordained, became the magnet for all these disconsolate feelings. The trade balance was a first-class gauge of the country’s recovery. If we attained a surplus, we were on the mend. If we persisted in deficit, and our share of world trade went on declining, we were still heading for decay.

3.3.4 Economists, of course, rightly prefer to ground their analyses in terms of market

fundamentals, with sentiment an intangible and thus intractable. However, British electoral history demonstrates the shock value of the balance of payment,30 and indeed it is clear if we follow the adversary politics – rather than the postwar consensus– interpretation of pre-1979 British politics that sterling and the balance of payments had become highly politicised. As a component of demand management they had thus become a routine part of the cut and thrust of party political competition in which, from the late 1950s onwards, competing claims for competence in economic management were dominating that contest (Middleton 2000, pp. 70–2). In the resulting discourse sterling’s value and the state of the balance of payments become part cause and part consequence of that ongoing inquest into national economic decline; and, like demand management, they had a much higher profile in Britain than in most other ACCs (see Hansen 1969, p. 417), this of course a consequence of the way in which Keynesianism was incorporated into postwar British economic policy.

3.4 The capital account balance of payments 3.4.1 Progressing now to the second of the interacting weaknesses, that of a net capital outflow, we

have a further connection to the decline debate – one, however, not always made – and an element of continuity with earlier periods when the authorities sought sufficient of a current account surplus to fund a significant net outward long-term capital flow. The background here is Britain’s long-established status as a major outward investor and the City of London’s financial institutions that underpinned this, compounded by the postwar period having seen the rapid growth of multinational enterprise (MNE) activity between ACCs as part of the process of shifting international specialisation and the renaissance of globalisation after the autarky of the interwar years. Quantitatively, when net outward foreign direct investment (FDI) is related to GDP, the pressure on the capital account was actually far less after the Second World War than earlier in the century.31 This is hardly surprising given the reduction in the available current account surplus (Figure 6) and that, far from the City expanding and thriving at the expense of the rest of the economy (another component part of the Pollard thesis), as the British economy declined relatively so did the City of London (Michie 1992, pp. 25–8). Even so, such was the scale of outward FDI in relation to the available current account surplus that offsetting private short-term borrowing could become significant which, in turn, increased the vulnerability of sterling to speculative pressures. As we can see from Table 6, which uses then contemporary accounting definitions and measures of balance of payments equilibrium, years of current account surplus could thus be associated with a heavy 30 In the 1970 general election with the highly aberrant trade figures published three days before the election

date, this just following the English football team’s defeat by Germany in the World Cup (Butler and Pinto-Duschinsky 1971, pp. 166, 347n). Ironically, it is probable that these first published estimates were particularly pessimistic; shortly afterwards, the Board of Trade admitted that its procedures underestimated visible exports by about 2 per cent; while 1970 now appears from revised data as having not just a substantial current account surplus (1.8 per cent of GDP) but, unusually, a near zero balance to the visibles account.

31 Clegg (1996, table 2.1) estimates IDP coefficients (calculated as net outward investment divided by GDP and expressed as a percentage) as follows:

1914 56.7 1938 40.4 1960 8.1 1971 7.3

Page 23: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

TABLE 6 Balance of payments statistics (£m), 1951-70 Balance of

current and External

Exports Balance Balance on long-term Balance Index of Index of Gold and liabilities

(incl. re- Merchandise on long-term capital for import export Terms of convertible of the

Imports exports) trade Invisible current capital account official volume volume trade currency public

fob fob balance balance account account (basic balance) financing (1970=100) (1970=100) (1970=100) reserves sector

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (5a) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

1951 3,424 2,735 (689) 320 (369) n.a n.a. (334) 48 53 72 834 4,1431952

3,048 2,769 (279) 442 163 (134) 29 (175) 44 50 77 659 3,7861953 2,927 2,683 (244) 389 145 (194) (49) 296 48 51 82 899 4,0041954 2,989 2,785 (204) 321 117 (191) (74) 126 49 53 82 986 4,1791955 3,386 3,073 (313) 158 (155) (122) (277) (229) 55 57 81 757 4,0451956 3,324 3,377 53 155 208 (187) 21 (159) 55 59 83 799 4,0911957 3,538 3,509 (29) 262 233 (106) 127 13 56 60 85 812 3,9181958 3,377 3,406 29 317 346 (198) 148 290 57 58 91 1,096 3,9761959 3,642 3,527 (115) 287 172 (284) (112) 18 61 61 91 977 4,2121960 4,138 3,737 (401) 173 (228) (229) (457) 325 68 63 92 1,154 4,4321961 4,043 3,903 (140) 187 47 17 64 (339) 67 65 95 1,185 4,5041962 4,103 4,003 (100) 255 155 (141) 14 192 69 67 97 1,002 4,1061963 4,450 4,331 (119) 244 125 (160) (35) (58) 72 70 96 949 3,7371964 5,111 4,568 (543) 185 (358) (391) (749) (695) 75 72 94 827 3,8611965 5,173 4,913 (260) 230 (30) (244) (274) (353) 76 77 97 1,073 4,2731966 5,384 5,276 (108) 238 130 (193) (63) (547) 78 79 98 1,107 4,8441967 5,840 5,241 (599) 330 (269) (182) (451) (671) 84 82 100 1,123 5,1451968 7,145 6,433 (712) 468 (244) (167) (411) (1,410) 93 84 97 1,109 5,4281969 7,478 7,269 (209) 691 482 (97) 385 687 94 97 96 1,053 5,8421970 8,142 8,128 (14) 835 821 n.a 1,287 100 100 100 1,178 5,419Source: Thirlwall and Gibson (1994, tables 9.3, 9.4).

Page 24: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

24 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

balance for official financing (1952, 1956, 1961, 1963 and 1966). 3.4.2 The balance for official financing was defined as the basic balance (that is the balance on

current account plus long-term capital movements) plus private short-term capital movements. It was during this period the summary measured monitored closely because before 1970 private short-term capital movements were regarded as accommodating or financing the surplus/deficit of the current account, and it thus gave rise to an equilibrium measure of the financial pressure on the authorities from the point of view of maintaining the external value of the currency (Thirlwall and Gibson 1994, p. 9). As Table 6 shows between 1951 and 1970 whilst the current account was in deficit for only seven years there was a negative balance for official financing for eleven years.

3.4.3 MNE activity, of course, is only part of determinants of trends in Britain’s capital account

balance of payments, but it is an important part of that story and it needs to be linked more strongly to the various narratives about economic decline and in particular to those examining weak competitiveness in manufacturing. Our purpose here is not to identify the capital account for particular attention, nor indeed MNE activities, but to use them to reiterate the interrelatedness of the balance of payments and national economic decline stories in the context of the British economy being a leader in the globalisation of production.32

3.5 Sterling as a reserve currency and the foreign exchange reserves 3.5.1 We come then to the third and final interactive weakness: the foreign exchange reserves. The

question of the adequacy of international reserves, both for the system as a whole and for individual economies, was a lively topic of the 1950s but particularly the 1960s (Stern 1973, pp. 390–3), not least in Britain. Whilst the various international roles of sterling were being eclipsed by the dollar over one third of international trade was still being settled in sterling in the early 1960s (Cooper 1968, p. 180 n.71), such that the total global volume of sterling denominated transactions was of a magnitude that it could easily swamp available British reserves (Cohen 1971, pp. 72-3).

3.5.2 Whilst the precise criteria and level of reserve adequacy for the UK must remain in doubt, all

were agreed that in practice actual levels were inadequate to enable government to meet its macroeconomic objectives. Estimates vary but Heller’s (1966, table 1) results are suggestive: on his definition of optimal reserve levels, Britain had the lowest actual levels of all of the western European countries, and this without factoring in the margin required for key-currency status, let alone –as some maintained ought to be the case – some measure of provision for the outstanding liabilities of the Sterling Area. Moreover, if we focus specifically on the period in which the balance of payments was becoming established in policy-makers minds as the primary impediment to faster growth, we can see how complex and limited was the potential for replenishing the reserves and thus widening the policy space. Conan (1966, pp. 91–2) estimates that between 1958–63 the current account had a surplus of nearly £2bn with the overseas sterling area and a deficit of nearly £1.5bn with the non-sterling area, but that whilst the surplus contributed nothing to the reserves the deficit involved an equivalent drain. On capital account, UK exported £1bn of long-term capital to non-sterling countries but imported £1.4bn, resulting in an overall deficit of £400m. In sum, therefore, it was the deficit on capital account, not the surplus on current account, which was the effective agent in replenishing the reserves.

3.5.3 Many commentators by the early 1960s (Hirsch included) had no trouble in concluding that

32 Thus Williams et al. (1983, table 1) estimate that in 1971 UK overseas production was 215 per cent of UK

exports as against 37 per cent for West Germany and for Japan. The US figure was 393 per cent.

Page 25: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 25 __________________________________________________________________________________________

the burden of sterling’s reserve function had to be transferred to an international institution, such as the IMF (cf. Cohen’s 1971 important cost-benefit analysis of sterling’s international role which produced a less clear-cut case for full ‘domestication’ of the pound). James (1996, p. 186), in his official IMF history of the Bretton Woods system, is emphatic that ‘The instability caused by the sterling balance overhang and the danger of liquidation ... lay behind each of the major British crises of the second half of the 1960s.’ As is clear from Table 7, when we examine the anatomy of earlier sterling crises we see that factors relating to sterling’s international role and speculation predominated. This necessarily feeds back to our assessment of ‘Stop-Go’ and its significance, for many of the sceptical school (for example, Matthews 1969, p. 128) saw the three most important crises of our period (1957, 1961 and 1966) as not due to the state of the current account balance of payments, which was improving, but as essentially crises of confidence in sterling in which the remedies lay beyond macroeconomic policy.

3.6 The political economy of the balance of payments 3.6.1 For Hirsch, as for others who understood the British policy community, the trading

performance problems of the balance of payments were unnecessarily compounded by the unwillingness of successive governments to confront the Bank of England’s agenda for reconstructing the international pre-eminence of the City of London and the role that this would entail for sterling: an accelerated timetable for full convertibility (Green 1992, pp. 200–1, 204). As is now clear, nationalisation of the Bank in 1946 was ‘a great non-event’, a technical change of ownership which did not lead to a fundamental overhaul of British monetary policy (Middleton 1996, pp. 547–8).33 Monetary policy continued to be conducted on the basis of traditional and informal arrangements, with the Treasury’s efforts during the 1950s to develop monetary policy as a complement to fiscal policy being hindered by the Bank who were deeply resistant to monetary instruments becoming part of demand management and thus subordinate to government macroeconomic policy strategy (Lowe et al. 2002, ch. 5).

3.6.2 Once returned to power in 1951 the Conservatives pursued a rhetoric of ‘sterling strong and

free’ which resulted in accelerated liberalisation of trade and finance, with the driving force behind this being the Bank. As we now know from Fforde (1992) on the Bank, and from Robert Hall’s diaries (Cairncross 1989; 1991),34 Cairncross (1987) and others beginning to research the Treasury papers in the PRO, Treasury officials, and particularly the professional economists in the Economic Section of the Treasury, were frequently in conflict with the Bank over monetary policy, and especially over the Bank’s reluctance to restrict bank credit to make monetary policy more effective. We know that one result of this was that the government established the Radcliffe committee, from which emerged a report (HMSO 1959) which is typically taken as the triumph of Keynesian views as to the superiority of fiscal over monetary instruments in demand management, and which also led the Bank to be more transparent about its activities,35 not least in inaugurating the Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin in 1960 and the Central Statistical Office’s (CSO) Financial Statistics in 1962. However, less well known is how frequently these clashes were generated by strong 33 For recent assessments of postwar monetary policy, see Dimsdale (1981) and Howson (1994); for

contemporary assessments of our specific period, see Kennedy (1962), Dow (1964), Tew (1978a) and Artis (1978).

34 Hall was successively Director, Economic Section, Cabinet Office, 1947–53, and Economic Adviser to HM Government, 1953–61. He succeeded James Meade in the former post, and was in turn succeeded by Alec Cairncross in the latter.

35 It is generally accepted that the committee’s work, and especially chapter VI of the report (‘The influence of monetary measures’), was largely the product of its two academic economist members, Cairncross and Sayers, this now confirmed by the publication of the former’s diary for this period (Cairncross 1999). Sayers (1960) is, in turn, generally regarded as an exposition of the monetary theory implicit in the report.

Page 26: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

TABLE 7 Hirsch's (1965) assessment of eight sterling crises, 1947-65 Gold and Net reserves

Duration dollar at lowest Crisis period (months) Dates drain ($bn)a point ($bn)b Crisis cause

1. Convertibility crisis 1947 7 02.47-08.47 c.2.5 c2.0 Speculation; conversion: Britain's own dollar deficit increases after February fuel crisis; yet sterling still made convertible for most overseas holders in mid-July. Leads to massive conversion of foreign-held pounds into scarce dollars.

2. Devaluation crisis 1949 5.5 31.03.49-18.09.49 1.265 1.33 Mainly speculation; small deficit; price discrepancies: Deterioration of Britain's balance after 1948 recovery provokes gathering speculation on need for devaluation, urged by US and IMF.

3. Korean aftermath 1951-2 10 07.51-04.52 2.284 1.662 Large deficit; conversion; speculation: Big British deficit caused by rise in import prices and strains of rearmament coincides with sharp fall in export earnings of sterling area primary producers, following break in Korean commodity boom.

4. Floating rates crisis 1952

3 07.55-09.55

0.345

2.345

Small deficit; short sharp speculation: following official (secret) British advocacy of wider margins for

exchange rates to fluctuate.

5. Suez crisis 1956 5 08.56-12.56 0.845 1.572 Speculation alone: Britain in surplus, though burdened by some large conversions of Indian sterling balances, speeded by speculation. Size of withdrawals after Anglo- French landings in Egypt forces Eden government to request IMF and American help - which is granted only on condition of a cease fire. The one constructive sterling crisis?

6. 1957 crisis 2 08.57-09.57 0.7 1.85 Speculation alone: based on devaluation of French franc and expectation of revaluation of German mark. Britain has current payments surplus almost covering outflow; domestic worries about price inflation and fall in gilt-edged, but boom already passed the peak.

Page 27: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

7. 1961 crisis 5 03.61-07.61 1.62 1.56 Speculation follows deficit: revaluation of German mark in March causes intensive speculation against sterling: massive outflow of short-term funds that had financed 1960 deficit.

8. Whose crisis 1964-5 8 09.64-04.65 2.408 342 Speculation plus deficit: Deficit on current and long-term capital of near £800m (over $2bn) in 1964, financed in first eight months by inflow of short-term capital and build up of balances of overseas sterling area: followed by massive speculative

withdrawals.Notes: a Changes in reserves net of special credits, i.e. adding net drawings on all external credits to actual reserve loss. b Short-term and medium-term repayable credits (i.e. IMF and central bank credits, but not postwar American Loan in 1947) are deducted from reserve total. Source: Hirsch (1965, pp. 48-9).

