three essays in industrial organization

103
Three Essays in Industrial Organization by Matthew R. Backus A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Economics) in The University of Michigan 2012 Doctoral Committee: Professor Daniel A. Ackerberg, Chair Professor Francine Lafontaine Professor Scott E. Page Assistant Professor Jeremy Fox Assistant Professor Natalia Lazzati

Upload: others

Post on 16-Feb-2022

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Three Essays in Industrial Organization

by

Matthew R. Backus

A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillmentof the requirements for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy(Economics)

in The University of Michigan2012

Doctoral Committee:

Professor Daniel A. Ackerberg, ChairProfessor Francine LafontaineProfessor Scott E. PageAssistant Professor Jeremy FoxAssistant Professor Natalia Lazzati

c© Matthew R. Backus 2012.All Rights Reserved.

To my parents

ii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

A special thanks to my dissertation committee for their invaluable encouragement and comments:

Dan Ackerberg(Chair), Jeremy Fox, Francine Lafontaine, and Natalia Lazzati, and Scott Page. Also

special thanks to William Adams, Randy Becker, Sasha Brodski, Ying Fan, Shawn Klimek, Kai-Uwe

Kuhn, Greg Lewis, and Jagadeesh Sivadasan for thoughtful comments. Chapter 1 of this dissertation

was written while I was a Special Sworn Status researcher of the US Census Bureau at the University

of Michigan Research Data Center. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the

author and do not necessarily represent the views of the U.S. Census Bureau. All results have been

reviewed to ensure that no confidential information is disclosed. All remaining errors are my own.

iii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

DEDICATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii

LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi

LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii

CHAPTER

I. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

II. Why is Productivity Correlated with Competition? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3

2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32.2 Data and Measurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

2.2.1 The Ready-Mix Concrete Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52.2.2 Sample Inclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62.2.3 Market Definition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72.2.4 Measuring Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72.2.5 Productivity Measurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

2.3 The Productivity Effect of Competition . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92.4 X-Inefficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112.5 Dynamic Selection . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122.6 Methodology and Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

2.6.1 The Quantile Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142.6.2 The Selection Correction Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

2.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

III. General Comparative Statics for Industry Dynamics in Long-Run Equi-librium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 373.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

3.2.1 Idiosyncratic Types . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 383.2.2 Stage Game . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 393.2.3 Entry and Exit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 403.2.4 Timing and Dynamics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

3.3 Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 413.4 Comparative Statics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

3.4.1 Fixed Costs of Entry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 453.4.2 Market Size . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

iv

3.5 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 483.6 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49

IV. An Estimable Demand System for a Large Auction Platform Market (withGregory Lewis) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 584.2 Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61

4.2.1 Environment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 614.2.2 Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

4.3 Nonparametric Identification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 694.3.1 Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 694.3.2 Formal Result . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

4.4 Estimation Strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 724.4.1 Step 1: Estimate transitions, exit and payments . . . . . . . . . . . 734.4.2 Nonparametric Approach Step 2: Recover valuations . . . . . . . . 744.4.3 Semiparametric Approach Step 2a: Estimate bid function . . . . . 754.4.4 Semiparametric Approach Step 2b: Match Moments . . . . . . . . 754.4.5 Characteristic Space Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77

4.5 Monte Carlo . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 784.6 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 814.7 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

V. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

v

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure

2.1 County Map of the USA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 272.2 CEA Map of the USA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 282.3 Allocative vs. Productive Efficiencies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 292.4 Value Function Response to Change in Market Size. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 302.5 Predicted effect of two narratives on productivity residual distribution. . . . . . . . 312.6 Effect of the number of ready-mix concrete firms on deciles of the productivity

residual distribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (1) and (2). . . . . . . . . . . 322.7 Effect of HHI (calculated using firms) on deciles of the productivity residual distri-

bution by CEA. Corresponds to models (3) and (4). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 332.8 Effect of the number of ready-mix concrete establishments on deciles of the produc-

tivity residual distribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (5) and (6). . . . . . . 342.9 Effect of HHI (calculated using establishments) on deciles of the productivity resid-

ual distribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (7) and (8). . . . . . . . . . . . . 353.1 Industry in Equilibrium: Recall Ψ(φ) =

∫v(φ′, µ;D)dF (φ′|φ) is the continuation

value for a firm of type φ today. Condition E2 requires that Ψ(φ) pass through thepoint (φE ,cF ), while condition E3 gives x∗ at the Y-intercept of the function. . . . 55

3.2 Decrease in Entry Costs: Let cf1 > cf2 . The reduction spurs entry, which drivesprofits down for all types. The new continuation value function Ψ2(φ) is smallerthan Ψ1(φ), and valued cf2 at φE . The exit threshold x∗ rises, spurring higherturnover and average type. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56

