the root causes of growth under capitalism

Upload: workineh-aba

Post on 05-Apr-2018

245 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    1/24

    Cambridge Journal of Economics 2011, 1 of 24doi:10.1093/cje/beq054

    The root cause of economic growth undercapitalism

    Michael Joffe*

    Drawing on historical and other empirical evidence, this paper provides a causalexplanation of a central question: why sustainedper capita growth occurs in capitalisteconomiesi.e. in what way capitalism differs from the market that gives it thisproperty. It describes an endogenous economic logic that is based on theinstitutional characteristics of capitalist firms in the non-financial sector, especiallythe flexibility of the inputs that they can call upon and of the size of the market thatthey can supply. This perspective naturally generates a realistic theoretical accountnot only of the source of economic growth, but also of the evolution of marketstructure, the forces that produce divergence in, for example, profit rates, a startingpoint for explaining price-setting and a language for describing firms economicpower. It draws on previous traditions, especially those based on the works of Marxand Schumpeter, but differs from them in important respects.

    Key words: Growth, Capitalism, Firms, Institutions, Micro-foundationsJEL classifications: O43, P17, N10

    1. Introduction

    The tendency for capitalist economies to grow is one of their most characteristic

    properties. The successful capitalist countries have experienced sustained per capita

    growth for many decades, to an extent unparalleled in previous human history. Take-off

    has occurred successively in country after country over the past 200 years. Such take-off

    was not a one-off event, but rather a step change to an altered mode of operation of the

    economic system, that has persisted ever since. This inexorable growth tendency has been

    maintained across numerous transformations: in institutions (e.g. limited liability), marketstructure and the role of science and technology. It encompasses growth at the

    technological cutting edge as well as catch-up growth in countries that have imported

    technology and (sometimes) institutions.

    Nevertheless, the source of growth is not well understood. The aim of this paper is to

    ask, what is it about capitalism that has this effect?, and to try and answer that question by

    Manuscript received 28 November 2008; final version received 17 December 2010.Address for correspondence: Imperial College, St Marys Campus, Norfolk Place, London W2 1PG,

    UK; email: [email protected]

    * Imperial College London, UK. I would like to thank Hasan Gu rak, Gidon Carmeli, Ben Fine, SteveKeen, Arthur Grimes and especially Geoff Hodgson for commenting on earlier versions of this paper. Theydo not necessarily agree with its content.

    The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society.

    All rights reserved.

    Cambridge Journal of Economics Advance Access published March 22, 2011

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    2/24

    providing a causal analysis in terms of the properties of the capitalist firm in contrast with

    individual traders.1 It deals only with the generality that capitalist economies have this

    specific property; the causes of variations in growth rates between different capitalist

    economies or sectors or over time are beyond the scope of the current paper. At this stage

    only a verbal model is presented, the objective being to discover deep regularities.The term capitalism here is taken to mean an economic system dominated by

    production that employs wage labour, in which the means of production (equipment and

    materials) belong to the employer. There is also a case for including a dominant role for

    financial markets in the definition, because their growth has historically been a key

    precondition for corporate operation and expansion. Private ownership of the means of

    production is another traditional element in the definition, but may not be a necessary

    feature. These issues are discussed below. It is important to note that capitalism is not

    used in an evaluative sense: the analysis would have the same validity whether one favours

    or abhors the capitalist system, and whether one wishes to pursue or to limit growth.

    One problem is the apparent obviousness of at least part of the account presented.

    Probably some of this is widely understood intuitively and not only by economists.

    However, while important aspects can be found in the literature, this intuitive un-

    derstanding has not so far generated a systematic account of the endogenous causal

    processes involved in the way that capitalism operates, which could be described as the

    micro-foundations of growth. Such an explicit description is essential, for example to

    avoid confusion of capitalism with the marketone is dynamic, the other self-

    regulatingas well as to tease out which particular components of the capitalist system

    are responsible for its dynamism. Moreover, it allows the explication of the main stages of

    capitalist growth. As will become clear, there are several advantages in describing this

    apparently obvious process explicitly.

    1.1 The market or capitalism?

    The modern economy is conventionally portrayed as a market economya system of

    trading relations between individuals. Adam Smith provided the classic description in the

    Wealth of Nations (Smith, 1776), in which he emphasised the crucial importance of the

    extent of the division of labour. The structure of his argument was that under certain

    institutional conditionssummarised as a system of natural libertythe economic

    system would generate both stability and growth.

    The stability was due to the price mechanism bringing supply and demand into balance,

    as if by a hidden hand. Thus, the apparently anarchic behaviour of individuals had the

    emergent property of self-regulation at the aggregate level of the market, creating an entitythat has the features of a system with endogenous causal processes, what we would now call

    a balancing or negative feedback mechanism (Lowe, 1977), even though it is not formally

    organised as one.2

    1 The term firm is henceforth used to indicate the specifically capitalist firm, characterised by theemployment relationship (Hodgson, 1999, especially pp. 22046: The Coasean tangle: the nature of the firmand the problem of historical specificity). It also can convey a sense of agency, denoting the person/people incharge, who take/s the initiative. This is in contrast to the type of firm that consists of only one person, or justfamily labour, or an equivalent, which is variously described as sole trader, sole producer or pettyproducer depending on the context.

    2 This accords with modern system concepts: systems containing feedback loops generate their own

    endogenous causal processes that make them less sensitive to initial conditions. These intra-systemicprocesses can be modelled (Lowe, 1977); in addition, exogenous causal processes such as shocks anddisturbances can also exist (Forrester, 1970; Lane, 2007).

    2 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    3/24

    According to Smiths verbal model, growth resulted from a cyclicalor rather,

    spiralseries of causal processes. These formed a reinforcing (or positive) feedback loop,

    operating through a progressive increase in the division of labour, generating endogenous

    but slow growth (Lowe, 1977). The assumptions required for this model are specific to

    small-scale production (Lowe, 1977), and in particular require economic power to bewidely dispersed (Harcourt, 1994).