Page 28: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

28Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58]__________________________________________________________________________________________

differences of opinion as to the appropriateness of the government’s fiscal stance, in particular its public expenditure plans, usually portrayed as a ‘burden’ by the Bank, and most particularly the investment programmes of the nationalised industries.

3.6.3 We have as yet not had the opportunity to explore the balance of payments dimension of this

conflict, although of course the way it came to a head in the early days of the Wilson government in October 1964 is now well-known.36 We do know, however, that ‘throughout the 1950s the Treasury worked assiduously with the Bank ... to foster the development of London’s international role’ and that, from the late nineteenth century onwards, ‘the basic tenet of the Treasury’s position has been that the City’s earnings have been either a mark of underlying prosperity or the means to achieve prosperity’ (Green 1992, p. 212). Given that, compared with the interwar period, it was the invisibles account that had changed greatly for the worst, there was a certain rationality to this position. We must guard, however, against assuming that the Treasury can be treated as one institution with one voice on these matters: as Peden (2000) has shown there were frequent conflicts between the overseas finance (OF) division and those officials responsible for more domestic policy issues, whilst as Opie (1968) and Brittan (1971) argued at the time there existed an ‘overseas lobby’ within Whitehall which in its effectiveness and influence challenged one of the precepts of national economic policy. Thus, as Brittan (1971, p. 471) put it:

One does not need to have any truck with the more chauvinistic forms of patriotism to be mildly disturbed by the number of departments which approached economic problems primarily from the point of view of international negotiation, and how few are professionally concerned to put forward the interests of this country, ‘let alone of something as materialistic and crude as the standard of living’.

3.6.4 Next we come to the matter of balance of payments statistics and the interests and institutions

that underlay their production and interpretation. We have already noted that these were subject to frequent, on-going revision. The inadequacies of these data, indeed the whole infrastructure of national account and other economic data, was considered in quite some detail by the Radcliffe report (HMSO 1959, ch. X). It was by then very noteworthy that there was a growing discrepancy between official estimates of the deficit on the basic balance measure and the net changes in reserves, overseas sterling holdings and other items that comprised the balance of monetary movements, the residual being the ‘balancing item’. This was always positive, indicating the under-recording of credit items, but it became very strongly positive in 1960 and 1961 (Bank of England 1962, p. 16; 1964). Moreover, as McMahon (1964, p. 20), at this time writing for the Royal Institute of International Affairs rather than the National Institute, observed:

... what is the point of all of this? Lumping movements of volatile short-term claims and liabilities in with current receipts and payments and long-term capital movements will simply blur an important distinction ... Surely an ‘overall’ deficit of £200 million together with a private monetary inflow of £300 million would represent a greatly inferior position to that of an ‘overall’ surplus of £100 million and no net private monetary movements? Yet they would both imply a ‘market’ surplus of £100 million.

3.6.5 He went on to quote from an earlier National Institute (Major 1962, p. 58) comment on the

British data: ‘Thus, the balance of payments can be regarded as anything from indifferent to potentially disastrous according to the view taken of the balancing item.’ Concurrently, IMF officials were both developing procedures for standardising balance of payments concepts and data and becoming concerned about the British situation (de Vries 1987, chs 2–4), and whilst we need to guard against making too much of balance of payments statistics in its own 36 The view of an ‘inherited crisis’ and attempted bankers’ ramp of October-November 1964 is put forcefully

by Wilson in his memoirs, with his distrust of Cromer, Governor 1964-6, barely concealed (Wilson 1971, pp. 33, 34–8, 129, 251). On the appointment of Cromer’s successor, Leslie O’Brien, Governor 1966–71, Wilson (p. 251) noted: ‘We now had a totally professional, cool and competent central banker ...’

Page 29: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 29__________________________________________________________________________________________

right it is legitimate to ask – as did many contemporaries – whether some of the speculative pressures endured might have been lessened if the British authorities had moved more quickly to both modernise the presentation of the accounts and to improve on the under-recording of credit items.

3.6.6 There is an obvious parallel here with the delay in reforming the budget accounts to

accommodate the reality of Keynesian demand management and the developing national accounts framework, where there was much friction between the Treasury – anxious about its traditional public expenditure control functions – and the economists-statisticians of the CSO (Lowe et al. 2002, ch. 6). The role of Bank officials in these debates and, more generally, official Whitehall thinking on the development of balance of payments statistics, needs to be investigated now that the papers are available. The costs, for suppliers and collectors of such data, will obviously need to be taken into account, and there are suggestions that these issues were particularly relevant to the on-going problem of under-recording exports (Balacs 1972, p. 44). Given that the incoming Labour government was ill-prepared for the balance of payments and sterling crisis it faced in October-November 1964, an adjunct to that investigation must be whether attention was devoted to improving the presentation skills of the key actors and the reception of economic and financial data by the markets.

3.6.7 The balance of payments situation and the roles of sterling raise bigger questions about power

and governance in two important senses. These were first, at the centre of government, where efforts at modernization devised in response to the growing perception of decline challenged existing relationships within Whitehall and between Whitehall and key interests groups. Treasury-Bank conflicts have already been noted in this respect, but beyond this it should be observed that the ‘external constraint’ was variously deployed to promote or to retard some of the more radical proposals for modernisation. Thus it is part of folklore amongst economic radicals that the 1965 National Plan was stillborn, possibly murdered by the refusal to devalue (for example, Opie 1972, pp. 170–1). Conflict between the Department of Economic Affairs (DAE) and the Treasury was endemic, and in some minds to be encouraged in pursuit of a ‘creative tension’ in British economic policy which would at last bring the supply side to the foreground (Clifford 1997; Clifford and McMillan 1997). The struggle being played out between the Treasury and the DAE was thus, to its critics in the City, one between financial and structural remedies which translated into more or less market friendly or inherently dirigistic solutions, the latter, of course connected with – in a delicious phrase from a leading financial journalist of the time – the ‘Hungarian goulash’ (Davis 1968, ch. 5) of Balogh and Kaldor. Even earlier, the Suez humiliation had brought forth a fundamental defence review (the Sandys white paper of 1957) which sent shock waves throughout Whitehall and which began a process of global disengagement which was to accelerate in the 1960s, one eventually bringing relief of sorts to the balance of payments. Although Suez was an accelerant rather than a cause of this disengagement, sterling weakness (upon which see Johnman 1989 and Klug and Smith 1999) was used strategically by Macmillan, now prime minister but previously chancellor, and others to promote their broader ambitions.37

3.6.8 We have secondly a national sovereignty dimension to this, one we introduced earlier with

Manser’s (1971) diagnosis of the balance of payments as an English sickness, and which we now need to develop. It is axiomatic that postwar British political economy was conducted in terms of a number of polarities and that whatever the rhetoric the reality of government policy typically required extensive resort to smoke and mirrors. At the domestic economic policy level, the cross-party rhetoric was that full employment was the pre-eminent policy objective whereas, contra Keynes and the spirit of the Keynesian revolution, it was the pursuit of external balance which always prevailed until the ill-fated Barber boom of 1971–3 37 On sterling, see Johnman (1989) and Klug and Smith (1999); on the broader crisis, Freedman et al. (1988).

Page 30: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

30 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

(Middleton 1989), the one time when the initial current account balance of payments surplus was deemed sufficiently durable to merit a ‘dash for growth’ (we discount the Maudling dash of 1962–4 because the initial starting point was much weaker and the onus was placed on ‘Keynesian plus’ to deliver salvation).

3.6.9 In terms of external economic policy, there was a coincident and related myth of continued

national macroeconomic autonomy which was underpinned by an interpretation of Britain’s joint role with the US in the framing and development of the Bretton Woods system and in the ongoing Anglo-American ‘special relationship’. Wilson’s railing against the gnomes of Zurich hid a bitter truth, one admittedly always more difficult for a Labour government: the ability of international markets to discipline even democratic governments. The reality, of course, was that ‘sterling [w]as the dollar’s first line of defense’ (Eichengreen 1996a, p. 125; also James 1996, p. 186), this severely limiting the UK’s room for manoeuvre and thus the policy space. Britain’s international economic diplomacy was similarly constrained, but here it was a combination of de facto US client status and burgeoning post-colonial guilt which operated to condition what was thought to be possible (Reynolds 2000, ch. 8). Set against the background of growing globalisation of trade and capital by the 1960s, increased competition in western Europe as those economies not only recovered fully from the war but appeared to overtake Britain, it is not difficult to see how the assumption of economic superiority that had guided policy-makers for so long became increasingly unsustainable and that consequently the search for remedies for economic decline became ever more desperate.

§4. EXCHANGE RATE POLICY 4.1 Assessing exchange rate choices 4.1.1 Our starting point for assessing British exchange rate policy is with Joan Robinson’s

observation (1937, p. 154), made shortly after the General theory’s (1936) publication, that there is no unique, policy-free equilibrium exchange rate which accords with balance of payments equilibrium. The notion of such an equilibrium rate is accordingly a chimera, and since the General theory’s publication we have come to understand and to make exchange rate choices within a framework that there are an infinite number of equilibrium rates which correspond to various mixes of demand and supply conditions and monetary, fiscal, trade and other policies. Much of that framework, of course, was developed into the open economy macro model by the subjects of this conference.38 Interpreting the historian’s brief here to provide data and background for the economists to consider the transition path between developments in theory and policy in practice, we here focus on what our current understanding is of British policy from devaluation in 1949 through to the decision to float sterling in June 1972.

4.1.2 Before embarking upon that assessment we need to comment, in relation to the British

situation, on the three stylised facts that preface Kenen’s (1985, pp. 628-36) literature review of how the closed economy macroeconomic model of Keynes’s General theory was opened. We can confirm the first two stylised facts: those concerning the preference for government over the market in exchange rate management, and of the dominance of the Keynesian model (and of the operational assumption that government could deliver macroeconomic stability) in the evolving system of national economic management. Indeed, so far as Britain is concerned, the balance struck in favour of government rather than the market and the dirigiste

38 The locus classicus for the development of open economy macroeconomics is Kenen (1985) which, for a

fuller historical perspective, can be supplemented by Flanders (1989). Both can usefully be supplemented by Mussa (1979) and Isard (1995).

Page 31: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 31__________________________________________________________________________________________

policies that resulted produced, in terms of the models of capitalism literature, a distinctly mid-Atlantic hybrid: one neither resembling American nor continental European practice (Middleton 1996). We take issue, however, with his third stylised fact, that of the insularity of national economies, which in turn was derived from three characteristics:

(1) The share of foreign trade in gross national product was relatively small and, more important,

substantial trade barriers restricted the role of commodity arbitrage. In consequence, exchange rates could be changed without significant effects on domestic prices. Domestic prices were determined by domestic wages, and wages were determined by conditions in domestic labor markets. The Phillips curve was firmly anchored even before it was discovered.

(2) The international capital market did not function freely. Therefore, private capital movements could not automatically finance deficits and surpluses on current account. By implication, those deficits and surpluses could not raise or reduce asset stocks or wealth by enough to induce large changes in aggregate demand. (The private flows that did occur could also continue for long periods, because they were small in relation to the corresponding stocks.)

(3) The national monetary systems were insulated. On the one hand, official intervention in foreign-exchange markets were sterilized; they did not affect the monetary base. On the other hand, short-term rates could be controlled by monetary policy; they were not influenced by foreign rates or exchange-rate expectations. [Kenen 1985, p. 636]

4.1.3 Kenen uses Grassman’s (1980) data on the long-term openness of economies, taking as his

measure exports plus imports as a share of GNP. This data shows that Britain largely regained its traditional openness in trade quickly after the war, with openness then relatively stable from the mid-1950s through to the mid-1970s whereas other ACCs (including the US, a far less open economy) had a delayed catch-up and then an accelerated trend to greater openness, which of course for the original EEC member states was influenced by the trade creation effects of that customs union. On international capital markets, we agree that they did not function freely but would contend that Britain was again a special case and that consequently international capital market activity was particularly relevant to the financing of the British the balance of payments. Finally, the British monetary system was by no means insulated; indeed, that it was not is central to the ‘Stop-Go’ phenomenon and thus to the policy-makers dilemmas. Part of our thesis is thus that the British economy and sterling its national currency were in the vanguard of renewed globalisation. To an important extent this determined its exchange rate choices, or more often non-choices.

4.2 Devaluation, 1949 4.2.1 The September 1949 devaluation (from $4.03 to $2.80 to the pound) was at the time, as it

remains today, the subject of much debate.39 Generally represented fatalistically, as largely inevitable given the convertibility crisis of 1947, and as mainly driven by the requirements of Anglo-American relations, this episode encapsulates most if not all of the dilemmas present for policy makers in conducting national economic management and exchange rate policy in particular. The similarities and continuity with later episodes should not, however, be overdone: this was still a time of intensive postwar reconstruction, the background was one of a fully (indeed over-fully) employed economy operating within an extensive system of physical controls and, notwithstanding the undeniable policy achievements since the end of the war, there was a pervading anxiety about whether a postwar slump, domestically and internationally, could ultimately be avoided.

4.2.2 The dominant questions were: was a change in the parity necessary; and, if so, by how much;

and what accompanying adjustments to demand- and supply-side policies ought there to be? Some key figures in the British economics establishment (for example, Hawtrey, Henderson 39 Cairncross and Eichengreen (1983, ch. 4) represents our current knowledge, supplement by the more

recent, often more general works of Cairncross (1985, esp. ch. 7), Pressnell (1987; 2001), Burnham (1990), Schenk (1994), Tomlinson (1997) and Toye (2000).

Page 32: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

32 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

and Harrod) opposed the devaluation at the time and subsequently; indeed, Hawtrey maintained to the end that Britain’s postwar economic problem was not an overvalued but an undervalued currency which resulted in domestic excess demand. They were certainly not lone voices, either amongst the economists outside government, nor inside, nor indeed some of the politicians involved, in fearing that in circumstances of a supply-constrained economy a devaluation would simply result in an adverse turn in the terms of trade without producing a significant correction to the current account balance of payments.

4.2.3 One of the most penetrating assessments of this risk was actually provided before the

devaluation, by Meade (1948) in his LSE inaugural lecture. Meade’s position is particularly important, not just because he was at that time developing what would become The theory of international economic policy (1951; 1955a),40 but because he would become a forceful and influential exponent of a managed float for sterling (Meade 1955b).41 Meade’s pioneering work on reconciling internal and external balance was already most attentive to the pass-through effects of a devaluation if higher import prices fed through to higher money wages (a problem that Friedman 1953, another early exponent of floating, also conceded), But in the development of the open economy macro model it must be remembered that the manner in which Meade defined external balance at this time excluded the capital account, and thus although his developing work on policy assignment (monetary and fiscal instruments to attain internal balance, the exchange rate for external balance) was relevant to both British policy and theory it was not until Mundell (1962; 1963) recasts internal and external equilibrium by redefining the balance of payments to include the capital account that we have a fuller and more effective role for monetary policy in the assignment of instruments and objectives.

