the role of targeted predictors...

40
RUHR ECONOMIC PAPERS The Role of Targeted Predictors for Nowcasting GDP with Bridge Models: Application to the Euro Area #559 Tobias Kitlinski Philipp an de Meulen

Upload: others

Post on 18-Oct-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

RUHRECONOMIC PAPERS

The Role of Targeted Predictors for

Nowcasting GDP with Bridge Models:

Application to the Euro Area

#559

Tobias KitlinskiPhilipp an de Meulen

Page 2: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Imprint

Ruhr Economic Papers

Published by

Ruhr-Universität Bochum (RUB), Department of EconomicsUniversitätsstr. 150, 44801 Bochum, Germany

Technische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social SciencesVogelpothsweg 87, 44227 Dortmund, Germany

Universität Duisburg-Essen, Department of EconomicsUniversitätsstr. 12, 45117 Essen, Germany

Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI)Hohenzollernstr. 1-3, 45128 Essen, Germany

Editors

Prof. Dr. Thomas K. BauerRUB, Department of Economics, Empirical EconomicsPhone: +49 (0) 234/3 22 83 41, e-mail: [email protected]

Prof. Dr. Wolfgang LeiningerTechnische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social SciencesEconomics – MicroeconomicsPhone: +49 (0) 231/7 55-3297, e-mail: [email protected]

Prof. Dr. Volker ClausenUniversity of Duisburg-Essen, Department of EconomicsInternational EconomicsPhone: +49 (0) 201/1 83-3655, e-mail: [email protected]

Prof. Dr. Roland Döhrn, Prof. Dr. Manuel Frondel, Prof. Dr. Jochen KluveRWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49-213, e-mail: [email protected]

Editorial Offi ce

Sabine WeilerRWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49-213, e-mail: [email protected]

Ruhr Economic Papers #559

Responsible Editor: Roland Döhrn

All rights reserved. Bochum, Dortmund, Duisburg, Essen, Germany, 2015

ISSN 1864-4872 (online) – ISBN 978-3-86788-640-6The working papers published in the Series constitute work in progress circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comments. Views expressed represent exclusively the authors’ own opinions and do not necessarily refl ect those of the editors.

Page 3: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Ruhr Economic Papers #559

Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen

The Role of Targeted Predictors for

Nowcasting GDP with Bridge Models:

Application to the Euro Area

Page 4: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Bibliografi sche Informationen

der Deutschen Nationalbibliothek

Die Deutsche Bibliothek verzeichnet diese Publikation in der deutschen National-bibliografi e; detaillierte bibliografi sche Daten sind im Internet über: http://dnb.d-nb.de abrufb ar.

http://dx.doi.org/10.4419/86788640ISSN 1864-4872 (online)ISBN 978-3-86788-640-6

Page 5: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen1

The Role of Targeted Predictors for

Nowcasting GDP with Bridge Models:

Application to the Euro Area

Abstract

Using factor models, it has recently been shown that a pre-selection of indicators improves GDP forecasts in the very short-term. The aim of this paper is to adopt this research to the methodology of bridge models in combination with pooling approaches. Focusing on Euro Area GDP between 2005 and 2013, we fi nd that a selection of targeted predictors by means of soft- and hard-threshold algorithms improves the forecasting performance, especially during periods of economic crisis. While a critical number of indicators are needed to include all relevant information, adding additional indicators has a negative eff ect on forecasting performance, all the more, if the set of indicators becomes unbalanced.

JEL Classifi cation: C53, E37

Keywords: Forecasting; bridge equations; pooling of forecasts

May 2015

1 Both RWI. - We thank Roland Döhrn, Michael Roos, Christoph M. Schmidt and Torsten Schmidt for helpful comments and suggestions. - All correspondence to: Tobias Kitlinski, e-mail: [email protected]

Page 6: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

1 Introduction

Reliable information on the current macroeconomic situation is an essential in-

gredient of decision making within private enterprises, central banks and govern-

ments. It helps to identify the current stage of the business cycle and thereby

builds an important starting point for assessing the future path of the economy.

Unfortunately GDP - which is the most important indicator of economic activity

- is released only quarterly and mostly with considerable delay.1 To estimate

GDP more timely, forecasters therefore refer to monthly economic indicators - of

which a plethora is available.

To condense the information contained in these indicators into a single fore-

cast, there are basically two strands of approaches. With the factor model (FM)

approach, the information is pooled before the regressions are estimated. The

numerous indicators are first combined in few common factors. Then, these fac-

tors jointly enter a regression equation to forecast GDP.2 The alternative strand

suggests to use indicators directly to produce different forecasts of GDP and to

condense the information contained in the forecasts in a second step, e.g. by

pooling techniques.

One approach in this field is Mixed-data sampling (MIDAS), which regresses

quarterly GDP on monthly indicator observations.3 Statistically less sophisti-

cated, Bridge models (BM) regress quarterly GDP on quarterly aggregates of

the monthly indicator values.4 Generating forecasts by means of simple linear

regressions, BM are a popular and widely used forecasting tool, which in general

1For the countries of the EU, the first official estimates are published six weeks after the endof the reference quarter.

2The literature on forecasting with FM is extensive, see (Diebold and Lopez, 1996; Giannoneet al., 2008). Applications to forecasting Euro Area GDP can be found in Angelini et al. (2011),Banbura and Runstler (2011), Marcellino et al. (2003) and Runstler et al. (2009).

3See e.g. Clements and Galvao (2008), Clements and Galvao (2009), Kuzin et al. (2011),Ferrara et al. (2014) and Foroni et al. (2015).

4Among the papers which put their focus on forecasting Euro Area GDP with BM areGrassmann and Keereman (2001), Diron (2008), Hahn and Skudelny (2008) and Drechsel andMaurin (2011).

4

Page 7: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

do not perform worse than MIDAS and FM in terms of forecast precision.5

Despite their differences, all forecast approaches have one problem in common:

Which indicators should be taken into account in first place? In this regard,

forecasters face a trade-off: Focusing on only a few indicators bears the risk

of ignoring important information for forecasting, while considering too many

indicators may lead to increased error variance. Moreover, if a certain group

of predictors is overrepresented in the set of indicators, forecasts may be biased

since different indicator groups may explain different parts of GDP. This trade-

off generates the starting point of our paper, which poses the question, whether

reducing large indicator sets toward fewer carefully chosen predictors in a first

step can reduce forecast errors.

This question has recently become popular in the field of FM. Boivin and

Ng (2006) show that a smaller set of indicators can enhance forecast accuracy

if the influence of factors which provide high forecasting power declines with an

increasing panel size. Bai and Ng (2008) show that if the set of indicators is not

only small but restricted to those series which well explain the target variable,

this also improves forecasts of FM. In the present paper we analyze if this line of

reasoning can be adopted to the field of BM, which, to the best of our knowledge,

has not been done before.6

If we follow the arguments of Boivin and Ng (2006) and Bai and Ng (2008),

additional indicators (and thus additional forecasts) may harm forecast accuracy

if they only add noise. Whether this materializes in the field of BM is however

uncertain. Therefore, it is at the heart of our paper to investigate if a selection

of indicators provides a better forecasting performance of BM than including

5See Angelini et al. (2011), Kitchen and Monaco (2003), Schumacher and Dreger (2004),Antipa et al. (2012) and Schumacher (2014).

6This is at least true if we focus on forecasting with many low-dimensional bridge equations.Alternatively, it can be set up one single bridge equation including a small representative set ofindicators as regressors. In this strand, reducing the set of indicators is of course an importantaspect to prevent overfitting. However, since it can only be handled a limited number ofindicators, this strand is less suitable to investigate forecast accuracy with regard to the size ofthe indicator set.

5

Page 8: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

all available information. On the one hand, like for FM, additional indicators

may trigger overrepresentation of a certain group of indicators and thus bias

forecasts of BM. On the other hand, adding as many indicators as possible to the

BM should not harm forecast precision: Additional indicators mean additional

forecasts and if these were useful in enhancing forecast accuracy, an appropriate

pooling technique would account for them, while if not, they would simply be left

out of consideration.