    The only exogenous variable in Smiths model of stability and growth is preferences,

    with other psychological assumptions of a broad nature also being necessary to drive the

    system, such as the propensity to truck and barter (Lowe, 1977). This latter Smith

    regarded as universalwhich fits with the ancient origin of trade and its widespread spatial

    distribution, and distinguishes the system he described from a capitalist one, which barely

    existed in 1776.

    There were two other major consequences: first, there would be gains from trade as

    a result of a greater variety of goods and services. Second, by enlarging the division of

    labour, over time trade would lead to specialisation and specialisation in turn leads to

    greater dexterity, time saving and invention [as was already recognised by Plato,

    Xenophon, de Mandeville and Hume, among others (Peaucelle, 2006)].

    By contrast, in a capitalist society the division of labour takes two forms: between traders

    (a market), and within a firm (an authority structure). Although the Wealth of Nations starts

    with a classic description of a pin factory, based on earlier French sources ( Peaucelle,

    2006), the explanatory passages focus on traders who are sole producers and neglect firms.

    Smith has the excuse that such individuals were still dominant in his time, factories being

    rarethey only became commonplace decades later when industrial capitalism took off.

    Factories, and firms more generally, quickly established themselves in England and

    subsequently in many other parts of the world. Gradually they became ever more dominant

    players in the economy. And it was firms that transformed both the economy and widersociety.

    What is remarkable is that an explanatory tradition focussing on trade still dominates

    mainstream economics, especially the neoclassical tradition, more than 200 years later.

    The textbook theory of the firm is blind to its scale and its internal structure, treating large

    corporations that hire and fire workers in the same way as it treats sole traders.

    Thus, the lack of sufficient acknowledgement of historical specificity in Smiths work has

    been continued in most of the later traditions, but without his excuse. This is particularly

    surprising as J. S. Mill already described cheapeningthe novel feature of continuous

    reduction in the real costs of inputsin 1848 (Mill, 1848), albeit without explaining it.

    And soon afterwards, Karl Marx took the historical specificity of capitalism as central,recognising that this mode of production develops the forces of production like no other

    (Marx, 1867). Something had changed dramatically: in place of an economic system

    dominated by the distribution of existing resources, for example the switching of crops or

    the mining of less accessible seams as described in neoclassical theory, new structures

    emerged that transformed how resources were used. Scarcityin Robbins sense of limited

    supply, not merely a budget constraintwas replaced by abundance in sector after sector

    as capitalism developed. In the early and mid twentieth-century, Joseph Schumpeter

    provided a vivid description of the dynamism and turbulence of the capitalist system

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 3 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    4/24

    (Schumpeter, 1911/1934, 1942). However, neither Marx3 nor Schumpeter4 provided

    a causal account explaining why capitalism is uniquely dynamic, although it takes a close

    reading of their works to realise this.

    Also relevant is a contribution by Ronald Coase, who in 1937 asked the question, if

    market trading between individuals generates the most efficient and generally optimaloutcomes, why do firms exist (Coase, 1937)? This paper has stimulated a fruitful tradition

    of research, based on the importance of transaction costs, seeking to explain why firms have

    the boundaries that they have (e.g. the extent of vertical integration or disintegrationthe

    make-or-buy decision). However, its success in this has proved to be patchy (Poppo and

    Zenger, 1998; David and Han, 2004; Carter and Hodgson, 2006), and the transaction cost

    approach faces special challenges in explaining innovation and the entrepreneurial firm

    (Hodgson and Gindis, 2007).5 More important, the deeper question about why firms exist

    at all still remains unanswered, and is largely ignored by mainstream economics.

    Moreover, the concept of the firm is rather unclear in the large literature devoted to its

    study. For example, in much of the orthodox literature the firm is treated merely as

    a production function. Others define it as a nexus of contracts ( Bainbridge, 2002), or as

    a collection of assets without examining its internal structure (Grossman and Hart, 1986).

    These limited viewpoints are effectively criticised by Hodgson (2002), who emphasises the

    importance of the legal foundation of the firm. Gindis (2009) builds on this, demonstrating

    that the firm is a real not a fictional entity, citing the earlier tradition of real (or natural)

    entity theory. This recognised that capitalist firms possess emergent properties of collective

    knowledge and capabilities, and that these have consequences, in particular that the firm

    has causal powers and is a unit of selection. This perspective accords with the classic

    organisational analyses that explored relationships within the firm (Berle and Means, 1932;

    Penrose, 1959).

    Micklethwait and Wooldridge (2003) present a short history of the firm, describing it asa revolutionary idea that gave birth to the industrial revolution. They trace the institutional

    innovations that gave rise to the existence of economic entities with their own legal

    personhood, a necessary condition for the emergence of specifically capitalist firms (see

    section 3.2 on the key properties of firms). However, their emphasis on the joint-stock

    3 Marx included an analysis of productivity growth in his verbal description of capitalism in chapter 12 ofVolume I of Capital (Marx, 1867 pp. 42938), but it was dropped when he came to introduce his formalmodel in chapter 17. There are, of course, numerous possible readings of Marx, but any of them has torecognise that his formal economic model excluded productivity growth, a fact first noted by Engels in thenineteenth century (p. 655, footnote).

    4

    Schumpeters writings on creative destruction and capitalist dynamism are unclear on the causalmechanism (Schumpeter, 1911/1934, 1942; Joffe, 2010). Two views can be discerned: the entrepreneur asagent of change is the better developed, and has been deservedly highly influential. However, it does notaddress the specificity of capitalist dynamism: if the existence of entrepreneurs is to be an explanation forcapitalistdynamism, why does this particular type of economic system generate entrepreneurs? And second,why should they innovate in such a way that one result is growth? Or did they occur equally frequently in, forexample, Imperial China? And, if so, why was that civilisation characterised by technical inventiveness butpatchy per capita growth? Schumpeters systemic view stresses how capitalism creates the tendency to think incertain ways, e.g. to generate innovations, but is poorly developed in his writings, and no mechanism issuggested (Joffe, 2010). In addition, Schumpeter himself denied the specificity of creative destruction tocapitalism, devoting 14 pages to equivalent processes occurring under a simple exchange economy, anisolated manorial estate, and an isolated communist society (Schumpeter, 1942).