4.2.4 We see then that from an early point there was concern about incipient inflation in relation to

exchange rate policy. In fact, for British policy makers these anxieties had interwar antecedents, while of course after September 1931 the exchange rate regime was one of a managed float.42 Moreover, in contrast to the interwar period, we have full employment since the Second World War, and we know that right from outset of planning for postwar employment policy there was a recognition (best represented in Kalecki’s classic 1943 paper) that the eradication of unemployment would alter the political economy of the labour market with consequent risks for inflation. The call for sterling to be floated was, however, muted and underdeveloped in 1949, as was professional economists’ opposition to devaluation. Policy-makers at this time operated with a conception of Britain’s limited room for manoeuvre born of their deep commitment to international economic cooperation; they had little time for longer-term, strategic thinking which might redefine what a purely British national interest might be. In any case, British balance of payments and/or sterling crises provide a low signal to noise ratio, one which concentrated the minds of policy makers on the here and the now to the exclusion of almost everything else.

4.2.5 What then can we discern in this first episode? First, 1949 is unusual because the official US

position was one of encouraging the UK to adjust the parity, whereas British officials used the prospect of devaluation as a bargaining counter in Anglo-American negotiations on trade, finance etc. Moreover, when devaluation did eventually occur it ‘may also have helped to 40 He was also, of course, a former Director of the Economic Section and had been a central figure in the

diffusion of Keynesian ideas during the war, being decisive (with Dick Stone) in the development of national income accounting and its use in macroeconomic policy and in the white paper which committed government to the maintenance of a high and stable level of employment after the war, this taken by many as the formal recognition of the Keynesian revolution in British economic policy.

41 He was, however, amongst the professional economists the only witness before the Ratcliffe committee who entertained the idea of a floating rate, this noted in the report (HMSO 1959, para. 719) and used as a partial justification for preserving the status quo.

42 See, for example, Howson’s (1975, app. 4) assessment of the 1931 devaluation, and her analysis of sterling’s managed float, 1931–9 (Howson 1980).

Page 33: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 33__________________________________________________________________________________________

reduce US criticism of the “restrictivist” aspect of British policy as it showed a willingness to let the price mechanism be used to try and correct the payments position’ (Tomlinson 1997, p. 36). But there is also a continuity here, with a polarity that resonates for the ensuing British policy debate of whether shifting relative prices through the price mechanism or something more fundamental is required to attain external balance. Thus, for Labour the lesson learnt from 1949 was that for political reasons it must never again be branded the ‘party of devaluation’, whilst such was the intractability of Britain’s economic problems that it was planning not the price mechanism that needed to be invoked. Accordingly, when Labour confronted the issue of devaluation once more, on taking office in 1964, it was distrust of the price mechanism that was critical in Wilson’s thinking, and in his account of this later episode the lessons of 1949 reverberate strongly (Wilson 1971; see also Stewart 1977, pp. 27–8).

4.2.6 Secondly, devaluation was inextricably linked to issues of confidence, a means thereby of

fusing politics and economics. It provided a veil behind which opponents – insiders as much as outsiders – of government policy could unite to strengthen their positions; thus, the devaluation issue was ‘spun’ by its opponents as a loss of confidence in the parity being equivalent to a loss of confidence in the whole conduct of economic policy. Cobbold, the Governor of the Bank (1949–64), made no secret of his view that public expenditure should be cut and the nationalisation programme halted if further US assistance was to be attained, whilst senior Treasury civil servants wrote memoranda on the ‘burden’ of government expenditure: all further evidence of the qualified nature of the Keynesian revolution in economic policy in early postwar Britain. In this case the bogy of confidence and the rhetoric of excessive government were not decisive in the subsequent decision, but the die was cast and once exchange controls loosened they were to be much more decisive forces.

4.2.7 Thirdly, the compelling factor in this episode – as later – was the parlous state of the reserves,

but ‘the corollary was not drawn that ways must be found of reinforcing reserves either at once or at least in time to withstand further pressure of the same kind’ (Cairncross and Eichengreen 1983, p. 139). This in turn resulted from the multiplicity of justifications that the pro- and anti-devaluation camps expounded, together with confusion about what accompanying measures there need be to make devaluation (or non-devaluation) effective: how was competitiveness to be improved and/or resources redeployed. And, in turn, amidst the bombardment of claim, counter-claim and confusion the domination of short-term considerations was enhanced when it is arguable that longer-term thinking needed to be decisive. Examination of the Treasury and other papers in the PRO shows that officials and ministers in practice had little opportunity to carefully consider the pros and cons of the matter. It was the loss of reserves that settled the matter, and no amount of entreaties by the Chancellor about the commitment to the parity were effective once the speculative momentum was established because market operators were only too well aware of the uniquely difficult circumstances faced by the British authorities.

4.2.8 Finally, a number of other characteristics are evident:

1. Devaluation was delayed beyond the period of maximum advantage. Although obviously hindsight matters here, it is the case that in 1949, as later, there was a presumption against surprising the markets;

2. The measures to accompany the devaluation were considered separately and after the event: policy was not as ‘joined-up’ as it might have been;

3. In 1949 at least, the decisive actors in the decision were not the Chancellor, nor the prime minister, nor even other senior ministers with economic briefs. Rather, the running was made, and the impetus provided, by three young and relatively junior figures, all incidentally economists (Gaitskell, Jay and Wilson).

Page 34: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

34 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

4. The background to the crisis was one of an overall current account balance of payments surplus: the crisis arose after one of the most sustained improvements from a payments deficit ever seen (from a deficit of 8.8 per cent in GDP in 1945 to a surplus of 0.9 and 0.5 per cent in 1948 and 1949 respectively);43 and

5. Amidst the confusion of debate we should highlight the role of rhetoric: the invocation of national prestige, the reliance upon moral arguments concerning obligation as lines of defence for the status quo.

4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 4.3.1 This episode has acquired something of a reputation as a missed opportunity to alter radically

the whole trajectory of postwar economic policy by floating sterling (and thus attaining nominal convertibility) and acting decisively on the sterling balance overhang - in effect, taking the strain off the reserves and putting it on the exchange rate.44 Originating as a joint Bank-Treasury proposal made shortly after the Conservative’s regained power in October 1951, amidst a developing Korean War induced sterling and balance of payments crisis, ‘Operation ROBOT’45 has been invested with much counterfactual authority: had it been adopted, it is said, the postwar settlement of the balance between government and market would have shifted decisively towards the latter and, with the external constraint lessened, ‘Stop-Go’ might never have occurred and thus there would have been less scope for its supposed growth-inhibiting effects. Big claims have thus been made in certain quarters for ROBOT, not least from Dell (1996, p. 194) that ‘Never again would a British government contemplate the possibility of imposing its policy on its external economic environment. In 1952, for the last time, the thought was there that it might be attempted.’ After Suez, which revealed the reality of dependence on America and the chimera of Britain’s great power posturing, the room for independence in exchange rate policy was greatly reduced.

4.3.2 With the official papers now available, at least for the Treasury (if less so the Bank), the

ROBOT episode has now been extensively investigated. Historical revisionism being what it is, it will come as no surprise that the most recent works have downgraded the radicalism of ROBOT , at least in its implications for the domestic economy. ROBOT is now understood as more the product of contingent circumstances than of some generalised reaction against the (domestic and international) postwar settlement. Opinions have hardened too about whether it was ever a viable proposition, although it should be noted that none of the three principal advocates ever published their mature reflections on this episode whilst many of those who had opposed the scheme have been active in promoting their version of events and their significance. 43 Of course, contemporary statistics portrayed a less rosy picture, but it was still one of a surplus. 44 The Robot episode has recently been the subject of a number of scholarly investigations, by Milward et al.

(1992, pp. 351–9), Proctor (1993), Schenk (1994, esp. pp. 114–19), Bulpitt and Burnham (1999), Peden (2000, pp. 458–62) and Burnham (2000); also less scholarly, more polemical works such as Dell (1996, ch. 5). There are a number of accounts by participants, including the then Chancellor (1951–5), Butler (1971) (+), and MacDougall (1987, ch. 5; 1989) (-) and Plowden (1989, ch. 14) (-), two insider economists; and by informed outsiders of various degrees of closeness to the centre of power, including Cairncross and Watts (1989, esp. pp. 302–9) (-) in their history of the Economic Section. Robert Hall’s (-) diaries are valuable (Cairncross 1989), as is Fforde (1992) who provides the story from the Bank’s side. The +/- in parentheses indicates whether the participant/observer was for/against the proposals of Operation Robot.

45 Sometimes referred to as the ‘External Sterling Plan’, ‘ROBOT’ had two meanings: the first that of rebalancing economic policy by putting it on an automatic pilot (a floating exchange rate, this determined by the operation of the price mechanism); and the second, a derivation from the names of its three principal advocates, Sir Leslie ROwan (Head, Overseas Finance, Treasury), Sir George Bolton (Bank of England Executive Director principally concerned with overseas finance) and Sir Richard (OTto) Clarke (Under-Secretary, Overseas Finance Treasury), the last of these an unusually dynamic and intellectually adventurous Treasury official, ‘an example of the truth that someone who can draft well and quickly can acquire enormous influence. The influence thus acquired is not always benign’ (Dell 1996, pp. 166–7).

Page 35: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 35__________________________________________________________________________________________

4.3.3 What then can we conclude for our purposes? First, that the attractions of a floating rate, hitherto largely confined to the professional economists in or associated with the Economic Section, had now been recognised by some in the core economic policy-making community (including very importantly the Bank). Secondly, although matters had not progressed to the point that the incoming government had campaigned for a floating rate (far from it), the rhetoric of ‘sterling strong and free’ could be interpreted in this light, and this seems to be how Butler saw it and was thus attracted to ROBOT. In his memoirs Butler (1971, pp. 158–9) made much of this episode:

In the long-term ... I believe that the decision not to free the pound was a fundamental mistake. The absence of a floating exchange rate robbed successive Chancellors of an external regulator for the balance of payments corresponding to the internal regulator provided by Bank rate. If such a regulator had existed, and a floating rate had been accepted, Conservatives would have been saved some of the uncertainties and indignities of ‘stop-go’ economics and Socialists the traumatic experience of a second formal devaluation.

4.3.4 Cairncross and Watts (1989, p. 303 n. 1) warn against Butler’s mature reflections, indicating

(but without citing a source) that Butler admitted to Bridges, Permanent Secretary, Treasury (1946–56), that he was wrong in supporting ROBOT at the time.46 We should note also that by the time his memoirs were published Bretton Woods was in its deaththroe and sterling was on the brink of finally being floated. Howard’s (1987, pp. 184–9) life of Butler adds little to our detailed knowledge of events, but he is convincing that whilst Butler was not bounced into supporting ROBOT his status as one of the most circumscribed Chancellors in recent history made him susceptible to its surface appeal as he sought to define his chancellorship. It is, of course, critical that the impending sterling crisis of which ROBOT’s proponents warned did not actually transpire (the Bank had taken far too pessimistic a position on the vulnerability of sterling), whilst the ‘freedom’ and the widening of the policy space for which the Conservatives hankered was potentially available through the reactivation of monetary policy: Bank rate having been unchanged since 1939 it was symbolically moved up from 2 to 2½ per cent shortly after assuming office and then onward to 4 per cent in the March 1952 budget. The end of the Korean War, and the ensuing peace dividend, then widened the fiscal policy space yet further, at least in the short- to medium-term.

4.3.5 The manner of ROBOT’s defeat, and the passions that it had aroused, ensured that the issue

of a floating rate was kicked into touch for at least a decade as a potential political option.47 It continued to surface as something worthy occasionally of economic debate within the Treasury48 and in the Bank,49 but typically amongst the economists the positions taken were not straightforward because what ROBOT had done was to conflate the issues of a fixed vs. flexible exchange rate with that of when convertibility might be attained and how it would be defined. Thus some policy insiders who one would expect to favour a floating rate, such as

46 Cairncross and Watts’ (1989) warning, however, is somewhat weakened when a little later (p. 309) they

report that Butler was still in favour of a floating rate in 1958, by this time no longer being Chancellor. 47 Strictly speaking, the formal demise of the floating option came with the defeat later in 1952–3 of what

was known as the Collective Approach, a plan for a return to convertibility at a flexible exchange rate which arose at the behest of the Commonwealth Finance Minister’s Conference of January 1952, involved a working party on convertibility and eventually its rejection as an option by the Randall Commission on External Monetary Policy which was presented to the US Congress in January 1954 (Schenk 1994, pp. 119–23).

48 For example, during the Suez crisis, but floating with weak reserves considered unviable (Peden 2000, p. 465).

49 James (1996, pp. 99–100) notes that ‘As late as 1958, the Governor of the Bank of England whilst arguing on practical grounds against floating, still added: “It would be prudent to organize monetary policy both at home and abroad, on the probability that something like a unified floating-rate policy is inevitable but to make no attempt to force the pace until it becomes more acceptable to the Western world as a whole.” Floating attracted the Bank ... because it would allow greater room for interest rates as an instrument for the control of the domestic UK economy.’

Page 36: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

36 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

Hall and Plowden,50 who were broadly ‘expansionists’, did not because of the implications of early convertibility for sterling and the balance of payments. Moreover, fad and fashion came into play. As Brittan (1964, pp. 173–4) put it in the first edition of his insider-inspired account of the Treasury in the 1950s and 1960s:

In the early 1950s the idea that we could dispose of our balance of payments problem by leaving sterling to its own devices was advocated by economists and politicians who were regarded as Right Wing. Indeed, every Conservative Chancellor before Mr Selwyn Lloyd [1960–2] seriously considered letting the pound float up and down to find its own level in the world currency markets. If no one took the plunge it was through lack of nerve rather than doctrinal inhibitions. It was among ‘progressive’ and ‘Left of centre’ economists that exchange rate changes were violently opposed as a false solution that did not get to the root of the difficulties. Today the pendulum has swung right back. Any thought of touching sterling is denounced in leading articles and political and City columns as irresponsibly extreme - too extreme for the official leaders of the Labour Party; and economists who believe in floating rates (mostly moderate Lib-Labs in their politics) are treated almost as bomb-carrying Bolsheviks.