In focusing on the prediction of quarterly growth rates of Euro Area GDP

between 2005 and 2013, we apply two different data reduction rules, soft- and

hard-thresholding, to identify the so-called ”targeted predictors” from a large set

of predetermined indicators. To analyze the sensitivity of forecast accuracy with

regard to the set of targeted predictors, we test different thresholds. Constructing

quarterly aggregates of the respective targeted predictors, we set up bridge equa-

tions, run one-step-ahead forecasts and pool them by means of different weighting

schemes.

To mimic the ragged edge of the dataset a forecaster is faced with in real

time, we account for the monthly release pattern of our indicators. In a first step

we forecast the missing values by means of univariate autoregressive models. In

a second step we compute the quarterly aggregates. Since new indicator infor-

mation arrives every month, we run our forecasts monthly to correspond to the

monthly frequency of indicator releases. As GDP is released only quarterly, this

results in three successive forecast rounds on each quarterly GDP growth rate.

To not mix up the different levels of information, we conduct separate analyses

for forecasts made in the first, second and third forecasting round, respectively

It turns out that pre-selecting around 30 out of the 132 indicators provides

the lowest average forecast errors for most of the pooling approaches. While it

needs this critical number to include the relevant information for forecasting Euro

Area GDP, adding further indicators leads to overrepresentation of financial and

survey indicators - and apparently to lower forecast precision. Interestingly, the

forecasting performance of targeted predictors is significantly better in compari-

6

Page 9: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

son to the whole indicator set if we leave out the period of the Great Recession.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 introduces the thresh-

old algorithms used for the pre-selection of indicators. Section 3 introduces the

system of bridge models and the different pooling techniques and it explains the

measurement of forecasting performance. Section 4 reports the empirical results

before section 5 concludes.

2 Selection of targeted predictors

Ideally, a set of predictors is chosen to include all relevant information for forceast-

ing the target variable. If, however, one predictor is highly correlated with an-

other, this bears the risk that instead of adding predictive power to the set, it

only adds noise, making forecasts less efficient. Further, if a certain group of pre-

dictors is overrepresented in the set of indicators, this may bias forecasts toward

the part of the target variable this group explains. Then a more parsimonious

but balanced set of predictors may provide more accurate forecasts.

Looking to the literature, the finding of Bai and Ng (2008) that identifying

a subset of suitable predictors is effective in improving forecast performance of

factor models was recently confirmed in several studies. Caggiano et al. (2011)

showed that using smaller subsets of the available large data set improves the

forecast performance of factor models for the six largest Euro Area economies,

the Euro Area aggregate and UK. Using Monte Carlo analyses, Alvarez et al.

(2012) show that small scale factor models outperform larger ones in terms of

forecast precision. To reduce the size of the data, they group indicator series into

different categories and choose one representative indicator from each group.

Focusing on forecasting models of Euro Area GDP, Girardi et al. (2014) ana-

lyzed dimension reduction methods. They used factor models that bridge factors

extracted from a large panel to quarterly national accounts and conclude that

using targeting predictors is an effective way to improve forecast performance. In

the field of BM, the related literature is scarce. To the best of our knowledge there

7

Page 10: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

is only one paper, Bulligan et al. (2012), which investigates the effect of screening

targeted predictors on forecast precision. Focusing on Italian GDP, the authors

use different data reduction rules, namely hard- and soft-thresholding methods,

to reduce the dimension of the data and find that the forecasting performance

improves by screening targeted predictors. However, other than we do, Bulligan

et al. (2012) use the set of targeted predictors and extract the most informative

among them to set up a single forecast equation.

In the present paper, we adhere to the literature in using hard- and soft-

thresholding algorithms to select targeted predictors. The selection processes

start from a large set of 132 potentially relevant indicators, chosen in line with

the forecasting literature. It consists of real-economy indicators, survey indi-

cators, financial-market indicators, prices, as well as global economic indicators

(see Section A.2). All indicators enter the thresholding algorithms as stationary

variables. Below we describe how the algorithms work.

2.1 Hard-thresholding

Hard-thresholding algorithms aim to select those indicators which are most highly

correlated with the target according to some predetermined threshold. In order

to find those indicators, we adhere to Bair et al. (2006) and Bai and Ng (2008).

Precisely, for each of the 132 potentially relevant indicators we run a regression

of the quarterly growth rate of Euro Area GDP (yt) on an indicator-specific

function fi (xi,t−pi , (L)yt), where xi,t−pi is the potentially lagged indicator with

pi ∈ {0, ..., 6} and (L)yt is a lag polynomial of degree qi ∈ {0, ..., 4}. In each

regression, pi and qi are determined by the SIC to equal the optimal number of

lags. The estimation period consists of 24 quarters between 1999Q1 and 2004Q4.

In what follows, an indicator is selected as targeted predictor if and only if the

significance level (p-value) of the associated regression coefficient exceeds some

threshold α. In our forecast exercise we choose the common significance levels,

α = 0.9, α = 0.95 and α = 0.99.

While hard-thresholding is a very simple procedure, one obvious shortcom-

8

Page 11: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

ing is that the selection process ignores the cross-correlations between indica-

tors. If the targeted predictors are highly correlated with each other, this bears

the risk that important information for forecasting is ignored. Methods of soft-

thresholding can remedy this deficiency.

2.2 Soft-thresholding

As soft-thresholding rule, we apply a forward selection algorithm, which will be

explained in the next paragraph. This algorithm explicitly accounts for the corre-

lations between indicators. Originally, soft-thresholding methods were applied in

biostatistics to find out if groups of genes in a DNA microarray can be applied to

predict the appearance of a certain disease (Donoho and Johnstone (1994)). Bai

and Ng (2008) used the soft-thresholding approach for the first time to determine

a smaller group of indicators from a large data set in the forecasting literature.

The forward selection algorithm proceeds stepwise. Within the estimation

period (1999Q1 − 2004Q4) it tries to find at each step the indicator which best

explains the part of the target not explained by the predictors selected so far.

Among our candidate set of 132 indicators, the algorithm starts from the

indicator (afterwards called x1) most highly correlated with y. Then, it searches

for a second indicator (x2 �= x1), which is most highly correlated with the residual

(u1) from the regression of y on x1, where x1 enters the regression with its optimal

lag p ∈ {0, ..., 6} according to the SIC. Regressing u1 on x2 again leaves some

unexplained part (u2) and again the algorithm searches among the remaining

indicators the one - then called x3 - that shows the highest correlation with u2.

The algorithm proceeds like this until there is no indicator left, where in each

regression of ui on xi+1, xi+1 enters with its optimal lag, restricted to a maximum

of six. As a result, we are provided with a ranking of indicators. To select the

targeted predictors, we simply select the k highest ranked indicators. In our

forecast exercise, we set k equal to the two extreme values 1 and 132 as well as

the multiples of 10 in between.

All in all, we end up with 17 different sets of targeted predictors, which

9

Page 12: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

are related to 3 different thresholds with the hard-thresholding approach and 14

different thresholds with the soft-thresholding approach. Based on this variety, we

are given the opportunity to investigate the sensitivity of forecasting performance

with regards to the size and the contribution of the predictor set.

3 Forecast evaluation framework

Having selected different sets of targeted predictors, we compare them with regard

to their forecasting performance. The forecasts are derived from linear estima-

tions of Euro Area GDP on the predictors. To cope with the different frequencies

of GDP and indicators, we calculate quarterly aggregates of the monthly indi-

cators. In doing so, we only account for data which were available at the time

of each forecast and predict the respective missings with the help of univariate

autoregressive models.7 Since the ragged edge of the data frequently changes over

a month, we have to be precise in determining the date of each forecast.

For the present paper, we updated the data on July 10, 2014 and applied the

corresponding shape of the ragged edge to the whole forecast period.8 Figure 1

gives an illustration of this pattern for three successive months, in which one and

the same GDP growth rate is forecasted. As an example, it is considered the

monthly cycle of forecasting GDP in Q2. Since second-quarter GDP is released

around August 15, the three forecasting rounds take place on June 10, July 10

and August 10.