    5 Oliver Williamson, the foremost contributor to operationalisation of transaction cost economics(Hodgson, in Hodgson and Gindis, 2007), states that: Innovation poses special challenges. Transaction

    cost economics can speak to some of these but it does not have a well-rounded explanation. And again:Entrepreneurial firms are a special challenge. In terms of theoretical analysis, another generation ofeconomists is going to have to come up with the answers.

    4 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    5/24

  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    6/24

    explaining the industrial revolution and cutting-edge growth more broadly (Mokyr, 2002;

    Lipsey et al., 2003). However, it fails on grounds both of specificity and of generality. It

    lacks specificity because technical change can occur without capitalist growth, as in

    medieval Europe and especially in Imperial China. More important, it lacks generality: in

    most economies that have undergone capitalist transformation, technical innovation wasabsent, at least in the early stages, with technology being imported.6 A complementary

    account of the institutional context is required, that promotes either technological

    innovation or the effective assimilation of imported technology (Nelson and Pack,

    1999)and in a way that promotes growth. Furthermore, even in innovatory societies

    like the USA, the growth-promoting changes in production have not necessarily been

    technological in the usual sense (see next section).

    The evidence shows that under certain institutional conditions, the endogenous workings

    of the economic system generate self-sustaining growth. Section 2 considers evidence

    relevant to this question, Section 3 proposes an account of how the institution of the

    capitalist firm can generate continuing growth in the light of this evidence, and Section 4

    situates this account within a wider context.

    2. The historical evidence

    2.1 Spatial and temporal distribution of g rowth take-off

    In England, per capita growth shows a structural break at around the time of the Industrial

    Revolution. The economy started expanding rapidly around 1800, if judged by the hourly

    wage of building workers (Clark, 2005), or 1820 (Maddison, 2007). This tendency to grow

    has been sustained ever since in England, albeit with fluctuations. Growth diffused

    throughout the economy, creating and then continuously transforming mass markets in

    basic necessities such as food and clothing. Subsequently, linkages were established assector after sector became involved.

    US growth has followed a similar pattern, and has been close to exponential over

    a similar period. The countries of Continental Europe and then various other parts of the

    world have followed suit at different times. The continuous per capita growth of a set of

    leading countries, a set that has gradually expanded, contrasts with other countries that

    have either variable growth rates or zero growth, and this has resulted in massive

    divergence (Pritchett, 1997, 2003). This change, in one country after another, has been

    described as a hockey stick: the horizontal handle represents zero or slow growth, while

    the upward-sloping blade represents the relentless growth of unprecedented magnitude

    characteristic of capitalism (McCloskey, 2010).Any theory aiming to explain this series of transformations needs to account for

    the change being persistent once it has begun, and generalisable across sectors and

    6 The same arguments apply to authors whose primary purpose is not to explain growth but to explore itscharacteristics. A prime example is Pasinetti (1981), whose model of structural change is based on theassumption that growth is based on technical change plus learning. His primarily macro approach, witha major role given to responsive changes in consumption, is complementary to the bottom-up focus of thepresent paper. He has a similar view of the role of institutions in structuring economic behaviour ( Pasinetti,1981, 2007), but does not consider the specificity of capitalist growth. Ed Nells (1996) model oftransformational change also starts from a technological shift, from Craft Economy to Mass Production,stressing the multiplier effect resulting from the need to invest in order to capture economies of scale. His viewis that Smiths invisible hand no longer provides stability as it did in the Craft Economy (despite stressing

    that disorderly markets are in fact relatively rare in the modern USA), thus generating cycles. This contrastswith the view set out here, that the market mechanism does operate, but has been joined by powerfuladditional forces.

    6 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    7/24

    internationally, as well as across the many varieties of capitalismor at least its

    successful examples. It must also be compatible with the first industrial revolution

    having occurred when and where it did. If attributed to exogenous technological shocks,

    these would need to have been sufficiently constant in frequency and intensity to

    generate close-to-exponential growth.An institutional explanation is a likely candidate. In particular, this tendency to

    inexorable growth has coincided with the growth and success of capitalist firms. Research

    is needed to explain why firms having the properties described in this paper emerged in

    those particular places and times, including, for example, the role of the state, and to trace

    the causal pathways that led from their establishment to the degree of subsequent growth

    experienced.

    Economic growth in non-capitalist societies has different characteristics. A

    growth spurt in England had begun earlier, in about 1640, and ended around

    1740, but population growth almost kept pace with it (Clark, 2005). Similar periods

    of growth were not uncommon in the millennium before the Industrial Revolution,

    notable examples being in China, Japan and the Netherlands, which also proved

    transient (Kelly, 1997; de Vries and van der Woude, 1997; Landes, 1998; Pomeranz,

    2000). Economic historians sometimes refer to these as examples of Smithian growth,

    as distinct from modern self-sustaining growth (Kelly, 1997), and their characteristics

    fit quite well with the slow growth process of Smiths account referred to above

    (Smith, 1776; Lowe, 1977).

    Extreme international inequalities in prosperity have developed in the past two

    centuries, some parts of the world having unprecedented riches, and others being stuck

    in severe poverty. These sharp contrasts could have resulted from the operation of

    capitalism, which is known to generate inequalities, or alternatively from the lack of

    capitalism, or at least of successful capitalism, in the laggard areas. The most cautiousposition is that it could be some of each. Deciding the relative merits of these viewpoints is

    an empirical not an ideological matter, and a satisfactory answer is crucially important if

    global poverty and inequality are to be addressed.

    Why might capitalism not be established successfully? One reason is that state policy

    forbids it, as in the USSR and in pre-reforms China, or at least did not facilitate it as in much

    of post-colonial Africa where African Socialism was attempted. Another is that the

    conditions for success are not met. Given that the success of capitalism is coterminous with

    the success of its constituent firms, this would mean the lack of widespread firms that are able

    to thrive, for example due to lack of access to a market of sufficient size and buying power

    and/or to lack of human and physical capital. Thus, any theory must not only recognise thespecific dynamic properties of successful capitalism, but must also allow for additional

    conditions that are necessary for sustained growth to occur, and in particular to explain the

    paucity of thriving firms and the slow growth in areas that remain poor (see below).