3.3 Increase in Market Size: Let D1 < D2. The increase in demand raises profits, inparticular for higher types. The higher profits spur entry, in turn reducing prof-its, especially for lower types. Combined, these countervailing effects push Ψ2(φ)counterclockwise around the original Ψ1(φ), pivoting around (φE , cf ). . . . . . . . 57

4.1 Monte Carlo Simulation: The figure shows the true and estimated marginal densityof valuations for product 1 for a randomly chosen Monte Carlo simulation of 500auctions with specification E. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80

vi

LIST OF TABLES

Table

2.1 Summary Statistics by CEA . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 222.2 OLS Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 222.3 Instrumental Variables Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 232.4 Decile Effects (β

(k)d ) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

2.5 Instrumental Variables with Selection Correction Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 252.6 Comparison of Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 262.7 Probit Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 364.1 Monte Carlo Results: Simple Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 864.2 Monte Carlo Results: Forward-Looking Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 874.3 Monte Carlo Results: Backward-Looking Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88

vii

CHAPTER I

Introduction

The three chapters of this dissertation are unified by two common interests: first, the modeling

of economic agents in an explicitly dynamic setting in order to capture, whether empirically or

analytically, features of their decision-making that depend on an endogenous, changing future and

second, an interest in deriving results, whether empirical or analytic, from models that depend on

economic rather than parametric assumptions.

Chapter 1 seeks an explanation for the oft-observed correlation between plant-level productivity

measures and market-level indexes of competition. The set of potential explanations can be divided

into two econometrically separable bins: X-inefficiency and dynamic selection. The former is a

plant-level treatment effect of competition and the latter is a selection story in which larger, more

competitive markets select more aggressively on productivity type. The distinction is identified both

by mechanism and by outcome: by mechanism, a nonparametric selection correction controls for

the effect of dynamic selection; by outcome, one compares the predicted and the actual effects on

quantiles of the market-level distribution of productivity residuals. The ready-mix concrete industry,

using data from the US Census of Manufactures, is a natural setting to apply these methods. Varia-

tion in competition at the local market level is driven by exogenous changes in demand for ready-mix

concrete. Both identification strategies point to X-inefficiency as the dominant explanation, raising

important questions about within-plant responses to competition.

Chapter 2 considers the set of comparative statics that can be obtained from industry dynam-

ics models without writing down a parametric model of the stage game. Results are obtained for

average type and turnover with respect to changes in market size and entry cost. Those for mar-

ket size depend on a simple and economically meaningful increasing differences assumption on the

relationship between firm type and competition. The generality of these results is important for

the booming literature that applies parametric variations of industry dynamics models to match

1

empirical stylized facts of plant-level production data and the effects of trade policy.

Chapter 3 constructs a model of repeated second-price auctions in which bidders are persistent

and have multidimensional private valuations. In this setting, equilibrium bids are shaded by the

endogenous option value of losing to bid another day. We prove existence of this equilibrium and

characterize the ergodic distribution of types. Having developed a demand system, we show that it is

non-parametrically identified from panel data. Relatively simple nonparametric and semiparametric

estimation procedures are proposed and tested by Monte Carlo simulation. The analysis highlights

the importance of both dynamic bidding strategies and panel data sample selection issues when

analyzing these markets.

2

CHAPTER II

Why is Productivity Correlated with Competition?

2.1 Introduction

There is a perennial paper in the productivity literature which presents the following empirical

result, updated for contemporary innovations in attitudes towards data and econometrics: firms

that are in more competitive markets are also more efficient. In the era of cross-sectional, cross-

industry regressions, the correlation was straightforward to measure (Green and Mayes (1991) Caves

and Barton (1990)). As panel methods became more prominent, the empirical result stood out

in still more clarity (Hay and Liu (1997), Nickell (1996), Pavcnik (2002)). Finally, when cross-

industry regressions became suspect, though finding an appropriate industry and instrument became

a challenge, the correlation was robust (Berger and Hannan (1998), Syverson (2004), Schmitz (2005),

Dunne, Klimek, and Schmitz (2010)).

The existence of a correlation between competition and productivity is significant both for anti-

trust as well as trade policy. As Williamson (1968) noted in the case of horizontal merger evaluation,

for deadweight loss to outweigh alleged productive synergies the estimated percentage change in

price would have to be several times larger than the percentage efficiency gain. Efficiency losses

from market concentration, however, which affect not only all firms in the market but operate on

infra-marginal sales, could potentially overturn that result. If measurable, these rectangles may be a

much stronger argument for worrying about mergers than deadweight loss triangles, famously found

to be so diminutive by Harberger (1954). Moreover, trade economists have been quick to adopt

measured efficiency gains as one of the central arguments for gains from trade, a Pantheon formerly

dominated by allocative efficiencies and Ricardo’s argument from comparative advantage.