3.1 Bridge equations

For any set of targeted predictors and any forecasting round, we have 36 quarterly

GDP growth rates (y1 . . . y36) between 2005q1 and 2013q4 to be forecast one step

7For each indicator and each forecasting round, the number of lags of the autoregressivemodel is determined by the SIC and restricted to a maximum of 12 months.

8Using the data from mid-2014 rather than real-time data for each forecaast, it should benoted that our forecast exercise is pseudo-real time.

10

Page 13: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

ahead. In the run-up of forecasting yt in round j, we determine a rolling window

of 24 in-sample quarters between t − 24 and t − 1 to estimate the relationship

between the targeted predictors and GDP growth.9

The in-sample estimations are based on a large variety of bridge equations

(system of bridge equations), which consists of three different subsystems. The

first subsystem includes K single indicator equations of the type

yτ = ck +

p∑m=0

βm,k · xk,τ−m + εk,τ τ = t− 24, . . . , t− 1 , (1)

where xk,· is the quarterly average of a representative predictor in the total set

of K targeted predictors. The second subsystem includes the K × K−12

possible

combinations of pairwise indicator equations of the type

yτ = ck,o+

p∑m=0

γm,k·xk,τ−m+

q∑n=0

γp+1+n,o·xo,τ−n+εk,o,τ τ = t−24, . . . , t−1 ; o �= k .

(2)

The third subsystem includes K equations each using one of the targeted predic-

tors as well as lagged dependent variables as regressors. A representative type of

such equation is given by

yτ = dk +

p∑m=0

δm,k · xk,τ−m +

q∑n=1

δp+n,k · yt−n + μk,τ τ = t− 24, . . . , t− 1 . (3)

In equations (1)-(3), parameters c and d denote the regression intercepts, the

β’s, γ’s and δ’s give the regression coefficients estimated by OLS, while ε and

μ denote usual zero-mean error terms. p and q give the number of lags of the

respective regressor, restricted to a maximum of 6 and optimized by the SIC. We

denote the optimal values of p and q by popt and qopt, respectively.

9Note that we need at least one forecast error if we want to pool forecasts based on theirpast performances. Hence, our investigation starts with the forecasts of GDP in 2005q2.

11

Page 14: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

3.2 Forecasts

Based on estimates of β, γ, δ, c and d from equations (1)-(3), 2K+K×K−12

single

forecasts of yt are calculated in each forecasting round. Recall that in contrast to

the in-sample period, monthly indicator values are not entirely observable over

the forecast period. Hence, the quarterly aggregates x partly rely on forecasts of

monthly indicators, which in turn depend on the information available and thus

on the time it was computed. This is why the forecasting round j enters the

forecast equations below.

yjk,t = ck +

popt∑m=0

βm,k · xjk,t−m ∀ k = 1, . . . , K (4)

yjk,o,t = ck,o +

popt∑m=0

γm,k · xjk,t−m +

qopt∑n=0

γp+1+n,o · xjo,t−n ∀ k = 1, . . . , K (5)

yjk,y,t = dk +

popt∑m=0

δm,k · xjk,t−m +

qopt∑n=1

δp+n,k · yt−n ∀ k = 1, . . . , K , (6)

3.3 Pooling of forecasts

To end up with a single forecast in each forecasting round, we apply various

linear pooling approaches widely used in the literature: the mean, median, sev-

eral approaches that consider the in-sample fit (R2 and the AIC) as well as

approaches which weight models’ past forecasting performance (Trimming ap-

proaches).10 These approaches have in common that the pooled forecast is con-

structed as a weighted average of all or a subsample of underlying forecasts, where

individual weights sum to one.

We start with very simple approaches commonly used as benchmarks. The

most simple one is the mean forecast, which gives equal weight to all forecasts.

10In the literature it has been shown that forecast combination is able to reduce forecasterrors on average compared to single forecasts, see e.g. Stock and Watson (2003a), Stock andWatson (2004), Timmermann (2006) and Drechsel and Scheufele (2012a,b).

12

Page 15: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Another approach simply selects the median of all forecasts.

In a second group are pooling approaches that take into consideration the

in-sample fit of bridge equations. We use two approaches that assign weights

according to the variance of models’ in-sample estimation errors. We consider the

R2 and the AIC as information criteria, where the weights given to the forecasts

of the single model i = 1, . . . , 2K +K · K−12

are constructed in the following way:

ωICi,t = e−0.5·(|ICi,t−ICopt,t|)/

2K+K·K−12∑

h=1

e−0.5·(|ICh,t−ICopt,t|) . (7)

IC denotes the respective information criterium, R2 or AIC. Depending on the

criterium, ICopt,t either equals the largest R2 value (R2max,t) or the smallest AIC

value (AICmin,t) among the in-sample estimations.11

Using in-sample information for the assignment of weights is reasonable if the

estimated relationships remain stable over the forecast horizon. In the presence

of structural instabilities, however, models which perform good in-sample may

generate poor forecasts, see e.g. Stock and Watson (2003b). Taking this cri-

tique into consideration, we introduce a third group of pooling approaches, which

accounts for models’ past forecast errors. Since the forecast environment system-

atically changes over the forecasting rounds, we only account for past forecast

errors made in the same forecasting round to assign the weights.

A first approach, called trimming approach, takes the mean forecast from only

the best 1− x% of models in terms of past forecast performance (Timmermann,

2006).12 In line with the literature we set different thresholds of x, 0.25, 0.5

and 0.75. A second approach calculates weights according to the discounted

11Among the in-sample pooling approaches, note that we abstain from employing a ”restrictedleast squares estimator”. With the weights constructed from the estimated coefficients of re-gressing GDP on its single forecasts, the in-sample RMSFE would be minimized (Granger andRamanathan, 1984; Drechsel and Scheufele, 2012b). However, given our relatively small samplesize and 405 forecasts on each yt, the restricted least squares estimator is likely to suffer fromoverparameterization, as argued e.g. in Drechsel and Scheufele (2012b).

12Past forecast performance is measured in terms of the mean squared forecast error fromthe complete history of forecasts.

13

Page 16: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

means of models’ past squared forecast errors. The weights assigned are inversely

proportional to the sum of discounted means of past squared forecast errors of

all models:13

ωji,t =

(∑t−1l=1 δ

t−l · (εji,l)2)−1

∑2K+K·K−12

h=1

(∑t−1l=1 δ

t−l · (εjh,l)2)−1 . (8)

3.4 Measuring Forecasting performance

With 8 different pooling approaches and three different forecasting rounds, there

are 3·8 levels to systematically compare the 17 different sets of targeted predictors

(3 sets for the hard- and 14 for the soft-threshold approach) with regard to their

forecast performance. To measure the forecast performance of the 3·8·17 forecastprocedures, we relate their RMSFE to the RMSFE conducted by a benchmark

autoregressive model of GDP growth

yt = a+

popt∑m=1

λm · yt−m , (9)

where each forecast yt is based on estimating a and the λm between t − 24 and

t − 1.14 With the forecasts of the benchmark AR model, the relative RMSFE

then reads as follows:

relative RMSFE =

√∑36t=1

(yt − yj,sw,t

)2√∑36

t=1 (yt − yt)2

. (10)

In equation (10), yj,sw,t describes the forecast of yt conducted in forecasting round j

which was pooled from the set of targeted predictors s using the pooling approach

w.

13In line with the literature, the discount factor δ is set equal to 0.95.14The number of lags popt ∈ {1, 2} is optimized in-sample by the SIC before each forecast.

14

Page 17: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

While a relative RMSFE smaller than one means that the considered forecast

procedure outperforms the prediction accuracy of the benchmark AR model, we

need to consider the standard deviation of forecast errors to judge whether the

difference is statistically significant. In the literature, different tests on equal

predictive ability exist. One popular test goes back to Diebold and Mariano

(1995) which employs unconditional probability limits of coefficients’ estimates.

This is appropriate to compare the general predictive ability of two models.