    2.2 Historical changes in productivity and prices

    Such descriptive spatial and temporal data do not give much indication of the

    underlying processes, and for this more detailed historical evidence needs to be

    examined. One example is a study of the American Northeast in the period 1820

    1860 (Sokoloff, 1986). This looked at changes in productivity and prices in the

    following sectors: boots/shoes, coaches/harnesses, cotton textiles, furniture/woodwork,glass, hats, iron, liquors, flour/grist mills, paper, tanning, tobacco and wool textiles.

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 7 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    8/24

    Within each sector, major product innovation was not involvedthe main new

    product at the time would have been the railroadso this is a suitable design for

    investigating the dynamics within existing product sectors. In addition, none of these

    sectors was dominated by a technological breakthrough or other major process

    innovation; rather they were subject to incremental change. This comprehensivewithin-sector focus, the absence of major product or process innovation and the rich

    data available, make this an ideal case study.

    The main finding was that sector-specific labour productivity more than doubled in all

    but one of the sectors during this 40-year period when value added is taken as the measure

    of output, and grew even faster if gross output is taken instead. Real wages also rose, and

    total factor productivity grew almost as fast as labour productivity. Relative to the quantity

    of raw materials processed, labour and capital inputs both fell, especially labour; the idea

    that capital substituted for labour was not supported by the data. When high and low

    capital- or machinery-intensity sectors were examined separately, larger changes were

    found in the more intensive ones, but the differences were small (Sokoloff, 1986).

    Increased productivity was due to a combination of:

    introduction and diffusion of machinery;

    increase in capital intensity (improvements not reflected in the price of capital);

    changes in work organisation;

    realisation of scale economies;

    learning by doing;

    impact of expanding markets (loss of inefficient producers and stimulation of technical

    innovation).

    It is noteworthy that such refinements as limited liability were not important features of

    these sectors during this period.It was also found that in most of the sectors, the price index fell by approximately 40%.

    Taking all the evidence together, the concept of reducing real costs describes the process

    extremely well, in that the input resources and the price index both fell. A caveat is that

    intensification of labour could have contributed to these changes, and that does not fall

    within cost reduction.

    A much more recent source of evidence is from the development of the retail sector in

    developed economies. Wal-Mart in particular has been subject to detailed research.

    Findings include the observation that Wal-Mart prices are typically 5%48% less than

    prices for the same product in supermarkets and other conventional retail outlets

    (Hausman and Liebtag, 2005). Also, a Wal-Mart store opening reduces county-levelretail employment . . . each Wal-Mart worker replaces approximately 1.4 retail workers . . .

    (Neumark et al., 2007). It would be possible to discuss these findings in terms of welfare

    balance, that the former is good and the latter is bad, but if the purpose is to understand the

    causal processes (positive economics) the conclusion must be that a decrease in labour

    costs and in price both reflect a tendency for the same service to be provided with lower

    inputs.

    An objection to this perspective could come from the observation that modern

    corporations in the developed world rarely compete on the basis of priceor less

    superficially, of costs. This is true, and reflects the historical process that has shifted

    cost-cutting competition in internationally tradable items to lower cost countries such as

    China. This leaves cost-based competition in such non-moveable sectors as retail andairlines. A second possible objection, specifically to the notion of the reduction of costs,

    8 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    9/24

    could be that inflation has been a more prominent feature of modern economies, but this

    would be to confuse money prices with real resource inputs.

    3. An institutional explanation of capitalist dynamism

    Why has the emergence of the firm as an institutional form led to the observed continual

    reduction of real resource inputs to produce a given unit of output? Why has it also led

    to an unprecedented profusion of new products? And how are these two processes

    related?

    The answer to the first of these questions at least is to be found in the nature of

    the competitive relationship between the heterogeneous firms that constitute

    a sector of capitalist production. There are two necessary conditions. First, firms

    have a stable existence beyond the individuals who constitute it at any given

    moment, enabling all stakeholders to have good grounds to trust in its future

    continuation. Secondly, firms have two key types of flexibility, in the size of the

    market that they can supply and in the combination of inputs they can bring

    together. Stable existence allows agglomeration of capital, and flexibility allows

    manipulation of the scale of production and of costs, which in turn imply control

    over the productive methods. They also facilitate control over the product, and

    therefore the introduction of new and/or better products.

    3.1 The process of competitionthe relationship between firms

    When firms enhance their competitiveness by reducing costs, they not only enlarge their

    own existing markets but also partially or completely take over the markets of other

    producers, whether these be sole traders or other firms. The same occurs with theintroduction of a successful new product, if it replaces a previous type of product produced

    by a competitor. Outside the capitalist system this happens to only a minimal extent: in

    a sector of petty producers who supply a particular level of effective demand, if one of them

    manages, for example, to improve his onion crop or to become a superior shoe repairer, he

    will prosper but is unlikely to displace the others and take over their markets. This is

    because his output capacity is limited by the extent to which he can expand his inputs;

    a sole trader is limited in a way that a capitalist-type firm is not.

    Capitalism is thus a power struggle between competing firms. Central to its operation is

    conquest by economic means, in which the weak are vanquished. One firm can replace

    many of its competitors as it grows in size to become the corporate equivalent of an

    empire.7

    7 This process does not require increasing returns: the extension of scale can in principle occur withconstant returns. In practice, however, a large proportion of the examples of capitalist growth do involveeconomies of scale, accentuating the growth in firm size. In addition, increasing market size (buying power)facilitates a greater division of labour (specialisation) between firms, promoting cost-reducing investment thatwould otherwise not be justified. This generates increasing returns, even without intra-firm economies ofscalelarge rather than large-scale production (Young, 1928). At the whole-economy level, aggregateproduction volume determines the size of the market, introducing the possibility of cumulative causation(Young, 1928). This would accentuate the process described here, but to produce self-sustaining growth itwould require an additional element; the suggestion that elasticity could generate a chain reaction ( Young,1928) is insufficient to do this in the absence of a rise of total income, which requires induced investment to

    reduce costs (Kaldor, 1972). Furthermore, the suggestion that an increase in the volume of production canincrease productivity (Verdoorns Law) has received empirical support (Harris and Lau, 1998), and thiswould also impart an additional impetus to the process described in this paper.