4.3.6 Full de jure convertibility of sterling was not permitted until December 1958, although in

practice February 1955 is the more important watershed, that when de facto sterling was made convertible into dollars and other foreign currency for all non-residents at or very near the $2.80 parity. The path to convertibility and the pace of the journey were constantly pressed by the Bank and the OF division of the Treasury; they were resisted by what Brittan (1971, p. 198) calls the ‘anti-laissez-faire wing’ of the Treasury. This fault line,51 in effect that between those privileging the interests of the financial and those of the real economy, was to endure, albeit much reconfigured as the 1950s progressed and the case for institutional restructuring of the Treasury and of fundamental economic policy reform gathered pace. With floating kicked into touch, and with the overseas finance lobby in the ascendant, the domestic finance (anti-laissez-faire) wing of the Treasury would eventually begin to move towards more fundamental solutions for slow growth and balance of payments weaknesses.

4.3.7 Economic growth was, of course, emerging by the late 1950s as a policy objective in its own

right, not just as a means of attaining ultimate economic objectives (Tomlinson 1996). This marked not just an addition to existing policy objectives, nor a simple shift in emphasis between them. Rather, the mid-late 1950s were the beginnings of a preoccupation with national economic and political decline which is still being played out today; and in particular it was part and parcel of Britain’s relations with Europe: ‘the story of fifty years in which Britain struggled to reconcile the past she could not forget with the future she could not avoid’. This delicious phrasing from Young’s (1998, p. 1) brilliant analysis of Britain in Europe could so easily be applied to the preoccupation with sterling and most other aspects of economic management in relation to the ongoing inquest into national economic decline.

4.3.8 What matters here is that with floating off the agenda, and declinism emerging as a dominant

motif in domestic political competition and thus a central preoccupation of policy-makers, there was an opportunity to confront traditional assumptions, institutional structures and deep-seated problem areas of the postwar settlement of the (Keynesian-Beveridge) managed-mixed economy welfare state. What ensued was, by British standards, an extraordinary period of institutional and policy experimentation and innovation: a ‘great reappraisal’ (Brittan 1964, ch. 7), ‘a “revolt against orthodoxy”’ (Ringe and Rollings 2000, p. 336; see also Pemberton 2000; 2001). There resulted new institutions of policy advice and policy- 50 Edwin Plowden, Chief Planning Officer, Treasury and Chairman, Economic Planning Board, 1947–53;

Chairman, Committee on public expenditure (HMSO 1961). 51 For post-ROBOT external financial policy the following relies upon Peden (2000, pp. 462–5) and

discussions with my fellow project members. Peden does not emphasis this fault line within the policy-making community; Cairncross and Watts (1989, chs 17–18), however, highlight tensions between OF and the Economic Section.

Page 37: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 37__________________________________________________________________________________________

making: the National Economic Development Council (NEDC) and its supporting National Economic Development Office (both 1962), and, eventually, the Department of Economic Affairs (1964). This period, which we might date from the October 1959 general election through to the first year or so of the Labour government first elected in October 1964, also saw the instruments of demand management augmented with the ‘regulator’, for fine-tuning purposes, and an incomes policy, not just in the hope of effecting a leftwards shift in the Phillips curve but to promote the corporatism that underpinned NEDC and planning; it resulted in a whole raft of supply-side initiatives, principally relating to indicative planning but also important reforms to taxation and industrial training (so-called ‘Keynesian plus’ policies); and marked a profound shift in geo-political direction with the decision to seek membership of the EEC, the first of these applications (1959) necessarily leading policy-makers to rethink the sterling problem in terms of Europe as much as America and the second (1967), much influenced by the sterling crisis of summer 1966 (Young 2000, pp. 88–9), concentrating minds on the parity.

4.3.9 In 1959 the Radcliffe report then confirmed that floating was neither a viable nor a necessary

course of action, justifying this in terms of interwar ‘experience ... [being] sufficient to demonstrate both the inconvenience of a fluctuating pound and the impossibility of altering its value without regard to the interests of other countries which use sterling as an international currency’ (HMSO 1959, para. 710). It did, however, give some attention to when a devaluation might be permissible to maintain competitiveness and thus current balance of payments equilibrium, but emphasised ‘everything possible should be done to bring the rise in domestic costs and prices under control’ (HMSO 1959, paras 715–16). With floating thus completely off the agenda, high hopes were thus entertained for the great reappraisal, as were great fears by the ‘forces of conservatism’ whose commitment to the Keynesian economic management aspects of the postwar settlement were always circumscribed by the prior claims of a more traditional political economy.

4.3.10 For what we might call the economic radicals, both inside and outside of government, this

was an exciting time, this excitement long predating the prospect of a Labour government which attracted so many within the British economics profession (and would eventually disillusion so many).52 The modernisation of government had been an explicit objective since Macmillan left the Treasury to become prime minister in 1957, and certainly the Plowden report on the control of public expenditure (HMSO 1961) had much more far-reaching effects on the Treasury’s structure, organisation and personnel that just public expenditure control (Lowe 1997), although the longer-term planning of expenditure programmes was itself very important and very pertinent to concerns about ‘Stop-Go’. The arrival of new personnel, replacements at the top, but above all the new structure established in 1962 of a unified ‘Finance and Economic division’ (comprising three groups: Finance, Public Sector and National Economy) promoted much improved policy coordination with important implications for policy-making with respect to growth-promotion and the balance of payments. Until the records are mined we will not know what became of the 1950s fault line between OF and domestic finance, but there will almost certainly be a different sort of story to be told here.53

4.4 The great unmentionable: defending $2.80 4.4.1 The fate of ‘Keynesian plus’ is typically told in terms of the excesses of the Maudling boom

52 Opie (1968) is a classic amongst the disillusioned economists; see also Middleton (1998, ch. 6) for what

befell the plague of economists who embraced. 53 Preliminary results from Pemberton , whose almost completed Ph.D. is on Keynesian plus policies, suggest

that a distinct OF strand continued and that they never accepted the National Economy’s group even qualified enthusiasm for the growth strategy which was at the heart of Keynesian plus.

Page 38: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

38 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

and the refusal of the incoming Labour government, for largely political and personal reasons, to devalue and thereby widen the policy space.54 This orthodoxy owes much to the dominant voices and accounts of disillusioned former Labour ministers and those economic advisers who, entering Whitehall as irregulars, quickly progressed from enthusiasm for Labour’s growth strategy (which explicitly committed the new government to an end to ‘Stop-Go’) to disillusion and despair.55 This orthodoxy culminates with, and has especial meaning because of, Labour’s defeat in the June 1970 general election, a result which was ascribed by many to the government’s inability to deliver the necessary economic ‘feelgood factor’ because the delay in devaluing sterling provided insufficient time to synchronise the economic and electoral cycles to its advantage.

4.4.2 The story of sterling in the 1960s is thus told largely in terms of adjusting (or not adjusting)

the parity and the implications (or opportunity costs) of this for macroeconomic policy and, thus ultimately, economic modernization. The history of floating rate proposals, as against moving on the adjustable peg, has not yet been told.56 There were a considerable body of British economists active in the policy debate who favoured alternatives ranging from a free float through to a crawling peg. Thus Kaldor – who would become a Labour special adviser (1964–8) – favoured floating from early 1963 onwards (McMahon 1964, p. 51), while the crawling peg, the invention of Harrod (1933, pp. 166–77), was revived by Scott (1959) and then taken up by Meade (1966) and Williamson (1966), all of whom sought to strengthen the underlying balance of payments ‘so as to release the British economy from “stop-go”’ (Williamson 1981, p. 65). Such proposals were, of course, part of a broader western dialogue – within and outside of the IMF – about ways in which greater flexibility could be introduced into the Bretton Woods par value exchange rate mechanism (de Vries 1987, p. 84), but at the risk of being parochial we maintain the UK focus of our account where for too long the myth has been perpetrated that there was a pro-devaluation consensus amongst academic economists which was opposed only by obstinate politicians (Thirlwall and Gibson 1992, p. 236).

4.4.3 This as yet largely untold story has a counterpart in the sceptical spirit in which the very real

economic reasons for not devaluing in 1964 are treated within the historical literature: thus too often the sceptics were derided in Labour circles as City lackeys, and thus part of the problem of the dominance of the ‘establishment’ in British official life (a critique pushed with unusual vigour and venom by one of the Hungarians, Balogh, who interestingly actually opposed devaluation in 1964).57 Four strands to these economic arguments deserve re-examination and more detailed research.

4.4.4 First, we have the ‘elasticity pessimists’, the contemporary term for those unconvinced by the

price competitiveness arguments for devaluation. Harrod’s pessimism was, of course, long-standing, but in 1965–6 others would join this camp, and from very different political

54 This episode forms one of the three case studies in Middleton (1998, pp. 253–68); see also Davis (1968),

Britton (197, ch. 8) and Bruce-Gardyne and Lawson (1976, ch. 4) for semi-insider contemporary accounts; Woodward (1993) and Bale (1999) for recent economic (re)assessments, and the Institute of Contemporary British History witness seminar on the 1967 devaluation edited by Brittan (1988).

55 See, in particular, Beckerman (1972). 56 For the IMF economists part of the story, see Blejer et al. (1995) and Polak (1995). Fleming (1962) was, of

course, a Staff Paper. 57 Of the five economic advisers in October 1964, Balogh opposed devaluation, as did Cairncross, albeit for

very different reasons as much to do politics as economics. Balogh would soon accept the case for devaluation, while Cairncross (1997, p. 1) had been convinced since 1961 ‘that the pound would have to be devalued at some stage in the 1960s. But I saw no point in devaluing in an overheated economy without the support of stringent deflationary measures which there was no likelihood that the Labour government would adopt.’ The pro-devaluation lobby comprised MacDougall, now at the DEA, Kaldor, at the Treasury, and Neild, also at the Treasury.

Page 39: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 39__________________________________________________________________________________________

standpoints (Lionel Robbins through R.J. Ball and John Hicks to Joan Robinson). Looking at 1964 specifically, but subsequent years in general, there was strong evidence that the balance of payments deficit had little to do with the price uncompetitiveness of British goods (the view pressed in Thirlwall 1970; 1988), and at least one highly respected retrospective economic assessment has argued that ‘The difficulties of 1964 were cyclical and were on the capital account; they were not the result of forces to be rectified by exchange rate depreciation’; that the deflationary measures of 1965–6 were effective in bringing the current balance back into surplus by 1966.II, although the size of long-term capital flows ensured that the balance for official financing (and thus the basic balance) was always sizeable; and that much of the pressures that eventually forced the devaluation in 1967 were speculative (reinforced by arbitrage) and external (initially, a slow-down in the growth of world trade and then the effects of the Middle East crisis) rather than relating to a sustained deterioration in the trading balance.58

4.4.5 Secondly, there was the Paish view: that if aggregate demand is not extended beyond

productive potential, there is no need for a floating rate (or devaluation); if, however, excess demand is permitted then the floating rate becomes unworkable and merely results in permanent cost inflation, i.e. the exchange rate does not permanently free policy-makers but merely accommodates inflation and all with an uncertain future. This connects to the third developing concern: that of the pass-through effects of a devaluation on wages and thus prices. After two decades of moderately fluctuating inflation rates and broadly stable inflationary expectations, two decades in which full employment pertained with no slump to discipline wage bargaining, there was much anxiety by the mid-1960s that there was an incipient ‘new inflation’ in which newly militant trade unions were operating with an enhanced inflation consciousness (Jones 1987, p. 81). These sorts of arguments also acquire considerable retrospective force when related to recent general work by economists and political scientists on the labour market institutions and attitudes that were conducive to golden age growth in the ACCs (Eichengreen and Iversen 2000), and more particularly Eichengreen’s (1996b) exploration of how in Britain high union density, a fragmented and uncoordinated industrial relations system and a flawed postwar settlement prevented a cooperative capital-labour bargain emerging which could generate wage moderation and high investment. Certainly, there was a view – particularly associated with the National Institute – that a devaluation would jeopardise the success of the price and income policies, a strand of the ‘Keynesian plus’ strategy for which some held high hopes as a way of maintaining the competitiveness of British goods (Tew 1978b, p. 313).

4.4.6 Fourthly, and with shades of 1925 and the decision to return to the gold standard at the

prewar parity of $4.86 (upon which see Moggridge 1972), we have the issue of the discipline provided by a challengingly high exchange rate. Some saw distinct advantages in $2.80:

To those economists, inside as well as outside the government, whose views on the British economy came to be broadly in line with Paish’s, the $2.80 peg, at any rate up to mid-1966, was never an undesirable constraint on demand management, since from the end of the war up to that time demand had almost never been inadequate – and had intermittently been excessive. In the high-demand phase the constraint had been beneficial, in that it served to reinforce the government’s resolve to deflate demand to a level which this school of thought regarded as more appropriate to the domestic objectives of demand management

[Tew 1978b, p. 313]

4.4.7 The ‘great unmentionable’, as with the prewar parity in 1925, provided financial discipline, a strait-jacket, at a time when politicians and advisers recognised the risks that the new government could succumb to the ambitions of spending ministers and the natural desire of

58 Thirlwall and Gibson (1992, pp. 235, 238), a view broadly supported by Cairncross and Eichengreen’s

(1983, p. 216) comparative study of the 1931, 1949 and 1967 devaluations.

Page 40: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

40 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

trade union leaders to maintain free collective bargaining. Expectations of what Labour could deliver in 1964 were very, very high, indeed, impossibly inflated; had there been a devaluation or a free float of sterling the risks for the exchange rate, public borrowing and a wage-price spiral were immense. Possibly the worst could have been avoided, although what later transpired during the 1970–4 Heath administration does not make for optimism. In retrospect, the really interesting question about Labour’s exchange rate policy was not the 1964 decision but that of 1966, when George Brown raised the unmentionable once more and the economic fundamentals were more clearly commensurate with exchange rate realignment.59 But this really is with the benefit of 20:20 hindsight, that essential instrument of the economists’ toolbox.60

4.4.8 Having rejected devaluation in October 1964 the Wilson government had no other option but

to deflate, thereby initiating a new phase of the ‘Stop-Go’ cycle which, in opposition, it had been committed to terminating. Its hesitation in adopting that deflationary stance, together with the more dirigiste measures such as the emergency import surcharges, lessened its credibility with the foreign exchange markets already anxious about Labour’s intentions. The new Chancellor’s mini-budget speech the following month compounded the government’s credibility deficit with the markets, and from then on until, and indeed beyond, the eventual forced decision to devalue in November 1967 the situation was only sustained by tight capital controls, standby credits with the IMF and lines of credit from the G10. This was to be the pattern of crisis after crisis at the international level, the counterpart to frequent mini-budgets and even firmer ‘Stops’ at the domestic level. That a fundamental adjustment to the parity was avoided as long as it was owed as much to international relations as to market fundamentals. As James (1996, p. 186) describes it:

For the next three years, Britain continued to avoid devaluation because of the willingness of the United States to support sterling: partly because of a feeling of solidarity between reserve currencies and partly because of the United Kingdom’s importance to the US conception of its foreign policy. At the highest level of government to government dealings, foreign policy, troop stationing, and reserve currencies all entered into a complex calculation of national interest. An appreciation of the similarity between the international roles of the dollar and sterling led to the argument that the British currency represented the outer perimeter defense of the dollar. The escalation of war in Viet Nam after 1965 made the United States more desperate for European allies and eager to work the ‘special relationship’. After April 1966, when France withdrew from the military organization of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), the American search for European support became more pressing.