However, to test which model performs better conditional on the date of the

forecast t, Giacomini and White (2006) have developed a conditional test of pre-

dictive ability, which uses parameter estimates βt instead. The null hypothesis is

tested using a Wald-type test statistic T . It states that the expected loss func-

tions L of the two compared forecast procedures are equal, where L increases

with the squared forecast error of the considered procedure.15 Following the lit-

erature, the Giacomini-White test should be given priority unless the uncertainty

concerning β does not bias forecast errors. In our analysis, the conditions of such

asymptotic irrelevance (West, 2006) are not fulfilled since coefficients as well as

estimation specifications may vary over time due to an updated rolling window

of in-sample quarters.16 Hence, we apply the Giacomini-White test to compare

our forecast procedures with the benchmark AR model.

4 Results

4.1 The sets of targeted predictors

In this section we briefly discuss the results of the indicator selection exercise.

The sets identified with the hard- and soft-thresholding algorithms can be found

in Tables 1−5. By construction, the soft-thresholding algorithm selects predictor

sets, which are very much balanced over the different groups. However, as the

15For a detailed description of the test and the test statistic see Giacomini and White (2006).16Moreover, using the Giacomini-White test, it allows us to compare the forecast accuracy

of nested and non-nested models.

15

Page 18: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

whole indicator set is itself overrepresented by financial and survey indicators

for reasons of data availability, this unbalanced pattern emerges for some of the

thresholds. In fact, with k = 50 for the soft-thresholding approach, the vast

majority of real- and global-economic indicators are already included, while large

parts of financial and survey data is not.

Considering the hard-threshold approach, the results change. Since this ap-

proach ignores the correlation between indicators, the selected predictor sets are

less balanced: Relatively large weight is given to survey indicators while price

data are not covered at all. However, besides the sets of targeted predictors are

broadly balanced over the groups.

4.2 Forecasting performance

To compare the forecast ability of the 17 different sets of indicators, we conduct

the same forecast exercise for each set, as explained in section 3. The results

of these exercises are summarized by means of relative RMSFEs in tables 6−8,

where the three tables refer to forecasts conducted in the respective three different

forecasting rounds. Each Table is structured in the same way: The rows refer

to the pooling approaches, introduced in section 3.3. The columns refer to the

different sets of targeted predictors that enter the system of bridge equations.

Figures 2−7 provide a graphical analogue of Tables 6−8. Several interesting

patterns turn out.

First, the influence of the pooling approaches on forecast accuracy is much

less pronounced in the first compared to the second and third forecasting round.

This applies to both threshold approaches and is most conspicuous if we compare

the naive pooling approaches to out-of-sample schemes based on past forecasting

performance. Apparently, the more indicator data has to be predicted in first

place, the more biased becomes the assessment of bridge equations’ true forecast-

ing performance. Compared to Figures 2 to 6, the superiority of out-of-sample

schemes is much more pronounced than in Figures 3 to 7.

Second, the targeted predictors chosen by the hard-thresholding algorithm

16

Page 19: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

generate smaller forecast errors if we compare sets with a similar number of

indicators. No matter the forecasting round and the pooling approach, choosing

20 targeted predictors by the soft-thresholding approach, this set performs worse

forecasts than the corresponding set of 20 targeted predictors chosen with the

hard-thresholding method (α = 0.05). This conclusion also stands if we compare

the best performing sets of both algorithms in each forecasting round and with

each pooling approach. We will turn to analyzing the backgrounds of this result

in more detail in the following paragraphs.

Third, the impact of the size of the indicator set shows an interesting pattern,

which emerges very similarly in all forecasting rounds, with all pooling approaches

and for both thresholding algorithms: While forecast accuracy increases with the

number of included predictors up to a certain quantity of around 20 indicators,

adding more indicators beyond this number does not improve the forecast accu-

racy. It even reduces it once the number of indicators becomes too large. This is

most apparent with the trimmed mean (75%) in the third forecasting round for

the soft-thresholding approach.

Forecast accuracy dramatically increases once we move from k = 10 to k = 20

and goes on increasing if we add another 10 indicators. However, taking more

than 30 indicators, the forecast performance gradually worsens. The set of k = 30

indicators includes the vast majority of real economic, global economic and price

indicators. Moving towards k = 132, the representation of financial market and

survey indicators becomes larger and so do forecast errors. As we will show in

the next paragraphs, this kind of overrepresentation leads to increased forecast

errors foremost during and after the Great Recession, 2008q2 − 2009q2.17 In

fact, our results are significant if we leave out the period of the Great Recession.18

17To define the period of the Great Recession we adhere to the Center for Economic andPolicy Research.

18The results of the Giacomini-White test reveal that there is no significant difference betweenthe relative RSMFEs of the pooled forecasts and the benchmark model. However, if we leaveout the Great Recession, our results become significant. This is mainly due to the high forecasterrors during this period.

17

Page 20: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

In what follows, we want to go in more detail what is behind the impact of the

size (and composition) of the set of targeted predictors on forecast accuracy. To

simplify notation we denote by Sk and Hα the respective sets produced with soft-

and hard-thresholding, where the subscripts refer to the chosen thresholds. As a

first step, we identify the best-performing combination of pooling approach and

set of targeted predictors from each forecasting round and for both thresholding

algorithms separately. Throughout, the best pooling approach is given by the

trimmed mean (75%). Moreover, with soft-thresholding, S60, generates the lowest

relative RMSFE in the first forecasting round, while forecast errors are lowest

with S30 in the second and third round. Presumably, it needs less indicators

to cover the information for forecasting GDP as data availability improves over

the forecasting rounds. With hard-thresholding, it is always the same set (H0.05)

which generates the lowest errors in all forecasting rounds.19

Overall, it seems that a critical quantity of indicators is needed to cover the

relevant information for explaining GDP. Meanwhile, there is not much benefit

from adding further indicators. We conjecture that adding ”too” many variables

comes at the risk of increased error variance, and it comes at the risk of biased

forecasts if certain groups of indicators become overrepresented.

Based on the best-performing sets identified above, we want to go in further

detail and identify the quarters of the forecast periods, in which these sets show

their superiority. Again we proceed this analysis separately for each forecasting

round and for both thresholding algorithms, see Figures 8−13. In all six figures,

it is shown the time series of GDP growth as a solid line. Besides, it is shown

three series of forecast errors as bars. One refers to the errors conducted by

the respective best-performing set (blue bars). As benchmarks, the second one

refers to a set which comprises a very small number of indicators (S10 and H0.01

19While we focus on the typical significance levels, α = 0.9, α = 0.95 and α = 0.99 as arobustness check, we also calculated the forecasting errors in steps of 0.01 from α = 0.99 toα = 0.9 and it turned out that the results are very similar to those of the soft-thresholdingapproach. If a certain level of indicators is achieved, the forecasting performance does notimprove anymore.

18

Page 21: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

respectively (black bars)) and the third one refers to the errors conducted with the

full set of indicators (red bars). For comparability reasons, all sets are combined

with the pooling approach trimmed mean (75%).20

Comparing the three sets with regard to their forecast performances in each

figure, a clear pattern emerges. While the differences are not much pronounced in

”calm times” of stable growth, they became apparent during the Great Recession

and the European Debt Crises. Precisely, we can identify the quarters between

2008Q4 − 2009Q2 and between 2011Q3 − 2012Q3 as periods, where the best-

performing sets stand out.

Hence, we pick two characteristic quarters, 2009Q1 and 2012Q3, to illustrate

which bridge equations and thus predictors help to create the superiority of the

best-performing sets. Again we compare them to S10 and H0.01 as well as to

the full set S132 = H1. For simplicity, we only focus on the third forecasting

round (Figure 12 and Figure 13 ), in which forecasts are least affected by missing

indicator data and we apply the trimmed mean (75%) as the pooling approach.

Starting with 2009Q1, where GDP collapsed by −2.9% qoq, all sets produced

too positive pooled forecasts. While the deviation is relatively small with the

respective best sets (0.31 percenatage points (pp) with H0.05 and 0.55 pp with

S30), the small sets S10 and H0.01 produce errors of 0.95 pp and 1.45 pp. Taking

a look inside the indicator sets, the small sets lack most of the financial variables,

which proved to be very important predictors during the Great Recession. Above

that, H0.01 also discards all real economic data, which well explained GDP at that

time, particularly in combination with financial indicators. In addition, the small

set includes only one survey indicator, while the optimal sets takes five survey

indicators into account.