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 9 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    10/24

    More precisely, it is a struggle between firms of different relative strength, as the power

    relationship can exist with no direct contact, for example a firm in Uruguay, Italy or

    Zambia can go out of business simply as a result of cheaper Chinese imports. The system is

    driven not only by the stick of possible extinction, but also by the carrot of possible success,

    the fate of a firm being determined by its long-term profitability. It is universally agreed thatthe incentive to make a profit is critical to the future health of the firm, so much so that it is

    better described as its central imperative.

    It is one thing to have incentives, but the ability to respond successfully is also necessary.

    The crucial questions then are, what are the sources of a firms strength, and what are the

    consequences of differential strength of firms? Heterogeneity is central here: differences

    between firms are inputs to and outputs ofcompetition; for empirical investigation of this, see

    Haltiwanger (2000), Bartelsman et al. (2004) and Foster et al. (2008).

    Firms bring different qualities to the process of competition. Where competition is

    primarily through inputs and production method, the source of strength is the ability to

    achieve lower costs than competitors. Unlike many power-based interpretations (Wil-

    liamson, 2000), this one is non-tautological. A different source of strength is the ability to

    produce a superior new product or a quality improvement that finds favour in the market.

    This ranges from major product innovations such as sewing machines or mobile phones to

    minor features that have product differentiation as their main aim, achieved by

    a combination of branding and marketing (Chamberlin, 1933).

    In turn the outcome of this process affects market structure. As has been widely

    recognised, especially by evolutionary economists (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Dopfer,

    2005), firms vary in the extent of their profit, resulting over time in the disappearance of

    some firms and differential success among the survivors (Cabral and Mata, 2003;

    Bartelsman et al. (2004).

    High profitability increases the firms ability to invest and to attract high quality staff,altering its inputs so as to extend its market. The most successful firms in making a profit

    have a corresponding advantage in the next round of competition, so that capital

    accumulation is both a result and a cause of the firms growth in economic strengtha

    positive feedback loop operating over time. Taking both these ends of the spectrum of

    profitability, it means that if a market starts out as perfectly competitive, the operation of

    competition systematically erodes its perfection.8

    The process depends on the intensity of competition, i.e. the extent to which a firms

    profit margins are threatened by the actions of its competitors. This can occur in a sector

    with many or few firms, or even with only one but where new entry is possible. The

    intensity can vary, for example, in the data from the American Northeast referred to earlier,many of the changes (at least in the later stages) may have been driven by the increased

    effectiveness of competition brought about by the proliferating railroads.

    Intensity of competition should not be confused with perfect competition in the sense

    of multiple small firms, all of which are price-takers. Capitalist growth has occurred both

    with this scenario and in oligopolistic settings, and large innovative leaps can occur in

    sectors with relatively few large firms (Chandler, 1992) or in sectors with many

    independent start-ups as in the recent growth of web-based businesses.

    8 This is not a new observation: the process of concentration was known to Marx and Veblen, amongothers.

    10 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    11/24

    3.2 The key properties of firms: continuity and flexibility

    Firms can compete successfully if they not only continue to exist in the long-term, but also

    are able to build lasting organisations with the ability to commit capital for extended

    periods of time, allowing large-scale investments and the development of specialised

    knowledge, relationships, reputation, etc. A necessary condition is that organisations are

    allowed to have a continuing existence, independent of their members. The state, as it

    developed in medieval western Europeunlike, for example, in the Islamic world ( Kuran,

    2004)allowed and even fostered independent organisations with corporate legal status.

    These took many forms, including cities, religious orders and universities. Eventually, this

    corporate tradition led to the development of the capitalist firm, with its distinctive

    economic attributes.

    Long-term investment depends on the firms ability to provide a form of inheritance that

    transcends individuals and families. This has been facilitated by development of legal

    frameworks giving firms the status of a singular legal person that could trade as an entity in

    its own right, the main practical purpose being entity protection (Blair, 2003; Hansmannet al., 2006). As a result, they are largely protected from sequestration by others, including

    the state and those who might sue, and are also protected from their own share-

    holdersthe mirror image of limited liability, the protection of participating individuals

    from the debts of the firm, which has traditionally received more attention but which may

    have played a less important role (Blair, 2003; Hansmann et al., 2006).

    Entity protection has also allowed the separation of governance from the contribution of

    financial capital (Blair, 2003), typically putting a small designated group of directors in

    charge, and the combination of this with entity status has facilitated what Chandler has

    called organizational capabilities (Chandler, 1992). Company law has altered greatly as

    capitalism has developed, the changes tending to have been driven not primarily by legalinnovation but rather in response to the requirements of business people, industrial

    capitalists in the case of entity protection (Blair, 2003; Hansmann et al., 2006) and

    subsequently rentiers in the case of limited liability (Ireland, 2010).

    The corporate form in its many varieties together with free labour, i.e. workers who have

    been dispossessed or freed from their own means of production, make the employment

    relation a dominant characteristic of capitalism. This allows the capitalist firm to exist in

    protean manifestations: together with the firms ability to agglomerate a large quantity of

    capital, the source of its material strength, some firms grow to enormous size, whereas others

    are tiny. This flexibility in size is what enables imperial firms to replace large numbers of their

    competitors, as with a chain-store and local retail outlets, contrasting sharply with non-

    capitalist systems. It resembles the military conquest of an area farmed by smallholdingsfollowed by the establishment of latifundia, except that the conquest is achieved by economic

    means, and understanding how this works is key to any explanation of capitalist dynamism.