4.4.9 What James does not detail, but is now becoming clear from the PRO papers, is the extent to

which in pursuing this course the British monetary authorities were in effect allowing America to dictate not just external but internal economic policy. Ironically, shortly before devaluation did occur, Callaghan enraged his backbenchers when he told the Commons that he was now in sympathy with the Paish critique (James 1996, pp. 188–9); ironic also, and pace 1976 and another Labour government, that when the IMF made the extension of credits conditional on even stricter deflationary measures, Wilson and Callaghan refused to comply and instead the unmentionable became the inescapable: sterling was devalued from $2.80 to $2.40 on 18 November 1967 (Eichengreen 1996a, p. 128).

4.5 Devaluation, 1967 and its aftermath 4.5.1 The 1967 devaluation was accompanied by fervent efforts to make it ‘effective’, these

comprising packages of expenditure-switching and expenditure-reducing measures, increasing in intensity in a series of budgets and mini-budgets through to 1969, to create the 59 This conclusion follows Middleton (1998, p. 268); see also p. 272 where I raise the potential dissonance

between Brown’s account of events and that of MacDougall (1987, p. 157) and why this needs exploring. 60 This phrase is usually attributed to Walter Heller, chairman of the CEA, 1961–4.

Page 41: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 41__________________________________________________________________________________________

available resources to supply more exports and import substitutes until productivity could be raised. The further tightening of fiscal and monetary policy formed the bedrock of these packages. Upon devaluation, Bank rate was set at the unprecedented level of 8 per cent and was a very visible signal that a government, which came to power committed to an alternative to ‘Stop-Go’, had exhausted itself struggling with the impossible and in the process fatally compromised its longer-term growth-promotion strategies.

4.5.2 ‘Stop-Go’ was thereby reinforced and the policies that Labour had derided in opposition, of

resolving the balance of payments problem by depressing domestic production, investment and employment, and thereby undermining long-term growth potential, were once more in the ascendant. For ‘Stop-Go’ critics the devaluation solved little or nothing. As Pollard (1984, p. 34) put it:

To be sure, the clinging to a particular dollar exchange rate was irrational, as irrational as a great deal else in British economic policy. But it is equally certain that devaluation, when it came, was merely a means of registering the fact that Britain’s productivity had fallen far behind that of others while money incomes had risen at about the same rate. Moreover, once it was completed, devaluation would make no fundamental change whatever, since nothing would have been done to arrest the process of relative decline which had made it necessary in the first place.

4.5.3 Moreover, matters were about to deteriorate yet further. Pollard (1984, pp. 45–6) continued:

These measures availed the government little, for it lost the election, but the Conservatives inherited an economy which had been, in current parlance, ‘strengthened’: i.e. by producing less, cutting back on investment and on technical improvement schemes (making British industry much less competitive in real terms), something like a temporary balance in the foreign payments account had been achieved. Output had virtually stagnated during 1968–70, investment had risen very little from its low level of 1964–7, and price inflation had slightly subdued .... The pound was then undervalued in world price terms. But the potential for an enormous wage explosion had been accumulated in the pipeline, following years of restriction and restraint, and wage costs were beginning to push up prices even in the last months of Labour rule in a manner which has become all too familiar in the years since. Under the Heath government of 1970–4, in fact, continuing inflation, particularly of wages, was gradually taking over from the foreign balance of payments and the external value of the pound as the main preoccupation of economic policy makers, and the main pretext for restrictive policies.

4.5.4 In this view the next phase of ‘Stop-Go’ was thus established, with ‘Stops’ triggered not by

sterling or the balance of payments but by inflation fears, although of course after June 1972 sterling was floated and temporarily at least the current account, being in surplus, was out of the spotlight. Some comments on this further strand of the ‘Stop-Go thesis are necessary at this stage. First, more recent national accounts data portrays a somewhat rosier picture for these years: real GDP grew by 2.2 per cent on average per annum between 1968–70, admittedly somewhat below trend (approximately 3 per cent) but hardly virtual stagnation. Even manufacturing output grew by 2.1 per cent on average per annum over these years, while real GDFCF was 16.2 per cent higher on average 1968–70 than 1964–7.61

4.5.5 Secondly, at the time what preoccupied policy makers, indeed caused great puzzlement, was

why the current account took so long to turn around, and this necessarily – on the elasticity’s approach to balance of payments adjustment – elicited concerns that the devaluation had not been big enough. The lag, indeed initial deterioration in the trade balance, would, of course, later be understood in terms of a J-curve effect, a purely empirical phenomenon (Masera 1974; Artus 1975; Tew 1978b, pp. 354–6).62 Later, others would offer more fundamental critiques of how a balance of payments deficit could remain impervious to exchange rate

61 Calculated from ONS (1999, tables 1.3, 4.1). 62 Cairncross and Eichengreen (1983, pp. 197–213), Sinclair (1985, pp. 184–5) and Thirlwall and Gibson

(1994, pp. 239–43) provide very useful surveys of contemporary assessments of the British devaluation.

Page 42: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

42 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

changes (for example, Kaldor 1977 and Ball et al. 1977). 4.5.6 Thirdly, if sterling was initially undervalued after the devaluation, it is significant that even

those who considered the undervaluation to be inflationary did not on the whole oppose a devaluation. Thus Laidler (1978, p. p. 56) estimates that with the parity adjustment sterling moved from about 5 per cent overvaluation to 10 per cent undervaluation,63 but along with others involved in the 1977 National Institute sponsored retrospective simulation exercise, in which competing macroeconomic forecasting groups revisited 1964–9 and were given the opportunity to attempt what-if simulations of different policies, he devalued.64 Fourthly, it must be borne in mind that an earlier devaluation of lesser amount might very well have been effective, for whilst waiting and the struggle to defend the parity may have been good domestic and Anglo-American politics it meant that when the adjustment was eventually forced it had to be of sufficient size as to be credible with the markets. And even then through 1968 and early 1969 the drain on the reserves continued and there were doubts whether the new parity could be maintained: ‘Confidence in the pound was indeed slow in returning’ (Cairncross and Eichengreen 1983, pp. 193–4).

4.5.7 At the end of 1968 official liabilities to the IMF and other monetary authorities totalled some

$8.1bn (about 7.8 per cent of British GDP), over $3bn higher than a year earlier, while sterling and foreign currency reserves were $270m lower (Tew 1978b, table 7.2). Thereafter, after a further tight budget which must finally have done something to demonstrate the government’s commitment to the parity, and thereby enhanced its market credibility, the current account balance of payments situation turned sharply for the better. From a current deficit of 0.5 per cent of GDP in 1967 and 0.3 per cent in 1968, a surplus of 1.2, 1.8 and 2.2 per cent was reported for the three years 1969–71 respectively (see Figure 1, p. 9). The reserves were replenished (see Figure 2, p. 9) and by April 1972 the government, by now a Conservative administration, was liberated of all official short- and medium-term debt (Cairncross and Eichengreen 1983, p. 194). At last the government was within sight of its objective, declared in its submission to the Radcliffe committee, of securing a current account surplus sufficient to fund long-term overseas investment and build up sufficient reserves to both finance faster growth and provide some buffer against the pressures to which sterling as an international currency was inevitably subjected.65

4.5.8 Given the ‘formidable array’ of policies brought to bear to improve the balance of payments

there is no difficulty in explaining why it eventually came right for the authorities, reaching a record current account surplus in 1971 (Tew 1978b). Indeed, as Thirlwall and Gibson (1994, p. 243) noted:66 63 The extent of any overvaluation should also be put in longer-term historical context: thus commonly the

return to gold in 1925 overvalued sterling by 10-25 per cent, the appreciation of the real exchange rate between 1980–2 was of the order of 25–30 per cent while, upon entry into the ERM in 1990, it was argued that on a FEER basis sterling was overvalued by approximately 10 per cent, as indeed would be the case today.

64 The results were collected as Posner (1978). In addition to Laidler, representing a version of the monetarist position, the models participating in this exercise were those of the Cambridge Economic Policy Group, the London Business School and the National Institute. Laidler’s specific proposal was for a 5 per cent devaluation in 1964, followed by a tighter path for Domestic Credit Expansion (DCE) (p. 54), a position he adopted in part because he thought that ‘a golden opportunity had been missed in 1963 to exercise patience and break out of the stop-go cycle once and for all while maintaining the exchange rate. Instead a “dash for growth” had been undertaken and the monetary consequences [DCE] ensured that a new government came to power just as the “go” phase of a new cycle was building up to a balance of payments crisis’ (p. 53).

65 In the early 1950s the Treasury’s target current account surplus was £300–350m and in the Radcliffe report (HMSO 1959, para. 630) a surplus of £350m for the early 1960s is detailed. Adjusting for inflation this translates into a target surplus of approximately £675m for 1970; the figure obtained was actually £821m on contemporary estimates (Table 6, p. 23) or £911m on the most recent ONS (1999, table 1.18) estimates.

66 This, of course, leads on directly to the Thirlwall view that Britain’s golden age growth was balance of

Page 43: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 43__________________________________________________________________________________________

So severe were the deflationary measures ... and so rapid the growth of export volume (largely as a result of the rapid expansion of world trade), that the trade balance itself also moved into surplus in 1971, the surplus ... being the largest in recorded history [there having only been two surpluses since the 1820s in any case, both – interestingly – in the 1950s]. The ‘full’ employment trade balance would no doubt have been in deficit, but the current account would still have shown a surplus.

4.5.9 On this view then, the spotlight should be less on the exchange rate and more on a Labour

government breaching the spirit if not the letter of the commitment to full employment. Admittedly, the addition to unemployment and the total national figure to which it rose were small compared with what later transpired. Obviously, this was no easy matter for a Labour government at mid-term. Moreover, it has added significance because the Conservative government that unexpectedly took power in 1970 inherited an economy with a margin of unused resources that even it found unacceptable and then resistant to its early efforts to reflate. It was thus the Heath administration that would be panicked into a U-turn, thereby largely abandoning its burgeoning neo-liberal – in some eyes, proto-Thatcherite – policies, when the rise in unemployment threatened to take the headline total above 1m. The fall out from the measures to make the November 1967 devaluation effective was thus of long-duration and immensely important to both political parties: they form an important foundation to so many strands of the developing crisis of Keynesian conventional wisdom.

4.6 The decision to float the pound, 1972 4.6.1 For many British economists ‘devaluation seem[ed] to have rectified the fundamental

balance-of-payments disequilibrium’ (Matthews 1971, p. 15). However, it is the orthodoxy amongst the economists that the balance of payments surplus so painfully acquired after 1967 was then squandered by the Barber boom:

A policy of ‘steady as she goes’ would probably have consolidated the surplus and allowed the country to retain some of the benefits of devaluation for longer. As it was the surplus was frittered away by an irresponsible expansion of internal demand, reminiscent of what happened in 1964 and which led to the troubles and stagnation of the 1960s. [Thirlwall and Gibson 1994, p. 243]

4.6.2 Concurrently, of course, as the beleaguered Bretton Woods system headed towards terminal

crisis and disintegration there developed a growing body of international opinion that floating was in principle preferable to the adjustable peg system. It is important, however, to note here that floating always commanded more support amongst the academics than the politicians. Clearly, the December 1971 Smithsonian Agreement between the G-10 was a landmark in that process,67 and again at the risk of being parochial we here look at these developments through largely British eyes, noting in passing that ‘Between 1971 and 1974 the international monetary system moved towards floating, not so much because this was an agreed solution, but because it emerged out of a failure to produce an agreed solution ‘ (James 1996, p. 234). (We should also note here that, in contrast to the earlier episodes discussed, we have far less of a historical record to base our account as the official papers for the late 1960s and early 1970s have not yet been released by the PRO. The following is also not concerned with the

payments constrained on the demand side. Dubbed Thirlwall’s law by a sceptical Crafts (1991, 269), this stated ‘that except where the balance of payments equilibrium growth rate exceeds the maximum feasible capacity growth rate, the rate of growth of a country will approximate to the ratio of its rate of growth of exports and its income elasticity of demand for imports’ (Thirlwall 1979, p. 50). Crafts’ scepticism was that the problem was not on the demand side but that Britain failed to take advantage of fast growing world trade (a system characteristic of the golden age for the ACCs) as a consequence of weak competitiveness associated with low productivity and manifold supply-side deficiencies, in particular that the British labour market appeared to adjust more slowly to shocks than did the more corporatist economies where a more cooperative labour-capital bargain was engineered by the state.

67 This pegged sterling at $2.60 and it was this parity which was maintained until floating was initiated in June 1972.

Page 44: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

44 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

largely technical matters but concentrates on the broad political economy of the debate.)68 4.6.3 The international background, of scepticism about the realignments effected in December

1971, coupled with widely diverging inflation rates between countries, produced magnified international capital movements which inevitably heightened sterling’s vulnerability. The deaththroe of Bretton Woods thus created an entirely new situation for British policy-makers already struggling to reconcile their neo-liberal policy agenda with the underperforming domestic economy that they considered they had inherited from Labour. They certainly shared the concerns of the international policy community that if the system degenerated into uncoordinated floating rates then the whole tenor of international trade liberalisation and globalisation of finance could be imperilled by a return to protectionism and competitive devaluations, but perhaps for the first time since Operation ROBOT a ‘Britain alone policy’ could be entertained.

4.6.4 Within the British policy debate the floating rate option acquired a new salience, but this

actually predated the exciting events of 1971–2. There was a number of strands here which we introduce as a initial step in researching this topic. First, of course, the lag between the 1967 devaluation and the turnaround in the reserves and the current account kept many thinking that more radical alternatives might be necessary to free the British economy from the external constraint. Secondly, amongst the academics, the Bürgenstock papers (Halm 1970) received much attention, including an extended Economic Journal review by Harrod (1971), but above all it seems to have been an IEA pamphlet by Johnson and Nash (1969) which ignited the spark and caught the attention of the financial community and thus policy-makers. Importantly, the Economist had pressed for a floating rate before and after the 1967 devaluation (Anon. 1968). Johnson, of course, deserves a special place in the history of economic thought at this time (and not just for his contributions to the monetary theory of the balance of payments), indeed the history of the economics profession, and we await an intellectual biography of this important figure.69 Meanwhile, it is clear that for Johnson, as for many others, part of the appeal of the floating rate was as a preferable alternative to price and income policies which were then scarring British politics and economics and which he had long opposed for exacerbating inflation without curing the condition (Laidler 1984, p. 609).