Turning to the full set, the error amounted to 0.96 pp in 2009Q1. While this is

very much the same as the one conducted by H0.01, the background is completely

20In all forecasting rounds and in combination with both thresholding approaches, thetrimmed mean (75%) showed the lowest relative RMSFE. However, we cannot determine anysignificant difference between the trimmed mean (75%) and the other applied threshold ap-proaches.

19

Page 22: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

different. Rather than a lack of variables, it suffers from too many indicators.

Since half of the indicators of the full set are related to survey data, the forecasts

became biased. There is no clear pattern which of the survey indicators works

poorly, but if the share of survey indicators becomes too large, this worsens the

forecasting performance.

Turning to the forecasts for 2012Q3, the explanation is different. The general

deviation is smaller since the decline of GDP was not quite as pronounced as in

2009q1. Nevertheless, the best performing sets (S30 and H0.05) outperformed S10

and H0.01 as well as the full set S132 = H1. This is mainly due to the different

number of survey indicators included in the indicator sets. At least a certain

number of them perform well during the European Debt Crises. This result is

not surprising since the weak economic activity originated from uncertainty in

the Euro area.21

The small sets S10 and H0.01 lack most of the survey indicators. Hence, their

deviation (S10 with −0.53 pp and H0.01 with −0.62 pp) is higher than for the best

performing models (0.06 pp with H0.05 and 0.12 pp with S30). The reason for the

weak forecasting performance of the full sets is mainly the same as for 2009q1.

However, this time too many of the real economic indicators (among others) are

included which perform poorly.

5 Conclusions

Short-term forecasting relies on timely available indicators with a higher fre-

quency than the target variable. In recent times, the availability of indicators

has grown and the question arises if a selection of indicators provides a better

forecasting performance than including all available information. In this paper we

apply two threshold algorithms in combination with various pooling approaches

to analyze if different sizes of indicator sets have an impact on the forecasting

21For example, the Policy Uncertainty Index for the Euro Area shows several peaks in 2012and indicates high uncertainty (Baker et al., 2013).

20

Page 23: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

performance of bridge models to forecast Euro Area GDP. Furthermore, we focus

on the performance of the different sizes of indicator sets during periods of weak

economic activity.

It turns out that a selection of indicators improves the forecasting performance

in comparison to a benchmark model, especially in times of weak economic ac-

tivity. This is true if forecasts for Euro Area GDP are conducted with predicted

values for the respective missings of the indicators. However, the more official

data is published the more important becomes a selection of indicators. More

precisely, the combination of the hard-thresholding algorithm and the trimmed

mean (75%) shows always the lowest relative RMSFE in relation to the benchmark

model. Nevertheless, these results are only statistically significant if the Great

Recession is not included. By highlighting the important role of carefully select-

ing predictors especially in turbulent times of large turning points, we believe to

substantially contribute to the existing literature on short-term forecasting.

21

Page 24: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

References

Alvarez, R., Camacho, M., and Perez-Quiros, G. (2012). Finite sample performance

of small versus large scale dynamic factor models. CEPR Discussion Papers 8867,

C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.

Angelini, E., Mendez, G. C., Giannone, D., Reichlin, L., and Runstler, G. (2011).

Short-term forecasts of euro area GDP growth. Econometrics Journal, 14(1):25–44.

Antipa, P., Barhoumi, K., Brunhes-Lesage, V., and Darne, O. (2012). Nowcasting

German GDP: A comparison of bridge and factor models. Journal of Policy Modeling,

34(6):864–878.

Bai, J. and Ng, S. (2008). Forecasting economic time series using targeted predictors.

Journal of Econometrics, 146(2):304 – 317. Honoring the research contributions of

Charles R. Nelson.

Bair, E., Hastie, T., Paul, D., and Tibshirani, R. (2006). Prediction by supervised

principal components. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 101(473).

Baker, S. R., Bloom, N., and Davis, S. J. (2013). Measuring Economic Policy Uncer-

tainty. Technical Report 13-02, Chicago Booth Research Paper.

Banbura, M. and Runstler, G. (2011). A look into the factor model black box: Pub-

lication lags and the role of hard and soft data in forecasting GDP. International

Journal of Forecasting, 27(2):333–346.

Boivin, J. and Ng, S. (2006). Are more data always better for factor analysis? Journal

of Econometrics, 132(1):169–194.

Bulligan, G., Marcellino, M., and Venditti, F. (2012). Forecasting economic activity

with higher frequency targeted predictors. Temi di discussione (Economic working

papers) 847, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area.

Caggiano, G., Kapetanios, G., and Labhard, V. (2011). Are more data always better

for factor analysis? Results for the euro area, the six largest euro area countries and

the UK. Journal of Forecasting, 30(8):736–752.

22

Page 25: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Clements, M. P. and Galvao, A. B. (2008). Macroeconomic forecasting with mixed-

frequency data: Forecasting output growth in the United States. Journal of Business

& Economic Statistics, 26(4):546–554.

Clements, M. P. and Galvao, A. B. (2009). Forecasting US output growth using leading

indicators: an appraisal using MIDAS models. Journal of Applied Econometrics,

24(7):1187–1206.

Diebold, F. X. and Lopez, J. A. (1996). Forecast Evaluation and Combination. In

Handbool of Statistics, pages 241–268. North-Holland.

Diebold, F. X. and Mariano, R. S. (1995). Comparing Predictive Accuracy. Journal of

Business & Economic Statistics, 13(3):253–63.

Diron, M. (2008). Short-term forecasts of euro area real GDP growth: an assessment of

real-time performance based on vintage data. Journal of Forecasting, 27(5):371–390.

Donoho, D. L. and Johnstone, I. M. (1994). Ideal spatial adaptation by wavelet shrink-

age. Biometrika, 81:425–455.

Drechsel, K. and Maurin, L. (2011). Flow of conjunctural information and forecast of

euro area economic activity. Journal of Forecasting, 30(3):336–354.

Drechsel, K. and Scheufele, R. (2012a). The Financial Crisis from a Forecaster’s Per-

spective. Kredit und Kapital, 5(1):1–28.

Drechsel, K. and Scheufele, R. (2012b). The performance of short-term forecasts of the

German economy before and during the 2008/2009 recession. International Journal

of Forecasting, 28(2):428 – 445.

Ferrara, L., Marsilli, C., and Ortega, J.-P. (2014). Forecasting growth during the

Great Recession: is financial volatility the missing ingredient? Economic Modelling,

36:44–50.

Foroni, C., Marcellino, M., and Schumacher, C. (2015). Unrestricted mixed data sam-

pling (MIDAS): MIDAS regressions with unrestricted lag polynomials. Journal of

the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 178(1):57–82.

23

Page 26: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Giacomini, R. and White, H. (2006). Tests of Conditional Predictive Ability. Econo-

metrica, 74(6):1545–1578.

Giannone, D., Reichlin, L., and Small, D. (2008). Nowcasting: The real-time informa-

tional content of macroeconomic data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(4):665–

676.

Girardi, A., Golinelli, R., and Pappalardo (2014). The Role of Indicator Selection in

Nowcasting Euro Area GDP in Pseudo Real Time. Working Papers wp919, Dipar-

timento Scienze Economiche, Universita’ di Bologna.

Granger, C. W. and Ramanathan, R. (1984). Improved methods of combining fore-

casting. Journal of Forecasting, 3(2):197–204.

Grassmann, P. and Keereman, F. (2001). An indicator-based short-term forecast for

quarterly GDP in the euro area. European Economy - Economic Papers 154, Direc-

torate General Economic and Monetary Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission.

Hahn, E. and Skudelny, F. (2008). Early estimates of euro area real GDP growth: a

bottom up approach from the production side. Working Paper Series 0975, European

Central Bank.

Kitchen, J. and Monaco, R. (2003). Real-Time Forecasting in Practice: The U.S.

Treasury Staff’s Real-Time GDP Forecast System. Business Economics, 38(4):10–

19.