    Firms are able to do this because of another aspect of flexibility: what resources they use,

    how they use them, and what they are used for. A firm can alter its inputs, notably the

    number and type of workers, wage rates etc., and/or introduce a new production process,

    to try and maintain or enhance its market position by reducing costs. If not limited by, for

    example, legislation and/or trade union power, workers can be hired or sacked with little

    notice, and their wages can be driven down as far as market conditions allow. Alternatively

    a firm can introduce new products more easily than other organisational forms can,

    because of flexibility in opening and closing plants, radically altering the nature of theirworkforce, and so on.

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 11 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    12/24

    These options are not generally available in other ways of organising production. The

    only way that a petty producer, such as a handloom weaver in early nineteenth century

    England, could reduce costs was to pay himself lower wages, and the same is true of

    present-day sole traders such as peasant farmers. Their flexibility in the number of workers

    is typically limited by their family circumstances, and they are similarly limited in theirchoice of production methods. Traders (merchants) whose costs are dominated by the

    merchandise itself are in a similar position of lacking flexibility; they can reduce the costs of

    their goods only if they are able to put pressure on existing suppliers or to source from

    a cheaper one, and they may also be able to reduce other costs such as those of transport,

    for example. In a world of petty production and trade, change is therefore mainly

    incremental. Traders largely take the stock of product as given, with only an indirect

    influence via suppliers willingness to supply. Petty producers are similarly limited by the

    stock of their materials, labour time, skills and production methods.

    In contrast, the scope of a capitalist firm is limited only by the abilities of the people who

    are taking the initiative: their imagination and competencemanagerial capacity (Penrose,

    1959)and their access to resources. These resources include the availability of

    a workforce with particular types of skill and other types of tacit knowledge, as well as

    equipment and other more tangible assets. The ability to buy in the appropriate range of

    labour and equipment is central to capitalist firms success.

    Thus, capitalist firms have direct control over the volume of production, not being limited by

    fixed stocks of product, skills, etc. as petty producers and traders are, as long as they can

    purchase what is needed. The degree of flexibility varies from firm to firm, from sector to sector

    and in different historical times and places (e.g. for institutional reasons). But the unifying

    feature of capitalist production is that across all the dramatic changes that have occurred, for

    example in market structure and in the role of science and technology, it is composed of firms

    that have this characteristic of potential flexibility both in scale and in inputs.These key properties of the firm not only span the different organisational forms that

    have occurred in capitalist societies, but are also compatible with different types of

    ownership. Even the public sector, as with township-village enterprises in China (Qian,

    2003) and state-owned enterprises in Vietnam (Ngu, 2002), can function as capitalist

    firms if they are allowed to do sothis is the main difference from pre-reform

    organisations, and from the factories of the former USSR. Intermediate forms also exist,

    for example cooperatives, which have some similarities to capitalist firms but may be

    expected to have less flexibility and which have been observed to have lower growth rates

    (Gagliardi, 2009).

    It is also sometimes possible for firms to control their supply chains sufficiently tohave the same characteristic of flexibility. This has occurred in retailing, for example, so

    it is not simply a question of direct control over employed labour in a hierarchical

    authority structure (Cox et al., 2002). It may be that the ability of supermarket chains, for

    example, to dominate their suppliers itself originated in their ability to reduce costs,

    thereby enabling them to attain a powerful position in relation both to competitors and

    suppliers.

    3.3 Motivation and consequences at firm level

    The central role of profit in the success of the firm does not imply that profit

    maximisation is necessarily operating as an aim: it is possible that a firm aiming to maximiseprofit could be less successful than one that does not, if the latter firm has other attributes

    12 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    13/24

    that give it an edgethe outcome of competition is a matter of consequences not of

    motivation.

    The distinction between motivation and consequences is important more generally.

    Motivation, the combination of carrot and stick, is central for the individual firm.

    However, to understand the causes of growth we need to focus also on the consequences,both at the level of the firm and at the aggregate levels of the sector and the whole economy.

    A parallel distinction underlies the structure of Adam Smiths argument that differentiates

    the motivation of the trader from its consequence: It is not from the benevolence of the

    butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their

    own interest (Smith, 1776).

    The unintended consequences at the level of the individual firm arise simply from its

    being in business, and are contributions that it makes to the wider economy. Among the

    most important are:

    provision of goods and/or services;

    generation of profit and therefore accumulation of capital;

    employment of workers and payment of wages, thereby providing buying power for

    other companies products.

    Simple aggregation applies here, that the economy-wide consequences are simply

    the sum of the firm-level effectsexcept that in the case of wages, a lower wage bill

    helps to keep costs down, benefiting the individual firm, whereas a higher wage bill

    contributes more buying power to other sectors of the economy, a form of

    externality. But at the aggregate level, unintended consequences give the system

    its distinct properties.

    3.4 How cost reduction worksthe sector level and the wider economy

    Each firm pursues lower unit costs, attempting to maintain and improve its competitive

    position. Other firms in the same sector are similarly engaged, so that profit margins are

    constantly squeezed by the successes of ones competitors. An arms race takes place,9

    aptly described by Lewis Carroll as running as fast as one can in order to stay in the same

    place (the Red Queen effect; Carroll, 1872).

    A firm can use many different types of strategy to try and reduce its unit costs. Taking the

    example of a manufacturing firm (the question of generalisation outside manufacturing

    will be considered later), these include:

    9 In a literal arms race, the military expenditure of one country leads its adversary(ies) to respond byincreasing their own military budget, which in turn generates still more spending in the first country, a cyclethat in principle can continue indefinitely. Any temporary advantage an individual country may enjoy isquickly eroded, but at the aggregate level the overall effect is a build-up of armaments. Arms races can be ofa leaderfollower type, in which one country is always in the lead, or alternatively leap-frogging can occur.The concept of an arms race has been widely applied to other situations, and has been especially successful inevolutionary biology (Dawkins, 2009). In the current context, an arms race means that a companysinvestment threatens the profitability of its competitor(s), leading to a response in kind. The analysis putforward in this paper has been modelled in the System Dynamics software package Vensim, generating thefollowing simulations (Joffe, 2009):d with petty production (no control over costs), introduction of a productivity shock produces a step change

    in costs but no further changes;d

    capitalism (both firms can control costs) leads to an indefinitely continuing fall in costs and prices for bothfirms, which quickly exceeds the initial productivity shock;d with one of each type, the capitalist firm takes market share from the petty producer.