4.6.5 Thirdly, in America and, to a lesser degree, Britain there were the seeds of what we would

later call the New Right which, when combined with the developing monetarist critique of the Keynesian conventional wisdom, was bringing to the fore more market oriented solutions to all economic problems. In Britain the foremost proselytising agency for the market was the IEA (Cockett 1994), one of the sponsors of Johnson and Nash (1969). Indeed, in that volume 68 The following general accounts appear provisionally reliable: Tew (1978b), Milner (1980) and Dornbusch

and Fisher (1980), with Stewart (1977) interesting but more partisan. Economic reappraisals of the Heath government are now beginning to appear, for example Coopey and Woodward (1996) and Cairncross (1996b), while the quarterly National Institute Economic Review is an invaluable source and there is much of value in the reflections and analyses contained in F. Cairncross (1981) and F. Cairncross and A.K. Cairncross (1992). See also Harris and Sewill (1975), this setpiece sponsored by the Institute of Economic Affairs (IEA) between an important British exponent of monetarism and the former Chancellor’s (Anthony Barber, 1970–4) special adviser. Unfortunately, Barber did not produce memoirs; this government was far less leaky than that which preceded or succeeded it; and the one former senior Treasury official to publish widely on this period (Pliatzky 1984) adds little to our knowledge, being particularly disappointing on the decision to float.

69 Johnson was a founder of the Money Study Group, an important British vehicle for the development of monetarist ideas. This was the first stage in the development of a more independent British strand of monetary research, developing at the LSE (the International Monetary Economics Research Programme of Johnson and Swoboda), at Manchester (the Inflation Workshop of Laidler and Parkin) and, somewhat later, at the City University (with Griffiths and Wood in the Centre for Banking and International Finance). These research programmes were more appropriate to British conditions as an open economy with, by US standards, a comparatively large public sector and a central bank under greater political control.

Page 45: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 45__________________________________________________________________________________________

Johnson introduced the case for flexible exchange rates as ‘deriv[ing] fundamentally from the laws of supply and demand’, with the exchange rate a price like any other that would be established efficiently and appropriately by competitive markets if unhindered by government interference (Johnson and Nash 1969, p. 20).

4.6.6 Johnson continued with arguments constructed in terms of the prevailing polarities and

calculated to have particular British appeal, including ‘flexible exchange rates are essential to the preservation of national autonomy and independence consistently with efficient organisation and development of the world economy’ (p. 12), and the ‘resentment of the increasing subordination of domestic policy to international requirements since 1964’ (p. 13), a component of which was that fixed rates ‘gives considerable prestige and, more important, political power over national governments to the central bankers entrusted with managing the system, power which they naturally credit themselves with exercising more “responsibly” than the politicians would do, and which they naturally resist surrendering’ (p. 12). As with others before him, he stressed that floating would lessen the pressure on the reserves and thus the potential for sterling to be disruptive to macroeconomic policy, whilst no doubt he also thought that it might hasten the demise of sterling as an international currency which again would widen the policy space.

4.6.7 Given that the major threats to the reserves had been from sudden crises of confidence, not

from the current account balance of payments, an attractive spin could easily be constructed along the lines of the exchange rate rather than the reserves taking the strain. Moreover, in some quarters a flexible rate regime was an attractive option because, to avoid precipitous depreciation of sterling, the move would have to be accompanied by fundamental measures to improve competitiveness, and this part of the case could be made to appeal to the left or the right depending upon where reforms would focus. Conversely, ‘Floating could be a euphemistic prescription for a further series of devaluations’ (Strange 1971, p. 340) which did not produce such fundamental measures and diverted attention from ways in which the balance of payments, on capital as well as current account, could be improved by addressing the geo-political postures that created the weakness in the first place. Moreover, just as flexible rates could be presented as a counterpoise to price and incomes policies, so could they also to import controls and other restrictive trade measures, the case for which was increasingly being made and would eventually become associated with, first, the Cambridge Economic Policy Group and, later, the Alternative Economic Strategy. Finally, of course, Johnson’s optimism about the respective responsibility and prudence of bankers and politicians was highly questionable and not just with the benefit of 20:20 hindsight.70

4.6.8 In the event, however, as is typically the case with the major episodes in British exchange

rate management, contingent events and short-term responses to external developments actually precipitated the decision to float in June 1972. Heath (1998, p. 409) reports in his memoirs that his government was ‘by no means dogmatically attached to the principle of fixed exchange rates’, but that, after Wilson’s protracted troubles with sterling, where prevarication had forced ‘the worst of both worlds’ (devaluation and deflation), ‘it was important, given the potential volatility in the markets, that we should give no apparent signals about either revaluing or refloating the pound. Events now forced our hand.’ The events in question were manifest in a speculative attack on sterling which had complex causes. One set related to anxieties about British inflation and whether, despite its ideological and policy preferences to the contrary, the Conservatives would be compelled to introduce a statutory price and incomes policy. Another set stemmed from external developments, notably the continuing fallout from the ‘fix’ attempted at the Smithsonian and the early days

70 See, for example, Einzig’s (1970) dire warnings that flexible rates would result in a ‘gnomocracy’ with

sterling at the mercy of currency speculators.

Page 46: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

46 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

of a new manifestation of the European integration project, the EMU ‘snake in the tunnel’, the precursor of EMS (to which Britain was briefly a member (May-June 1972) as part of its preparations for entry into the EEC which was finally achieved on 1 January 1973).

4.6.9 That the Conservatives were not committed to an immutable fixed rate had been admitted by

Barber in his March 1972 budget speech: ‘the lesson of the international balance of payments upsets of the last few years is that it is neither necessary nor desirable to distort domestic economies to an unacceptable extent in order to retain unrealistic exchange rates, whether they are too high or too low.’ He was careful to ground that statement within the new position that ‘both the current balance of payments and our reserve position are much stronger than they were at the beginning of previous periods of expansion’ (Hansard 1972a, col. 1354). Received wisdom has it that Barber, backed by Heath, was prepared to abandon adjustable peg to avoid this latest dash for growth running into the sands of a sterling crisis. The Barber boom should perhaps be more attributed to Heath’s influence (Porter 1996, p. 38), while the EEC agenda seems also very important, but beyond this we need the official papers to cast new light on this episode.

4.6.10 What is clear is that the collapse of Bretton Woods provided a unique opportunity for the

Treasury, but the move to floating rates was seen in June 1972 as temporary and not as some decisive shift in direction. Unsurprisingly, Barber’s announcement of the change to the House of Commons was very low key (Hansard 1972b) and the decision had been anticipated – provoked, so say his critics – by Healey, the shadow chancellor (Heath 1998, p.409). The Economist’s immediate response, in its first leading article after the decision was announced, of ‘Float free and low’ (Anon. 1972) well captures the prevailing mood. We come then full circle: a government now ostensibly committed to a growth target without being hidebound by an external constraint.

§5. CONCLUSIONS 5.1.1 British economic policy during the golden age is a story that can be told in terms of

‘tinkerers’ and ‘structuralists’ (Bacon and Eltis 1976, p. 1). Within the policy community ‘tinkerers’ predominated and within their camp the prevailing ethos was that, in the main, adjustments to demand would suffice to attain the government’s macroeconomic objectives. Structuralists, by contrast, always in the minority, were preoccupied with the underlying structure of the economy and had in their sights much more fundamental, typically supply-side, reforms since in their view tinkering and the tinkerers were inadequate for the real challenge confronting Britain: that of complete economic, political and social modernization. As policy issues sterling and the balance of payments actually bridged the divide, but for the most part lay on the side of the tinkerers. None the less, as we have seen there was an important structuralist strand to the story in terms of various growth-promotion strategies, and particularly Keynesian plus, which in the eyes of their advocates were an important element in strengthening the balance of payments because no amount of tinkering with the exchange rate would suffice, indeed very often it was counterproductive.

5.1.2 We have seen also that amongst the complex characteristics of Britain’s balance of payments

situation there was also scope, from marginal to more or less radical, to improve the current account by diminishing the drain across the exchanges of ‘great power’ expenditures by adjusting geo-political posturing more speedily in line with diminished economic capability. Although Britain’s great power delusion can be pushed too far, for in terms of the hegemonic international relations literature it is clear that the US assumed less fully than Britain a number of international roles so that ‘American internationalism was no panacea for Britain’s post-war problems’ (Reynolds 2000, pp. 310–11), it is surely the case that had successive

Page 47: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 47__________________________________________________________________________________________

British governments behaved less like US clients, the UK authorities might accordingly have had greater room for manoeuvre in exchange rate policy and in other areas which impacted importantly on the policy space.

5.1.3 We should comment also on the grand narrative of relative British economic decline that now

prevails. This is a story of economic underperformance relative to comparators, it is typically calibrated in terms of the emerging gap between Britain and these comparators as measured by GDP per worker-hour, a whole economy labour productivity indicator; the focus for attention in explaining underperformance is typically on the manufacturing sector where the worst elements of the British disease were apparently located, and to which the various modernisation and growth-promotion strategies were directed; and the whole story is grounded in terms of the catch-up and convergence literature (see Middleton 2000, ch. 1 for a summary of the growth current debate). This is not yet a story which has taken on board Broadberry’s (1997) reassessment of long-term British growth and its important conclusion that Britain lost its lead (as measured by GDP per worker-hour), and Germany (the important European comparator for British policy-makers) and the US caught up, not because of their emerging productivity lead in manufacturing, but by shifting resources out of agriculture and improving their relative productivity position in services. In other words, the US and, to a lesser extent, Germany had long-standing productivity advantages in manufacturing over Britain. From this follows the important implication that to study Britain’s long-run decline, one must examine why Britain experienced a loss of productivity leadership in services. This is not to dismiss problems with the manufacturing sector, problems amenable to the remedies that were attempted or discussed as potentially applicable in Britain, but it is to shift the focus to the service sector about which we know far less (Middleton 2000, pp. 60–1).

5.1.4 Combining this with the balance of payments story we have told here leads on to the

suggestion that we need as a matter of urgency to re-examine the performance of Britain’s internationally traded financial services since the war. Hitherto, this has typically been a story told by the City about the City, and is one that takes as a given that it was British manufacturing and the visible side of the balance of payments that was underperforming and not the City and the invisible account. Yet, we know that since at least the early 1960s Britain has lost share in the value of world exports of services at a rate similar to that at which it had lost market share in exports of manufactures (Bank of England 1985, p. 410), while a recent assessment of the post-OPEC I British economy, which involved a detailed assessment of internationally traded services’ contribution to the balance of payments, produced the conclusion that ‘The once fashionable idea that the United Kingdom possesses a considerable comparative advantage [in this area] is not really sustainable’ (Haq and Temple 1998, p. 467). Kynaston’s (2001) history of the City of London makes clear that the culture of ‘short hours, leisurely lunches and long weekends’ endured for decades after the war in many City institutions and firms, while even Michie (1998, p. 569), typically a very sympathetic observer of the City, has conceded that for ‘a twenty-year period after the second world war ... the City could be accused of possessing a personnel that was not adequate for the domestic and international tasks demanded of it as a financial centre.’

5.1.5 Finally, we must ground our analysis of the golden age epoch in terms of our knowledge that

exchange rates have been a particular problem area for the British policy-making community since the end of the First World War. As our PRO project develops we will be able to provide a richer history for the later episodes that we have encountered,71 and we will also learn much 71 Full access to the PRO papers is particularly important because as Cairncross (1985, p. xiii) has found,

although they ‘supply some piquant details on the lines of argument ministers were prepared to entertain . . . they do not add a great deal to our knowledge of what they decided. What the papers do reveal more adequately is what went on at the official level, the techniques of analysis that were being developed, the possibilities of action that were being canvassed, the thinking and differences of opinion that underlay the

Page 48: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

48 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

about applied economics as practised in Britain. But, given the complex difficulties that comprised Britain’s exchange rate and balance of payments situation, it is likely that the fuller picture that will emerge will be of a policy community struggling with problems to which contemporaneous developments in international economic theory and policy added little except perhaps to magnify the task – British policy-makers were only too well aware of capital movements and price rigidities – and the sense that solutions to Britain’s economic underperformance were more political than economic. We end, therefore, with an apology for the incursion of this economic historian into an economists’ conference; an apology also for hardly dealing with the ostensible topic of the conference, but in Britain there were prior matters to do with balance of payments and exchange rate management which had to be dealt with before the issue of progress in economic theory, and its potential application, became relevant.

ministerial pronouncements.’

Page 49: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 49__________________________________________________________________________________________

§6 REFERENCES Anon (1968) ‘It’s better to float’, The Economist, 30

November, pp. 15-17. ___ (1972) ‘Float free and low’, The Economist, 1

July, pp. 7–8. Arndt, H.W. (1978) The rise and fall of economic

growth: a study in contemporary thought. Melbourne: Longman Cheshire.

Armstrong, P., Glyn, A. and Harrison, J. (1991) Capitalism since 1945. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Artis, M.J. (1978) ‘Monetary policy, part II’, in F.T. Blackaby (ed.) (1978) q.v., pp. 258–303.

___, Flemming, J., Matthews, R.C.O. and Weale, M.R. (2000) ‘Christopher Dow on major reces-sions’, National Institute Economic Review, 173 (July), pp. 89–105.

Artus, J.R. (1975) ‘The 1967 devaluation of the pound sterling’, IMF Staff Papers, 22 (4), pp. 595–640.

Bacon, R.W. and Eltis, W.A. (1976) Britain’s economic problem: too few producers. London: Macmillan.

Balacs, P.D. (1972) ‘Economic data and economic policy’, Lloyds Bank Review, 104 (April), pp. 35–50.

Blaazer, D. (1999) ‘“Devalued and dejected Britons”: the pound in public discourse in the mid 1960s’, History Workshop Journal, 47 (Spring), pp. 121–40.

Backus, D.K. and Kehoe, P.J. (1992) ‘International evidence on the historical properties of business cycles’, American Economic Review, 82 (3), pp. 864–88.

Bale, T. (1999) ‘Dynamics of a non-decision: the “failure” to devalue the pound, 1964–7’, Twentieth Century British History, 10 (2), pp. 192–217.

Ball, R.J., Burns, T. and Laury, J.S.E. (1977) ‘The role of exchange rate changes in balance of payments adjustment: the United Kingdom case’, Economic Journal, 87 (1), pp. 1–29.

Bank of England (1962) ‘Unrecorded movements in the UK balance of payments: the “balancing item”’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2 (1), pp. 16–22.

___ (1964) ‘The balance of payments: methods of presentation’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 4 (4), pp. 276–86.