Kuzin, V., Marcellino, M., and Schumacher, C. (2011). MIDAS vs. mixed-frequency

VAR: Nowcasting GDP in the euro area. International Journal of Forecasting,

27(2):529 – 542.

Marcellino, M., Stock, J. H., and Watson, M. W. (2003). Macroeconomic forecasting in

the Euro area: Country specific versus area-wide information. European Economic

Review, 47(1):1–18.

Runstler, G., Barhoumi, K., Benk, S., Cristadoro, R., Reijer, A. D., Jakaitiene, A.,

Jelonek, P., Rua, A., Ruth, K., and Nieuwenhuyze, C. V. (2009). Short-term fore-

24

Page 27: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

casting of GDP using large datasets: a pseudo real-time forecast evaluation exercise.

Journal of Forecasting, 28(7):595–611.

Schumacher, C. (2014). MIDAS and bridge equations. Discussion Papers 26/2014,

Deutsche Bundesbank, Research Centre.

Schumacher, C. and Dreger, C. (2004). Estimating Large-Scale Factor Models for

Economic Activity in Germany: Do They Outperform Simpler Models? Journal

of Economics and Statistics (Jahrbuecher fuer Nationaloekonomie und Statistik),

224(6):731–750.

Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. M. (2003a). How did leading indicator forecasts perform

during the 2001 recession? Economic Quarterly, (Sum):71–90.

Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (2003b). Forecasting Output and Inflation: The Role

of Asset Prices. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(3):788–829.

Stock, J. H. and Watson, M. W. (2004). Combination forecasts of output growth in a

seven-country data set. Journal of Forecasting, 23(6):405–430.

Timmermann, A. (2006). Forecast Combinations, volume 1 of Handbook of Economic

Forecasting, chapter 4, pages 135–196. Elsevier.

West, K. D. (2006). Forecast Evaluation, volume 1 of Handbook of Economic Forecast-

ing, chapter 3, pages 99–134. Elsevier.

25

Page 28: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

A Appendix

A.1 Tables and Graphs

A.2 Selection of targeted predictors

Table 1: Selection of Real Economic indicators

Hard Softthreshold α threshold k

0.01 0.05 0.1 1 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 132

Prod.; Total industry excl. constr.1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Mining & quarrying1 x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Durable consumer goods1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Non-durable consumer goods1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Energy1 x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Capital goods1 x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Intermediate goods1 x x x x x

Prod.; Manufacturing1 x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Electricity, gas, steam etc.1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Prod.; Construction1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Retail sales; Volume1 x x x x x x x x x x x x x

Registrations; New passenger cars;2 x x x x x x x x x

Earnings, per hour1 x x x x x x x x x x x1 = EMU; 2005=100, sa;2 = EMU; 1000;

26

Page 29: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tab

le2:

Selection

ofSurvey

indicators

Hard

Soft

thre

shold

αth

resh

old

k0.01

0.05

0.1

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

EM

UBusiness

confidence;M

anufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

EM

UBusiness

climate

;M

anufactu

ring;2000=100,sa

xx

xEM

UOrd

erbook

levelassessment;

Manufactu

ring;%,sa

xEM

USto

cksassessment(fi

nished

pro

ducts);

Manufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UEmploymentexpecta

tionsforth

emonth

sahead;M

anufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UPro

duction

trend

obse

rved

inre

centmonth

s;M

anufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UExport

ord

erbook

levelassessment;

Manufactu

ring;%,sa

;x

xx

EM

UPro

duction

expecta

tionsforth

emonth

sahead;M

anufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

USellin

gpriceexpecta

tionsforth

emonth

sahead;M

anufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UAss.ofexport

ord

erbook;M

anufactu

reofmachin

ery

and

equip

ment;

%,sa

xx

EM

UAss.ofexport

ord

erbook;M

anufactu

reofmoto

rvehiclesetc

.,%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UAss.oford

erbook;M

anufactu

reofmachin

ery

and

equip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xEM

UAss.oford

erbook;M

anufactu

reofmoto

rvehiclesetc

,%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UAss.oford

erbook;Oth

ermanufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

EM

UAss.ofstocks(fi

n.pro

d.);M

anufactu

reofelectricalequip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UAss.ofstocks(fi

n.pro

d.);M

anufactu

reofmachin

ery

and

equip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UAss.ofstocks(fi

n.pro

d.);M

anufactu

reofmoto

rvehiclesetc

.,%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UAss.oford

erbook;M

anufactu

reofelectricalequip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UAsse.ofexport

ord

erbook;M

anufactu

reofelectricalequip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UIn

d.ConfidenceIn

dicato

r;M

anufactu

reofelectricalequip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xEM

UIn

d.ConfidenceIn

dicato

r;M

anufactu

reofmachin

ery

and

equip

ment;

%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UIn

d.ConfidenceIn

dicato

r;M

anufactu

reofmoto

rvehiclesetc

.,%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

USto

cksassessment(fi

nished

pro

ducts);

Manufactu

ring;%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UBusiness

confidence;Constru

ction

industry

;%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

UActivity

trend

obse

rved;Civil

engin

eering;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UPriceexpecta

tions;

Constru

ction

industry

;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UEmploymentexpecta

tions;

Constru

ction

industry

;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UOrd

erbook

levelassessment;

Constru

ction

industry

;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UActivity

trend;Constru

ction

industry

;%,sa

xx

xx

EM

UBusiness

confidence;Reta

iltrade;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UBusiness

expecta

tionsovernext3

month

s;Reta

iltrade;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UBusiness

activity

(sales)

overpast

3month

s;Reta

iltrade;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UEmploymentexpecta

tionsovernext3

month

s;Reta

iltrade;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UOrd

ering

inte

ntionsovernext3

month

s;Reta

iltrade;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UDemand

developmentoverpast

3month

s;Serv

ices;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UDemand

expecta

tionsovernext3

month

s;Serv

ices;

%x

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UEmploymentexpecta

tionsovernext3

month

s;Serv

ices;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UEmploymentdevelopmentoverpast

3month

s;Serv

ices;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UBusiness

confidence;Serv

ices;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UBusiness

situ

ation

developmentoverpast

3month

s;Serv

ices;

%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UEconomic

sentiment;

Business

secto

r&

consu

mers;sa

xx

xx

xEM

ULeadin

gin

dicato

r(O

ECD);

Amplitu

deadju

sted,long

term

avera

ge=

100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UConsu

merconfidence;%,sa

xEM

UConsu

merclimate

(OECD);

Norm

al=

100,sa

xEM

UConsu

merclimate

;2000=100,sa

xEM

UM

ajorpurchase

splanned,next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UM

ajorpurchase

sinte

nded,currently;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xEM

USavin

gsplanned,next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

EM

USavin

gsinte

nded,currently;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xEM

UUnemploymentexpecta

tions,

next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UFin

ancialsitu

ation,last

12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

EM

UFin

ancialsitu

ation,next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UGenera

leconomic

situ

ation,last

12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xEM

UGenera

leconomic

situ

ation,next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UPricetrend

assessment,

last

12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UPricetrend

expecta

tions,

next12

month

s;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

USta

tementon

financialsitu

ation

ofhouse

hold

;Consu

mers;%,sa

xx

xx

xx

EM

UUnemploymentra

te;Base

don

surv

ey

data

;%

oflaborforc

e,sa

xx

xx

xx

x

27

Page 30: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tab

le3:

Selection

ofPrice

indicators

Hard

Soft

thre

shold

αth

resh

old

k0.01

0.05

0.1

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

EM

UPro

ducerprice;Excl.

energ

y;2005=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UPro

ducerprice;2005=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UConsu

merprice;Harm

onized

toEU

guid

elines;

2005=100,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UConsu

merprice;Energ

y,harm

onized

toEU

guid

elines;

2005=100

xx

xEM

UConsu

merprice;In

dustrialgoods,

harm

onized

toEU

guid

elines;

2005=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UExport

price;2005=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UIm

port

price;2005=100

xx

x

28

Page 31: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tab

le4:

Selection

ofFinan

cial

marketindicators

Hard

Soft

thre

shold

αth

resh

old

k0.01

0.05

0.1

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

EM

UM

SCIsh

are

pricein

dex;Euro

base

d,1996.12.31=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UAssets

ofM

FIs;Loansto

Euro

are

apr.

secto

r;Outsta

ndin

gamount,

bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UAssets

ofM

FIs;Loansto

Euro

are

aNon-M

FIs;Outsta

ndin

gamount,

bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UM

oney

supply

M1;Level,

bn

Euro

,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UM

oney

supply

M2;Level,

bn

Euro

,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UM

oney

supply

M3;Level,

bn

Euro

,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UCre

dit;Loansto

Euro

are

aprivate

secto

r;Level,

bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

ULoans;

To

priv.house

hold

s;Cons.

loans,

fixed

5+

yrs,outst.,bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

ULoans;

To

priv.house

hold

s;Cons.

loans,

fixed

<1

yr,

outst.,bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UYield

;Govern

mentbonds,

matu

rity

10

years;month

lyave.