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 13 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    14/24

    use of a technology with higher productivity to produce more units with the same

    resources;

    downward pressure on wages and/or employment levels;

    providing poor working conditions, and cutting corners on health and safety;

    sourcing of lower cost materials; superior organisation;

    mergers and acquisitions with elimination of overlaps;

    running at full capacity and thereby minimising fixed costs.

    Such cost reduction can involve innovation in a technological sense, but this is by no means

    the only method. There are multiple ways, with cost reduction as the final common path.

    For growth, the important consequences are at the level of the sector. Each firms cost-

    cutting is a contribution to a continual reduction in costs in the sector as a wholealthough

    the term contribution should not be seen as implying any more benevolence than in the

    case of the butcher, the brewer or the bakerit is an unintended consequence of how the

    system operates. In this way, a given output requires a constantly falling input of resourcesover successive waves of cost reduction. Just as Smiths hidden hand operates as an

    unintended consequence at the level of the market, the firm is here seen as embodying the

    emergent property that makes capitalism distinct and, specifically, more dynamic than

    other economic systems.

    It should already be clear that there are two ways in which this happens: (i) replacement

    of the less efficient firms and (ii) survivors behavioural response to lower their costs.

    Historically, the greater dynamism of capitalism in each geographical area starts when

    other forms of organisation begin to be replaced by capitalist firms that are able to undercut

    them, as when the English handloom weavers were driven into destitution by the more

    efficient factories in the early nineteenth century.

    The process does not end with lower unit costs. A second effect of competition is to exert

    downward pressure on margins, so that the price also falls. With the same real wage, the

    consumer can now afford to buy more: thus a price fall increases the buying power of

    workers in other sectors, making them richer. In this way, cost-and-price reduction in each

    sector increases the prosperity of the rest of the economy. In other words, it releases buying

    power. Over time, as this process occurs in many sectors, society becomes more

    prosperous, the distribution of prosperity depending on the income distribution. After

    some decades, the economy is transformed into the mass-consumption type of capitalism

    (see Section 4.2 on Staging).

    The trajectory of each sector depends not only on this process of ever-greater efficiency,

    but also on the market. At the new lower price, the quantity demanded increases until themarket becomes saturated; saturation is superseded when the next round of cost reduction

    occurs. In addition, a sector can be affected by exogenous developments in other sectors,

    for example, ones that render its product obsolete.

    At the aggregate level of the whole economy, the most important unintended

    consequences are:

    increased buying power as a result of the previous level of consumption now costing less;

    capital accumulation;

    to the extent that cost-cutting results in higher labour productivity, less labour is

    required for the same output, and despite higher quantities being produced, eventuallyis likely to fall for the sector as a whole.

    14 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    15/24

    It is convenient to think in terms of the release of resources from old sectors over time: the

    generation of extra buying power and capital, and a tendency for labour to be extruded. In

    particular, as industries mature in terms of efficiency, saturation and outdatedness, labour

    is released, and unemployment results if new sectors do not become available to provide

    suitable new employment opportunities.

    3.5 Price-setting and divergence

    The above account treats costs as primary, in that lower unit costs mean a firm has greater

    strength relative to competitors in that product line, giving it the initiative. It then has an

    important decision on how much of the advantage to pass on to consumers, a decision that

    jointly determines price and mark-up. It also strongly influences the consequent change in

    quantity sold, although this depends on other factors as well, such as marketing strategy.

    It would be possible to model the optimal decision in relation to the price elasticity of

    demand for the product, but in the real world the firms future success depends on its

    strategic planning under conditions of radical (Knightian) uncertainty. The best decision

    may in fact be quite different from the static optimum, as is illustrated by the possibility of

    such strategies as predatory pricing and the use of loss leaders. This perspective therefore

    provides a starting point for a causal account of how prices are set by the firm that has the

    initiative, one that requires the dynamic Red Queen context of real competition as

    a process to be considered, not a short-term optimum. It explains why Smiths idea of

    a natural price, around which actual prices fluctuate but to which they always tend to

    return (Smith, 1776), does not apply to capitalist systems; rather, the price level is

    constantly falling in real terms.

    More generally, this approach departs from the neoclassical focus on convergence. In the

    case of profit rates it predicts a divergent force, corresponding to firms heterogeneity in theoutcome of the competitive process, which counteracts their well-known tendency to

    converge as capital flows towards more productive uses. The latter on its own would

    predict tight clustering around zero, the average return on capital, whereas the observed

    distribution is rather widely dispersed (Farjoun and Machover, 1983).

    4. Generalisability

    4.1 Other strategies and their consequences

    The introduction of new products has similar properties to cost reduction, in that theresults differ at the level of the individual firm and in the aggregate. When a firm

    successfully introduces a new product, a new pharmaceutical for example, it has

    a temporary monopoly and consequently earns a good level of profit (Schumpeter,

    1942). This lasts until other firms manage either to imitate the product, which depends on

    the institutional and legal context such as patent law, or to produce something that in turn

    supersedes it. Once the patent expires, we are back in the cost-cutting world, in this case of

    generic drugs.

    Within a particular line of business, therefore, at the aggregate level firms once again find

    themselves in an arms race. The result is a profusion of new productsthis leads to

    expansion in product diversity and, in due course, supersession of obsolete products. A

    similar process operates for products of superior quality, leading to an aggregate-levelquality improvement. For example, automobiles have become more reliable over time, as

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 15 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    16/24

    well as accumulating various features including alarms, central locking, remote locking,

    airbags, satellite navigation systems, etc.10

    However, not all the strategies that firms use in their competitive struggle have growth-

    promoting aggregate effects. Those that primarily involve market share of one firm as

    against the others in the same sector, such as brand loyalty, do not contribute to aggregategrowth. It is the difference between non-zero-sum and zero-sum games. Thus it is

    important not to confuse the range of profit-generating strategies open to firms with the

    range of processes that contribute to growth; the latter is a subset of the former. It is

    a mistake to equate a firms success with a long-term contribution to economic growth.