___ (1985) ‘Services in the UK economy’, Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 25 (3), pp. 404–14.

Bean, C.R. and Crafts, N.F.R. (1996) ‘British economic growth since 1945: relative economic decline ... and renaissance?’, in N.F.R. Crafts and G. Toniolo (eds) (1996) q.v., pp. 131–72.

Beckerman, W. (ed.) (1972) The Labour government’s economic record, 1964–1970. London: Duckworth.

___ (2000) ‘Wilfred Beckerman (b. 1925)’, in R.E. Backhouse and R. Middleton (eds) (2000) Exemplary economists. Vol. II: Europe, Asia and Australasia. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp. 146–97.

Blackaby, F.T. (ed.) (1978) British economic policy, 1960–74. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Blejer, M.I., Khan, M.S. and Masson, P.R. (1995) ‘'Early contributions of Staff Papers to inter-national economics’, IMF Staff Papers, 42 (4), pp. 707–33.

Booth, A.E. (2000) ‘Inflation, expectations and the political economy of Conservative Britain, 1951–1964’, Historical Journal, 43 (3), pp. 827–47.

___ (2001a) ‘New revisionists and the Keynesian era in British economic policy’, Economic History Review, 54 (2), pp. 346–66.

___ (2001b) ‘Britain in the 1950s: a “Keynesian” managed economy?’, History of Political Economy, 33 (2), pp. 283–313.

Bordo, M.D. (1993) ‘The Bretton Woods inter-national monetary system: a historical overview’, in M.D. Bordo and B.J. Eichengreen (eds) (1993) A retrospective on the Bretton Woods system: lessons for international monetary reform. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 3–98.

Brandon, H. (1966) In the red: the struggle for sterling, 1964–1966. London: André‚ Deutsch.

Bretherton, R.F. (1999) Demand management, 1958–64. London: Institute of Contemporary British History.

Brittan, S. (1964) The Treasury under the Tories, 1951–1964. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

___ (1971) Steering the economy: the role of the Treasury, rev. edn. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

___ et al. (1988) ‘Symposium: 1967 devaluation’, Contemporary Record, 1 (4), pp. 44-53.

Britton, A.J.C. (1986) The trade cycle in Britain, 1952–1982. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Broadberry, S.N. (1997) The productivity race: British manufacturing in international perspective, 1850–1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ and Crafts, N.F.R. (1996) ‘British economic policy and industrial performance in the early post-war period’, Business History, 38 (4), pp. 65–91.

___ and ___ (1998) ‘The post-war settlement: not such a good bargain after all’, Business History, 40 (2), pp. 73–9.

Bronfenbrenner, M. (ed.) (1969) Is the business cycle obsolete? New York: John Wiley & Sons.

Browning, P. (1986) The Treasury and economic policy, 1964–1985. London: Longman.

Budge, I. (1993) ‘Relative decline as a political issue: ideological motivations of the politico-economic debate in post-war Britain’, Contemporary Record, 7 (1), pp. 1–23.

Bulpitt, J. and Burnham, P. (1999) ‘Operation Robot and the British political economy in the early-1950s: the politics of market strategies’, Contemporary British History, 13 (1), pp. 1–31.

Burnham, P. (1990) The political economy of postwar reconstruction. London: Macmillan.

___ (2000) ‘Britain’s external economic policy in the early 1950s: the historical significance of operation Robot’, Twentieth Century British History, 11 (4), pp. 379–408.

Butler, D.E. and Pinto-Duschinsky, M. (1971) The

Page 50: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

50 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

British general election of 1970. London: Macmillan.

Butler, R.A. (1971) The art of the possible. London: Hamish Hamilton.

Caballero, R.J. and Hammour, M.L. (1994) ‘The cleansing effect of recessions’, American Economic Review, 74 (5), pp. 1350–68.

Cairncross, A.K. (ed.) (1971) Britain’s economic prospects reconsidered. London: George Allen & Unwin.

___ (1985) Years of recovery: British economic policy, 1945–51. London: Methuen.

___ (1987) ‘Prelude to Radcliffe: monetary policy in the United Kingdom, 1948–57’, Rivista di Storia Economica, 2nd ser. 4 (1), pp. 1–20.

___ (ed.) (1989) The Robert Hall diaries. Vol. I: 1947–53. London: Unwin Hyman.

___ (ed.) (1991) The Robert Hall diaries. Vol. II: 1954–61. London: Routledge.

___ (1996a) Managing the British economy in the 1960s: a Treasury perspective. London: Macmillan.

___ (1996b) ‘The Heath government and the British economy’, in S. Ball and A. Seldon (eds) (1996) The Heath government, 1970–1974: a reappraisal. London: Longman, pp. 107–38.

___ (1999) Diaries: the Radcliffe committee and the Treasury, 1961–64. London: Institute of Contemporary British History.

___ and Eichengreen, B.J. (1983) Sterling in decline: the devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

___ and Watts, N. (1989) The Economic Section, 1939–1961: a study in economic advising. London: Routledge.

Cairncross, F. (ed.) (1981) Changing perceptions of economic policy: essays in honour of the seventieth birthday of Sir Alec Cairncross. London: Methuen.

___ and Cairncross, A.K. (eds) (1992) The legacy of the golden age: the 1960s and their economic consequences. London: Routledge.

Caves, R.E. (and Associates) (eds) (1968) Britain’s economic prospects. London: George Allen & Unwin.

___ (1971) ‘Second thoughts on Britain’s economic prospects’, in A.K. Cairncross (ed.) (1971) q.v., pp. 204–16.

Clarke, P.F. (1996) The Penguin history of Britain. Vol. 9: Hope and glory. Britain, 1900–1990. London: Allen Lane.

Clegg, J. (1996) ‘The United Kingdom: a par excellence two-way direct investor’, in J.H. Dunning and R. Narula (eds) (1996) Foreign direct investment and governments: catalysts for economic restructuring. London: Routledge, pp. 42–77.

Clifford, C. (1997) ‘The rise and fall of the Department of Economic Affairs, 1964–69: British government and indicative planning’, Contemporary British History, 11 (2), pp. 94–116.

___ and McMillan, A. (1997) ‘Witness seminar: the Department of Economic Affairs’, Contemporary British History, 11 (2), pp. 117–42.

Cockett, R. (1994) Thinking the unthinkable: think-tanks and the economic counter-revolution, 1931–1983. London: Harper Collins.

Cohen, B.J. (1971) The future of sterling as an international currency. London: Macmillan.

Cohen, C.D. (1971) British economic policy, 1960–1969. London: Butterworths.

Conan, A.R. (1966) The problem of sterling. London: Macmillan.

Coopey, R. and Woodward, N.W.C. (eds) (1996) Britain in the 1970s: the troubled economy. London: UCL Press.

Cooper, R.N. (1968) ‘The balance of payments’, in R.E. Caves and Associates (eds) (1968) q.v., pp. 147–97.

Crafts, N.F.R. (1991) ‘Economic growth’, in N.F.R. Crafts and N.W.C. Woodward (eds) (1991) q.v., pp. 260–90.

___ (1996) ‘“Post-neoclassical endogenous growth theory”: what are its policy implications?’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 12 (2), pp. 30–47.

___ and Toniolo, G. (eds) (1996) Economic growth in Europe since 1945. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ and Woodward, N.W.C. (eds) (1991) The British economy since 1945. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Croham, Lord (1992) ‘Were the instruments of control for domestic economic policy adequate?’, in F. Cairncross and A.K. Cairncross (eds) (1992) q.v., pp. 81–93.

CSO (1981) Economic trends, annual supplement, 1982 edn. London: HMSO.

Davis, W. (1968) Three years hard labour: the road to devaluation. London: André Deutsch.

Dell, E. (1996) The Chancellors: a history of the Chancellors of the Exchequer, 1945–90. London: HarperCollins.

Denison, E.F. (1968) ‘Economic growth’, in R.E. Caves et al. (eds) (1968) q.v., pp. 231–78.

Denman, J. and McDonald, P. (1996) ‘Unemploy-ment statistics from 1881 to the present day’, Labour Market Trends, 104 (January), pp. 5–18.

de Vries, M.G. (1987) Balance of payments adjustment, 1945 to 1986: the IMF experience. Washington, DC: IMF.

Dimsdale, N.H. (1991) ‘British monetary policy since 1945’, in N.F.R. Crafts and N.W.C. Woodward (eds) (1991) q.v., pp. 89–140.

Dornbusch, R. and Fischer, S. (1980) ‘Sterling and the external balance’, in R.E. Caves and L.B. Krause (eds) (1980) Britain’s economic perfor-mance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, pp. 21–80.

Dow, J.C.R. (1964) The management of the British economy, 1945–60. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ (1998) Major recessions: Britain and the world, 1920–1995. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Eichengreen, B.J. (1996a) Globalizing capital: a history of the international monetary system. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

___ (1996b) ‘Institutions and economic growth: Europe after World War II’, in N.F.R. Crafts and

Page 51: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 51__________________________________________________________________________________________

G. Toniolo (eds) (1996) q.v., pp. 38–72. ___ and Hatton, T.J. (1988) ‘Interwar unemployment

in international perspective: an overview’, in B.J. Eichengreen and T.J. Hatton (eds) (1988) Interwar unemployment in international perspective. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 1–59.

___ and Iversen, T. (1999) ‘Institutions and economic performance: evidence from the labour market’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 15 (4), pp. 121–38.

Einzig, P. (1970) The case against floating exchanges. London: Macmillan.

English, R. and Kenny, M. (1999) ‘British decline or the politics of declinism?’, British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 1 (2), pp. 252–66.

Feinstein, C.H. (1972) National income, expenditure and output of the United Kingdom, 1855–1965. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ (1990) ‘Benefits of backwardness and costs of continuity’, in A.W.M. Graham and A. Seldon (eds) (1990) Government and economies in the postwar world: economic policies and comparative performance, 1945–85. London: Routledge, pp. 284–93.

Fforde, J.S. (1992) The Bank of England and public policy, 1941–1958. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Flanders, M.J. (1989) International monetary economics, 1870–1960: between the classical and the new classical. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Fleming, J.M. (1962) ‘Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates’, IMF Staff Papers, 9 (3), pp. 369–79.

Foreman-Peck, J.S. (1991) ‘Trade and the balance of payments’, in N.F.R. Crafts and N.W.C. Woodward (eds) (1991) q.v., pp. 141–79.

___, Bowden, S.M. and McKinlay, A. (1995) The British motor industry. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

Freedman, L. et al. (1988) ‘Symposium: the Sandys white paper’, Contemporary Record, 2 (4), pp. 30–2.

Friedman, M. (1953) ‘The case for flexible exchange rates’, in M. Friedman (1953) Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 157–203.

Gamble, A.M. and Walkland, S.A. (1984) The British party system and economic policy, 1945–1983: studies in adversary politics. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Gorst, A., Johnman, L. and Lucas, W.S. (eds) (1989) Post-war Britain, 1945–64: themes and perspectives. London: Pinter.

Grassman, S. (1980) ‘Long-term trends in openness of national economies’, Oxford Economic Papers, n.s. 32 (1), pp. 123–33.

Green, E.H.H. (1992) ‘The influence of the City over British economic policy, c.1880–1960’, in Y. Cassis (ed.) (1992) Finance and financiers in European history, 1880–1960. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 193–218.

Hahn, F.H. and Matthews, R.C.O. (1964) ‘The theory of economic growth: a survey’, Economic Journal, 74 (4), pp. 779–902.

Halm, G.N. (ed.) (1970) Approaches to greater flexibility of exchange rates: the Bürgenstock papers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Hansard (1972a) ‘Budget statement’, Parliamentary Debates (House of Commons), 5th. ser., 833 (21 March), cols 1343–58.

___ (1972b) ‘£ sterling’, Parliamentary Debates (House of Commons), 5th. ser., 839 (23 June), cols 877–86.

Hansen, B. (1969) Fiscal policy in seven countries, 1955–1965: Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Sweden, United Kingdom, United States. Paris: OECD.

Haq, M. and Temple, P. (1998) ‘Overview: economic policy and the changing international division of labour’, in T. Buxton, P. Chapman and P. Temple (eds) (1998) Britain’s economic performance. London: Routledge, pp. 455–94.

Harris, R. and Sewill, B. (1975) British economic policy, 1970–74: two views. London: IEA.

Harrod, R.F. (1933) International economics. London: Macmillan.

___ (1963) The British economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.

___ (1967) Towards a new economic policy. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

___ (1971) Review of G.N. Halm (ed) (1970), Economic Journal, 81 (3), pp. 656–60.

Heath, E. (1998) The course of my life. London: Hodder & Stoughton.

Henderson, P.D. (1986) Innocence and design: the influence of economic ideas on policy. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Hirsch, F. (1965) The pound sterling: a polemic. London: Victor Gollancz.

HMSO (1959) Committee on the working of the monetary system (Radcliffe committee), Report, BPP 1958–9 (827), xvii.

___ (1961) Control of public expenditure (Plowden committee), Report, BPP 1960–1 (1432), xxi, 713.

Holmans, A.E. (1999) Demand management in Britain, 1953–58. London: Institute of Contemporary British History.

Howard, A. (1987) RAB: the life of R.A. Butler. London: Jonathan Cape.

Howson, S.K. (1975) Domestic monetary manage-ment in Britain, 1919–38. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ (1980) Sterling’s managed float: the operation of the Exchange Equalisation Account, 1932–39. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

___ (ed.) (1988) The collected papers of James Meade. Vol. III: International economics. London: Unwin Hyman.

Hutchison, T.W. (1968) Economics and economic policy in Britain, 1946–1966: some aspects of their interrelations. London: George Allen & Unwin.

Isard, P. (1995) Exchange rate economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

James, H. (1996) International monetary cooperation

Page 52: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

52 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

since Bretton Woods. Washington, DC and Oxford: IMF/Oxford University Press.

Jay, D.P.T (1985) Sterling: its use and misuse – a plea for moderation. London: Sidgwick & Jackson.

Johnman, L. (1989) ‘Defending the pound: the economics of the Suez crisis, 1956’, in A. Gorst et al. (eds) (1989) q.v., pp. 166–82.

Johnson, H.G. and Nash, J.E. (1969) UK and floating exchanges. London: IEA.

Jones, R. (1987) Wages and employment policy, 1936–1985. London: Allen & Unwin.

Kaldor, N. (1977) ‘The effect of devaluation on trade in manufactures’, in N. Kaldor (1978) Collected economic essays. Vol. 6: Further essays on applied economics. London: Duckworth, pp. 99–116.

Kalecki, M. (1943) ‘Political aspects of full employ-ment’, Political Quarterly, 14 (4), pp. 322–31.