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UYield

;Govern

mentbonds,

matu

rity

2years;month

lyave.

xEM

UYield

;Govern

mentbonds,

matu

rity

5years;month

lyave.

xx

xx

xEM

USpre

ad;Swapsvs.

Germ

an

govt.

bonds,

mat.

2-3

y.;

Basispts;month

lyave.

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

USpre

ad;Swapsvs.

Germ

an

govt.

bonds,

mat.

4-5

y.;

Basispts;month

lyave.

xx

xEM

USpre

ad;Swapsvs.

Germ

an

govt.

bonds,

mat.

9-1

0y.;

Basispts;month

lyave.

xEM

USpre

ad;Swapsvs.

Germ

an

govt.

bonds,

mat.

1-2

y.;

Basispts;month

lyave.

xx

EM

UExchangera

te;Euro

/US$;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

xx

EM

UExchangera

te;Euro

/£;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

xx

xEM

UExchangera

te;Euro

/100

�;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UExchangera

te;Tra

de-w

eighte

d,nomin

al,

partnercurrencies/

Euro

;2010=100

xx

xx

EM

UIn

terb

ank

rate

,uncollate

ralized

(EURIB

OR);

3month

,offere

dx

EM

UIn

terb

ank

rate

,uncollate

ralized

(EURIB

OR);

1month

,offere

d;month

lyave.

xx

xx

EM

UIn

terb

ank

rate

,uncollate

ralized

(EURIB

OR);

12

month

,offere

d;month

lyave.

xx

EM

USwap

rate

;Euro

,1

yearvs.

6-m

onth

Lib

or;

month

lyave.

xx

EM

USwap

rate

;Euro

,2

years

vs.

6-m

onth

Lib

or;

month

lyave.

xx

xx

xx

EM

USwap

rate

;Euro

,8

years

vs.

6-m

onth

Lib

or;

month

lyave.

xEM

USwap

rate

;Euro

,9

years

vs.

6-m

onth

Lib

or;

month

lyave.

xEM

USwap

rate

;Euro

,10

years

vs.

6-m

onth

Lib

or;

month

lyave.

xEM

UCall

money

rate

,uncollate

ralized

(EONIA

);month

lyave.;

xx

xx

EM

UCitigro

up

bond

perform

ancein

dex;US$

base

d,1998.12.31=100;

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UDJ

Euro

Sto

xx

share

pricein

dex;Euro

base

d,1991.12.31=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UDJ

Euro

Sto

xx

TM

Ish

are

perform

ancein

dex;Euro

base

d,1991.12.31=100;

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UDJ

Euro

Sto

xx

50

(blu

echip

)sh

are

pricesin

d.;

Euro

bs.,1991.12.31=1000

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UDJ

Euro

Sto

xx

pricein

dex;Tota

l;Euro

base

d,1991.12.31=100

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UDJ

Euro

Sto

xx

perform

ancein

dex;Tota

l;Euro

base

d,1991.12.31=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

EM

UiB

oxx

bond

perform

ancein

dex;Corp

ora

tes,

AAA,all

matu

rite

sx

xEM

UiB

oxx

bond

perform

ancein

dex;Corp

ora

tes,

BBB,all

matu

rite

sx

xx

xEM

UiB

oxx

bond

perform

ancein

dex;Corp

ora

tes,

overa

ll,all

matu

rite

sx

xEM

UiB

oxx

bond

perform

ancein

dex;Overa

ll,all

matu

rite

sx

xEM

UCitigro

up

money

mark

etperform

ancein

dex;Euro

base

d,1997.12.31=100

xEM

USto

ck

volu

mecurrently

hold

;Reta

iltrade;Balance,%

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UCentralbank

depositra

te;M

onth

end

xx

xx

EM

U3-m

onth

Euriborfu

ture

;Neare

stexpiration;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

EM

UM

arg

inallendin

gfacility;Volu

meborrowed;Bn

Euro

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xEM

UM

oney

mark

etfu

nds;

Flows,

bn

Euro

xx

xx

xEM

UM

oney

mark

etfu

nds;

12-m

onth

gro

wth

,%

xx

x

29

Page 32: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tab

le5:

Selection

ofGlobal-Econom

icindicators

Hard

Soft

thre

shold

αth

resh

old

k0.01

0.05

0.1

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

World

Commodity

price(H

WW

I);Raw

mate

rials,to

tal;

US$

base

d,2010=100

xx

xx

xx

xW

orld

Commodity

price(H

WW

I);Cru

deoil;US$

base

d,2010=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xW

orld

Commodity

price(H

WW

I);Energ

ypro

ducin

gra

wmat.;US$

base

d,2010=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xW

orld

Commodity

price(H

WW

I);Raw

mate

rials,excl.

energ

y;US$

base

d,2010=100

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xUSA

Pro

duction;Tota

lin

dustry

excl.

constru

ction;2007=100,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xUSA

Yield

;Tre

asu

rybills,matu

rity

3month

s;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

xUSA

Yield

;Tre

asu

rybills,matu

rity

6month

s;M

onth

lyavera

ge

xx

xUSA

Consu

merexpecta

tions(C

onfere

nceBoard

);1985=100,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xGerm

any

Business

expecta

tions(ifo);

Manufactu

ring;Balance,%,sa

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

xx

x

Tab

le6:

RelativeRMSFE-1stmon

th

1st

month

Hard

-thre

shold

α(k

)Soft-thre

shold

kNumberofin

dicato

rs0.01

(4)

0.05

(20)

0.1

(24)

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

Mean

0.629

0.528

0.533

0.639

0.662

0.608

0.593

0.597

0.586

0.565

0.556

0.553

0.546

0.544

0.547

0.549

0.553

Median

0.584

0.540

0.542

0.638

0.653

0.641

0.591

0.592

0.585

0.566

0.560

0.556

0.550

0.550

0.552

0.554

0.557

AIC

weighte

d0.632

0.507

0.517

0.645

0.668

0.588

0.567

0.574

0.564

0.541

0.539

0.539

0.535

0.535

0.538

0.541

0.547

R2

weighte

d0.627

0.525

0.530

0.641

0.656

0.601

0.585

0.590

0.578

0.558

0.551

0.549

0.543

0.541

0.544

0.546

0.550

Trimmed

mean

(75%)

0.604

0.469

0.500

0.731

0.683

0.564

0.542

0.545

0.544

0.521

0.533

0.534

0.535

0.539

0.544

0.550

0.557

Trimmed

mean

(50%)

0.573

0.535

0.508

0.723

0.697

0.584

0.557

0.559

0.539

0.531

0.537

0.537

0.536

0.541

0.544

0.549

0.558

Trimmed

mean

(25%)