    4.2 Staging

    Of the two major sources of growth, cost reduction can be regarded as primary because it

    does not require any other process to make it possible. In contrast, new products would be

    difficult to introduce were it not for the release of capital and labour, and especially of

    buying power, that cost reduction makes possible. This may be a major reason why product

    innovation becomes so vibrant as capitalism takes hold. The relationship between the two

    types of process is analogous to the way that non-agricultural occupations were able to

    increase during the Middle Ages, because increasing agricultural productivity meant that

    not everyone was needed to produce food and fibre.

    This analysis suggests an important distinction between the mode of operation of early

    (or low-income) capitalism and late (or high-income) capitalism (Solow, 2006). For

    countries that have not yet embarked on self-sustaining growth, the former is more relevant

    as it is the usual source of catch-up growth. In this early version, costs dominate: it is the

    relationship of productivity to costs that provides the opportunity to embark on growth. At

    this initial stage, downward pressure on costs greatly restricts wages in capitalistenterprises, so that workers incomes do not rise; regimes tend to be authoritarian,

    maintaining order. (The converse is not necessarily true: only a sub-set of low-wage and

    authoritarian societies manage to have a high productivity to cost ratio, and thus

    a competitive advantage that leads to convergence with the already-developed world.)

    Then later in the process of growth, this advantage is gradually eroded by rising per capita

    income.

    Growth typically starts with the appearance of capitalist firms in a small number of

    sectors, sometimes in only one. Firms cost advantage quickly leads to their dominating the

    sector(s). As real input costs and prices fall in each capitalist sector, the release of buying

    power in other sectors provides an economic linkage between sectors. It may be that the

    difference between economies with self-sustaining growth and those with transient growth

    accelerations (Hausmann et al., 2004) is such that a critical mass is reached. However, this

    effect of buying power only operates in the presence of capitalist production, as is

    illustrated by its failure to happen in seventeenth century Netherlands, despite an

    embarrassment of riches (Schama, 1987).

    We have already examined the evidence of how this process operated in the USA

    (without the authoritarian regime in that instance) in 182060. More recent examples

    include the East Asian tigers starting in the 1960s, and subsequently other parts of eastern

    10 In addition, as a corollary of the abundance generated by capitalist production, the limiting factor

    becomes ability to find markets for the product. This can lead to the creation of products with an artificiallylow life-span, e.g. by fashion, built-in obsolescence, etc. This could be seen as reducing quality, therebyintroducing a countervailing force.

    16 of 24 M. Joffe

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/
  • 8/2/2019 The Root Causes of Growth Under Capitalism

    17/24

    and southern Asia. Their catch-up growth has some important characteristics: usually they

    started after the introduction of policy measures that were pragmatic, outward-looking and

    included a major strategic role for the state. It is clearly an important research task to

    understand which features of such measures have been effective. They were seldom

    introduced using textbook economicsindeed the wrong relative prices were deliberatelyinduced in South Korea (Amsden, 1989). And textbooks have learnt little from their

    dramatic successes, although there have been attempts to interpret the evidence from the

    viewpoint of neoclassical economics (Rodrik, 2007).

    The export orientation of these countries means that they could establish and

    maintain very high growth rates: effectively they have been able to import the buying

    power of the rich world. In addition, they imported technology from more advanced

    economies. This was fully paid for, so that improvements not reflected in the price of

    capital (Sokoloff, 1986) were not prominent. The implication is that technological

    progress occurred without a rise in total factor productivity (Lipsey and Carlaw, 2004).

    This could explain the observation that global economic growth in recent decades has

    mainly occurred in two clusters: one with physical capital growth in certain regions, and the

    other with total factor productivity growth plus an interaction of initial human capital with

    physical capital growth (Durlauf et al., 2008). The latter would appear to describe the

    already-developed world, whereas East Asian catch-up growth has been characterised by

    rapid capital accumulation, plus growth in the quantity and quality of labour input,

    without an increase in total factor productivity (Young, 1995; Felipe and McCombie,

    2003).

    High-income capitalism, on the other hand, is innovation-based and occurs where

    human capital is high. Investment is characterised by innovative methods of productive

    technique and/or organisation, and new or higher-quality products are commonplace. In

    the societies where it happens, several features have already become established, most ofthem being consequences of earlier capitalist growth. They include a tendency to oligopoly,

    highly developed science and technology and economies of scale (Penrose, 1959; Baumol,

    2002; Reinert, 2007), together with the small-family, high-human capital pattern that

    emerges following the demographic transition (Galor, 2005). Each imparts an additional

    impetus to capitalist growth, a positive feedback loop, which has led some observers to

    attribute capitalist dynamism to one of these features.

    4.3 Generalisability outside manufacturing

    The above description is based on manufacturing, but may well be more general, invitingthe question, what other sectors have similar properties?. The historical record shows that

    agriculture has followed a path similar to industry, at least in rich societies. The

    development of retailing makes it clear that a similar dynamic must be operating in this

    sector too. The example of Wal-Mart has already been referred to, and in earlier times

    similar processes led to the rise of chain stores and supermarkets in America, Europe and

    elsewhere. Such developments are continuing, with the rise of internet-based sales

    companies such as Amazon.

    The example of retail corporations such as Wal-Mart in using cost-cutting provides

    a clear illustration of a principle that is quite general: their increase in market powerto an

    extent that approaches monopoly in many locationsgoes with lower not higher prices.

    This reverses the conventional logic found in mainstream economics, that givena monopoly position a firm will extract higher prices; whilst that is true, it does not allow

    The root cause of economic growth under capitalism 17 of 24

    atEcono

    micCommissionforAfricaonMarch28,2012

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/

    Downloadedfrom

    http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjournals.org/http://cje.oxfordjou