Kennedy, C. (1962) ‘Monetary policy’, in G.D.N. Worswick and P.H. Ady (eds) (1962) The British economy in the nineteen-fifties. Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 301–25.

Kenen, P.B. (1985) ‘Macroeconomic theory and policy: how the closed economy was opened’, in R.W. Jones and P.B. Kenen (eds) (1985) Handbook of international economics. Vol. II. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp. 625–77.

Klug, A. and Smith, G.W. (1999) ‘Suez and sterling, 1956’, Explorations in Economic History, 36 (3), pp. 181–203.

Kynaston, D. (2001) The city of London. Vol. IV: A club no more, 1945–2000. London: Chatto & Windus.

Laidler, D.E.W. (1978) ‘A monetarist viewpoint’, in M.V. Posner (ed.) (1978) q.v., pp. 35–65.

___ (1984) ‘Harry Johnson as a macroeconomist’, Journal of Political Economy, 92 (4), pp. 592–615.

___ (1992) ‘The cycle before new classical economics’, in M.T. Belongia and M.R. Garfinkel (eds) (1992) The business cycle: theories and evidence. Proceedings of the sixteenth annual economic policy conference of the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. Boston, MA: Kluwer, pp. 85–112.

Lamont, N. (1999) In office. New York: Little, Brown.

Li, C.-W. (2000) ‘Growth and output fluctuations’, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 47 (2), pp. 95–113.

Lowe, R. (1997) ‘The core executive, modernization and the creation of PESC, 1960–64’, Public Administration, 75 (4), pp. 601–15.

___, Middleton, R., Ringe, A. and Rollings, N. (eds) (2002) Economic policy under the Conservatives, 1951–64: a PRO handbook. London: PRO.

MacDougall, G.D.A. (1987) Don and mandarin: memoirs of an economist. London: John Murray.

___ (1989) ‘“Battling with ROBOT”’, Royal Bank of Scotland Review, 161 (March), pp. 40–53.

McMahon, C. (1964) Sterling in the sixties. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Macmillan, H. (1971) Riding the storm, 1956–1959. London: Macmillan.

Macrae, N. (1963) Sunshades in October: an

analysis of the main mistakes in British economic policy since the mid nineteen-fifties. London: George Allen & Unwin.

Maddison, A. (1960) ‘The postwar business cycle in Western Europe and the role of government policy’, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 13 (2), pp. 99–148.

___ (1964) Economic growth in the west: comparative experience in Europe and North America. London: George Allen & Unwin.

___ (1991) Dynamic forces in capitalist development: a long-run comparative view. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

___ (1995) Monitoring the world economy, 1820–1992. Paris: OECD.

Major, R.L. (1962) ‘Appendix: errors and omissions in the balance of payments estimates’, National Institute Economic Review, 19 (February), pp. 57–9.

Manser, W.A.P. (1971) Britain in balance: the myth of failure. London: Longman.

Marglin, S.A. and Schor, J.B. (eds) (1990) The golden age of capitalism: reinterpreting the postwar experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Martin, P. and Rogers, C.A. (2000) ‘Long-term growth and short-term economic instability’, European Economic Review, 44 (2), pp. 359–81.

Masera, R. (1974) ‘The J-curve: UK experience after the 1967 devaluation’, Metroeconomica, 26 (1), pp. 40–62.

Matthews, R.C.O. (1959) The trade cycle: a study of the theory of economic fluctuations. Cambridge: Nisbet/Cambridge University Press.

___ (1968) ‘Why has Britain had full employment since the war?’, Economic Journal, 78 (3), pp. 555–69.

___ (1969a) ‘Postwar business cycles in the United Kingdom’, in M. Bronfenbrenner (ed.) (1969) q.v., pp. 99–135.

___ (1969b) ‘Why growth rates differ’, Economic Journal, 79 (2), pp. 261–8.

___ (1971) ‘The role of demand management’, in A.K. Cairncross (ed.) (1971) q.v., pp. 13–35.

___, Feinstein, C.H. and Odling-Smee, J.C. (1982) British economic growth, 1856–1973. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Meade, J.E. (1948) ‘Financial policy and the balance of payments’, Economica, n.s. 15 (2), pp. 101–15. Rep. in S.K. Howson (ed) (1988) q.v., vol. III, pp. 67–80.

___ (1951) The theory of international economic policy. Vol. I: The balance of payments. London: Oxford University Press.

___ (1955a) The theory of international economic policy. Vol. II: Trade and welfare. London: Oxford University Press.

___ (1955b) ‘The case for variable exchange rates’, Three Banks Review, 27 (September), pp. 3–27. Rep. in S.K. Howson (ed) (1988) q.v., vol. III, pp. 161–76.

___ (1966) ‘Exchange-rate flexibility’, Three Banks Review, 70 (June), pp. 3–27.

Michie, R.C. (1992) The city of London: continuity

Page 53: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] 53__________________________________________________________________________________________

and change, 1850–1990. London: Macmillan. ___ (1998) ‘Insiders, outsiders and the dynamics of

change in the City of London since 1900’, Journal of Contemporary History, 33 (4), pp. 547–71.

Middleton, R. (1989) ‘Keynes’s legacy for postwar economic management’, in A. Gorst et al. (eds) (1989) q.v., pp. 22–42.

___ (1996) Government versus the market: the growth of the public sector, economic management and British economic performance, c.1890–1979. Cheltenham and Brookfield, VT: Edward Elgar.

___ (1998) Charlatans or saviours?: economists and the British economy from Marshall to Meade. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

___ (2000) The British economy since 1945: engaging with the debate. London: Macmillan.

Milner, C.R. (1980) ‘Payments and exchange rate problems’, in W.P.J. Maunder (ed.) (1980) The British economy in the 1970s. London: Heinemann Educational, pp. 218–46.

Milward, A.S. (with assistance of G. Brennan and F. Romero) (1992) The European rescue of the nation-state. London: Routledge.

Moggridge, D.E. (1972) British monetary policy, 1924–1931: the Norman conquest of $4.86. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Mosley, P. (1984) The making of economic policy: theory and evidence from Britain and the United States since 1945. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.

___ (1985) ‘When is a policy instrument not an instrument?: fiscal marksmanship in Britain, 1951–84’, Journal of Public Policy, 6 (1), pp. 69–86.

Mundell, R.A. (1962) ‘The appropriate use of monetary and fiscal policy for internal and external stability’, IMF Staff Papers, 9 (1), pp. 70–7.

___ (1963) ‘Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 29 (4), pp. 475–85.

Mussa, M.L. (1979) ‘Macroeconomic interdepen-dence and the exchange rate regime’, in R. Dornbusch and J.A. Frenkel (eds) (1979) International economic policy: theory and evidence. Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University Press, pp. 160–204.

NEDO (1976) ‘Cyclical fluctuations in the United Kingdom economy’, NEDO Discussion Paper, 3.

OECD (1996) Historical statistics, 1960–1994. Paris: OECD.

___ (1998) OECD Economic Outlook, 63 (June). Paris: OECD.

ONS (1999) Economic trends, annual supplement, 1998 edn. London: HMSO.

Opie, R.G. (1968) ‘The making of economic policy’, in H. Thomas (ed.) (1968) Crisis in the civil service. London: Anthony Blond, pp. 53–82.

___ (1972) ‘Economic planning and growth’, in W. Beckerman (ed.) (1972) q.v., pp. 157–77.

Paish, F.W. (1962) Studies in an inflationary economy: the United Kingdom, 1948–1961. London: Macmillan.

___ (1968) ‘How the economy works’, Lloyds Bank Review, 88 (April), pp. 1–30. Rep. in F.W. Paish (1970) q.v., pp. 129–62.

___ (1970) How the economy works and other essays. London: Macmillan.

Peden, G.C. (2000) The Treasury and British public policy, 1906–1959. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Pemberton, H. (2000) ‘Policy networks and policy learning: UK economic policy in the 1960s and 1970s’, Public Administration, 78 (4), pp. 771–92.

___ (2001) ‘A taxing task: combating Britain’s relative economic decline in the 1960s’, Twentieth Century British History, 12, forthcoming.

Pliatzky, L. (1984) Getting and spending: public expenditure, employment and inflation, 2nd edn. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Plowden, E. (1989) An industrialist in the Treasury: the post-war years. London: André Deutsch.

Polak, J.J. (1995) ‘Fifty years of exchange rate research and policy at the International Monetary Fund’, IMF Staff Papers, 42 (4), pp. 734–61.

Pollard, S. (1984) The wasting of the British economy: British economic policy 1945 to the present, 2nd edn. London: Croom Helm.

Porter, D. (1996) ‘Government and the economy’, in R. Coopey and N.W.C. Woodward (eds) (1996) q.v., pp. 34–54.

Posner, M.V. (ed.) (1978) Demand management. London: Heinemann.

Pressnell, L.S. (1987) External economic policy since the war. Vol. I: The post-war financial settlement. London: HMSO.

___ (2001) External economic policy since the war. Vol. II. London: Frank Cass.

Proctor, S.J. (1993) ‘Floating convertibility: the emergence of the Robot plan, 1951–52’, Contemporary Record, 7 (1), pp. 24–43.

Reynolds, D. (2000) Britannia overruled: British policy and world power in the 20th century, 2nd edn. London: Longman.

Ringe, A. and Rollings, N. (2000) ‘Responding to relative decline: the creation of the National Economic Development Council’, Economic History Review, 53 (2), pp. 331–53.

Robinson, J. (1937) ‘The foreign exchanges’, in J. Robinson (ed.) (1937) Essays in the theory of employment. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, pp. 134–55.

Saint-Paul, G. (1997) ‘Business cycles and long-run growth’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13 (3), pp. 145–53.

Sayers, R.S. (1960) ‘Monetary thought and monetary policy in England’, Economic Journal, 70 (4), pp. 710–24.

Schenk, C.R. (1994) Britain and the sterling area: from devaluation to convertibility in the 1950s. London: Routledge.

Scott, M.FG. (1959) ‘What should we do about the sterling area?’, Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Statistics, 21 (4), pp. 213–51.

Seymour-Ure, C. (1991) The British press and broadcasting since 1945. Oxford: Blackwell.

Shonfield, A. (1958) British economic policy since the war. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

___ (1965) Modern capitalism: the changing balance of public and private power. Oxford: Oxford

Page 54: STRUGGLING WITH THE IMPOSSIBLE: STERLING, THE ...hirm/Downloadpapers/Middleton...4.2 Devaluation, 1949 31 4.3 Operation ROBOT, 1951–2 and its aftermath 34 4.4 The great unmentionable:

54 Struggling with the impossible [2nd revise, Last printed 21/05/2003 08:58] __________________________________________________________________________________________

University Press. Sinclair, P.J.N. (1985) ‘The balance of payments and

the exchange rate’, in D.J. Morris (ed.) (1985) The economic system in the UK, 3rd edn. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 174–216.

Snowdon, B., Vane, H. and Wynarczyk, P. (1994) A modern guide to macroeconomics: an introduction to competing schools of thought. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

Stern, R.M. (1973) The balance of payments: theory and economic policy. London: Macmillan.

Stewart, M. (1977) The Jekyll and Hyde years: politics and economic policy since 1964. London: J.M. Dent.

Strange, S. (1971) Sterling and British policy: a political study of an international currency in decline. London: Oxford University Press.

Supple, B.E. (1994) ‘Fear of failing: economic history and the decline of Britain’, Economic History Review, 47 (3), pp. 441–58.

Tew, J.H.B. (1978a) ‘Monetary policy, part I’, in F.T. Blackaby (ed.) (1978) q.v., pp. 218–57.

___ (1978b) ‘Policies aimed at improving the balance of payments’, in F.T. Blackaby (ed.) (1978) q.v., pp. 304–59.

Thirlwall, A.P. (1970) ‘Another autopsy on Britain’s balance of payments, 1958–1967, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 23 (3), pp. 308–25.

___ (1979) ‘The balance of payments constraint as an explanation of international growth rate differences’, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review, 32 (1), pp. 45–53.

___ (1988) ‘What is wrong with balance of payments adjustment theory?’, Royal Bank of Scotland Review, 157 (March), pp. 3–19.

___ and Gibson, H.D. (1992) Balance-of-payments theory and the United Kingdom experience, 4th edn. London: Macmillan.

Tomlinson, J.D. (1996) ‘Inventing “decline”: the falling behind of the British economy in the postwar years’, Economic History Review, 49 (4), pp. 731–57.

___ (1997) Democratic socialism and economic policy: the Attlee years, 1945–1951. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

___ and Tiratsoo, N. (1998) ‘“An old story, freshly told”?: a comment on Broadberry and Crafts’ approach to Britain’s early post-war economic performance’, Business History, 40 (2), pp. 62–72.

Toye, R. (2000) ‘The Labour Party’s external economic policy in the 1940s’, Historical Journal, 43 (1), pp. 189–215.

UN Secretariat of the Economic Commission for Europe (1964) Economic survey of Europe in 1961, pt 2: Some factors in economic growth in Europe during the 1950s. Geneva: UN.

Whiting, A. (1976) ‘An international comparison of the instability of economic growth: is Britain’s poor growth performance due to government stop-go induced fluctuations?’, Three Banks Review, 109 (March), pp. 26–46.

Williams, K., Williams, J. and Thomas, D. (1983) Why are the British bad at manufacturing?

London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. Williamson, J. (1966) How to stop stop-go. London:

New Orbits Group. ___ (1981) ‘The crawling peg in historical per-

spective’, in J. Williamson (ed.) (1981) Exchange rate rules: the theory, performance and prospects of the crawling peg. London: Macmillan, pp. 3–30. Rep. in C. Milner (ed.) (1987) Political economy and international money: selected essays of John Williamson. New York: New York University Press, pp. 63–93.

Wilson, J.H. (1971) The Labour government, 1964–1970: a personal record. London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson.

Wilson, T. (1966) ‘Instability and the rate of growth’, Lloyds Bank Review, 81 (July), pp. 16–32.

Woodward, N.W.C. (1993) ‘Labour’s economic performance, 1964–70’, in R. Coopey, S. Fielding and N. Tiratsoo (eds) (1993) The Wilson governments, 1964–1970. London: Pinter, pp. 72–101.

Worswick, G.D.N. (1969a) Review of R.E. Caves and Associates (1968), Economic Journal, 79 (1), pp. 117–20.

___ (1969b) ‘Fiscal policy and stabilization in Britain’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1 (1), pp. 36–60. Rep. in A.K. Cairncross (ed.) (1971) q.v., pp. 36–60.

Yeager, L.B. (1966) International monetary relations: theory, history and policy. New York: Harper & Row.

Young, H. (1998) This blessed plot: Britain and Europe from Churchill to Blair. London: Macmillan.

Young, J.W. (2000) Britain and European unity, 1945–1999, 2nd edn. London: Macmillan.