0.593

0.555

0.517

0.643

0.652

0.595

0.576

0.576

0.558

0.542

0.539

0.537

0.536

0.539

0.542

0.548

0.556

Discounte

dM

SFE

weighte

d0.620

0.511

0.513

0.645

0.673

0.597

0.577

0.577

0.561

0.540

0.540

0.542

0.537

0.540

0.544

0.548

0.553

All

weighting

schemes

0.608

0.521

0.520

0.663

0.668

0.597

0.573

0.576

0.564

0.545

0.544

0.543

0.540

0.541

0.545

0.548

0.554

Naiveweighting

schemes

0.607

0.534

0.537

0.639

0.657

0.624

0.592

0.594

0.586

0.565

0.558

0.555

0.548

0.547

0.550

0.551

0.555

In-sample

weighting

schemes

0.630

0.516

0.523

0.643

0.662

0.594

0.576

0.582

0.571

0.550

0.545

0.544

0.539

0.538

0.541

0.543

0.549

Out-of-sa

mple

weighting

schemes

0.597

0.517

0.509

0.686

0.676

0.585

0.563

0.564

0.550

0.533

0.537

0.537

0.536

0.540

0.544

0.549

0.556

Tab

le7:

RelativeRMSFE-2n

dmon

th

2nd

month

Hard

-thre

shold

α(k

)Soft-thre

shold

kNumberofin

dicato

rs0.01

(4)

0.05

(20)

0.1

(24)

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

Mean

0.628

0.477

0.486

0.639

0.666

0.569

0.553

0.566

0.560

0.541

0.537

0.536

0.528

0.527

0.532

0.535

0.540

Median

0.578

0.492

0.500

0.638

0.647

0.603

0.560

0.570

0.569

0.555

0.548

0.548

0.538

0.539

0.543

0.544

0.549

AIC

weighte

d0.633

0.446

0.461

0.645

0.670

0.538

0.513

0.532

0.530

0.509

0.513

0.516

0.511

0.512

0.517

0.522

0.529

R2

weighte

d0.627

0.473

0.483

0.641

0.660

0.559

0.542

0.557

0.551

0.532

0.531

0.531

0.524

0.523

0.528

0.531

0.537

Trimmed

mean

(75%)

0.600

0.351

0.372

0.731

0.687

0.481

0.428

0.455

0.475

0.446

0.463

0.475

0.470

0.480

0.489

0.499

0.513

Trimmed

mean

(50%)

0.567

0.473

0.434

0.723

0.689

0.531

0.495

0.514

0.506

0.495

0.506

0.510

0.506

0.513

0.519

0.526

0.536

Trimmed

mean

(25%)

0.596

0.504

0.470

0.643

0.656

0.550

0.521

0.538

0.526

0.513

0.515

0.517

0.514

0.519

0.523

0.530

0.539

Discounte

dM

SFE

weighte

d0.620

0.424

0.426

0.645

0.672

0.520

0.483

0.499

0.499

0.468

0.478

0.486

0.485

0.491

0.497

0.504

0.514

All

weighting

schemes

0.606

0.455

0.454

0.663

0.668

0.544

0.512

0.529

0.527

0.507

0.511

0.515

0.509

0.513

0.518

0.524

0.532

Naiveweighting

schemes

0.603

0.484

0.493

0.639

0.656

0.586

0.557

0.568

0.565

0.548

0.543

0.542

0.533

0.533

0.537

0.540

0.544

In-sample

weighting

schemes

0.630

0.459

0.472

0.643

0.665

0.549

0.527

0.544

0.540

0.520

0.522

0.524

0.517

0.518

0.523

0.526

0.533

Out-of-sa

mple

weighting

schemes

0.596

0.438

0.425

0.686

0.676

0.520

0.482

0.502

0.501

0.481

0.491

0.497

0.494

0.501

0.507

0.515

0.526

30

Page 33: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Tab

le8:

RelativeRMSFE-3rdmon

th

3rd

month

Hard

-thre

shold

α(k

)Soft-thre

shold

kNumberofin

dicato

rs0.01

(4)

0.05

(20)

0.1

(24)

110

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

120

132

Mean

0.628

0.461

0.475

0.639

0.662

0.556

0.542

0.556

0.551

0.534

0.532

0.532

0.523

0.522

0.527

0.530

0.536

Median

0.577

0.475

0.490

0.638

0.639

0.579

0.543

0.560

0.556

0.545

0.542

0.543

0.532

0.534

0.538

0.540

0.545

AIC

weighte

d0.632

0.431

0.452

0.645

0.665

0.529

0.504

0.523

0.522

0.503

0.509

0.512

0.506

0.507

0.513

0.518

0.525

R2

weighte

d0.626

0.456

0.472

0.641

0.655

0.547

0.531

0.547

0.542

0.526

0.525

0.526

0.518

0.518

0.523

0.526

0.533

Trimmed

mean

(75%)

0.600

0.378

0.386

0.731

0.693

0.453

0.409

0.443

0.468

0.443

0.461

0.472

0.463

0.473

0.482

0.493

0.506

Trimmed

mean

(50%)

0.567

0.457

0.430

0.723

0.677

0.525

0.486

0.506

0.502

0.491

0.503

0.507

0.501

0.508

0.514

0.522

0.532

Trimmed

mean

(25%)

0.595

0.485

0.461

0.643

0.647

0.542

0.513

0.530

0.518

0.507

0.511

0.513

0.510

0.514

0.519

0.527

0.536

Discounte

dM

SFE

weighte

d0.619

0.420

0.426

0.645

0.670

0.495

0.461

0.479

0.483

0.456

0.469

0.478

0.477

0.483

0.489

0.497

0.507

All

weighting

schemes

0.606

0.445

0.449

0.663

0.664

0.528

0.499

0.518

0.518

0.501

0.507

0.510

0.504

0.507

0.513

0.519

0.527

Naiveweighting

schemes

0.602

0.468

0.482

0.639

0.650

0.568

0.543

0.558

0.554

0.540

0.537

0.537

0.527

0.528

0.533

0.535

0.540

In-sample

weighting

schemes

0.629

0.444

0.462

0.643

0.660

0.538

0.517

0.535

0.532

0.514

0.517

0.519

0.512

0.512

0.518

0.522

0.529

Out-of-sa

mple

weighting

schemes

0.596

0.435

0.426

0.686

0.672

0.504

0.467

0.489

0.493

0.474

0.486

0.493

0.488

0.495

0.501

0.510

0.520

31

Page 34: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

A.3 Figures

Figure 1: Timing of forecasting exercise and availability of data

32

Page 35: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 2: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Soft-thresholding: 1st month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

1 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 132

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

Figure 3: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Hard-thresholding: 1st month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

4 (0.01) 20 (0.05) 24 (0.1)

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

33

Page 36: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 4: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Soft-thresholding: 2nd month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

1 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 132

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

Figure 5: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Hard-thresholding: 2nd month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

4 (0.01) 20 (0.05) 24 (0.1)

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

34

Page 37: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 6: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Soft-thresholding: 3rd month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

1 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 132

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

Figure 7: Number of indicators and their forecasting performance: Hard-thresholding: 3rd month

0.300

0.400

0.500

0.600

0.700

0.800

4 (0.01) 20 (0.05) 24 (0.1)

Mean

Median

AIC weighted

R2 weighted

Trimmed mean (75%)

Trimmed mean (50%)

Trimmed mean (25%)

Discounted MSFE weighted Number of indivators

rel.

RMSF

E

35

Page 38: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 8: First month (soft-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (10)

tr 75 (60)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

Figure 9: First month (hard-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (0.01)

tr 75 (0.05)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

36

Page 39: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 10: Second month (soft-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

GDP

tr 75 (10)

tr 75 (30)

tr 75 (full)

qoq-

chan

ge in

%

-3.5

-3.0

-2.5

-2.0

-1.5

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (10)

tr 75 (30)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

Figure 11: Second month (hard-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (0.01)

tr 75 (0.05)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

37

Page 40: The Role of Targeted Predictors REPen.rwi-essen.de/media/content/pages/publikationen/ruhr-economic-p… · Ruhr Economic Papers #559 Tobias Kitlinski and Philipp an de Meulen The

Figure 12: Third month (soft-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (10)

tr 75 (30)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

Figure 13: Third month (hard-thresholding)

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

-3.5

-3

-2.5

-2

-1.5

-1

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013

tr 75 (0.01)

tr 75 (0.05)

tr 75 (full)

GDP

Solid line - GDP qoq growth rate (right axis) Bars - Forecast errors of pooled bridge models (left axis)

38