No consensus exists, however, regarding the explanation for such a correlation. There are two

main hypotheses: First, that competition has a direct effect on productivity. This hypothesis was

originally introduced as a black box under the name ”X-inefficiency” by Leibenstein (1966) and

3

has since received considerable theoretical development. A second hypothesis has emerged from

the trade literature on productivity gains from trade liberalization: that more competitive markets

select more aggressively on productivity. Even in the absence of a direct causal relationship, this

implies that the selected sample in more competitive markets will be, on average, more productive

than that in less competitive markets.1 The two hypotheses will be referred to here as X-inefficiency

and dynamic selection.2

The conflation of these two effects is not unknown, and some of the papers documenting the

correlation between competition and productivity have included reduced-form efforts to control for

dynamic selection. Pavcnik (2002) applies Olley and Pakes (1996) to obtain productivity residuals,

and then uses a regression framework with exit dummies to control for the selection effect. Alterna-

tively, Schmitz (2005) adopts a decomposition approach to measure the relative effects of exit and

within-firm change. Both papers find evidence in favor of the within-firm X-inefficiency story.

This paper endeavors to disambiguate the two stories in a way that is structurally consistent and

requires minimal appeal to parametric form beyond the original derivation productivity residuals.

Identification is formulated two way– first, bys thinking about the effect on the ergodic distribution

of types; though the predictions of X-inefficiency on the distribution of types is ambiguous, the

dynamic selection story implies the correlation of productivity quantiles and competition should

be decreasing in quantile, since it operates primarily on the left tail. Second, an explicit model of

the firm’s decision problem is formulated in order to derive a selection correction procedure which

isolates the effect of X-inefficiency by controlling completely for dynamic selection. While the first

approach has the appealing feature of offering a direct visual test, the latter is used to generate

numerical estimates of the relative contribution of the two stories. Both confirm the dominance of

X-inefficiency.

The natural setting for applying these identification techniques is ready-mix concrete. One of the

difficulties of studying the correlation between competition and productivity is generating sufficient

cross-sectional variance in competitive structure. High transportation costs make ready-mix concrete

1This is related, but not identical, to the selection issue treated in the third stage of Olley and Pakes’s (1996)structural production function estimator. In their paper there is only one market, and therefore market structure isfully controlled for by allowing the propensity score estimator to vary nonparametrically in time. Even given consistentestimator of the productivity residual, however, reduced-form estimates of the within-firm increase in productivitywill be influenced upwards by dynamic selection, as survivors in an increasingly competitive market are more likelyto have had a favorable innovation in productivity.

2A third hypothesis emerges if the object of interest is revenue-weighted average productivity; more competitivemarkets may better allocate demand to higher productivity firms, a hypothesis that comes out strong in Olleyand Pakes (1996). This paper pre-empts the third hypothesis by focusing on unweighted productivity, not becauseallocation is unimportant, but because it is beyond the scope of the paper– the focus here is to disambiguate theempirical consequences of X-inefficiency and dynamic selection. Moreover, due to data exclusion issues describedbelow, the data is poorly suited to measuring the reallocation effect.

4

markets local in character; these local markets permit the measurement of just such variance. Second,

the availability of homogeneous output measures in physical, rather than revenue terms, allows one

to estimate physical productivity entirely separately from market power. This paper builds on

Syverson’s (2004) pioneering study of productivity dispersion in ready-mix concrete, though here

the first rather than the second moment is under consideration,3 and this first moment is leveraged

to examine the underlying model. Also closely related is Collard-Wexler (2011), which studies the

determinants of establishment survival in ready-mix concrete markets.

There is also an extensive related literature on the use of decomposition methods in the study of

changes in aggregate productivity. Here, a regression framework is used instead of decomposition for

two reasons: to begin with, the objective is to take advantage of cross-sectional variation in order to

map the changes in productivity onto a continuous explanatory variable, an index of competition.

Decomposition methods are most apposite to the study of time-series variation and discrete policy

changes, as in Olley and Pakes (1996). Moreover, the dynamic selection story posited as an alterna-

tive to X-inefficiency is also a potential source of bias which would tend to overstate the within-firm

share of the change in productivity. At the end of the day, however, little evidence is found for the

dynamic selection effect, which should in turn offer reassurance on the use of decomposition methods

in productivity analysis.

Section 2 describes the ready-mix concrete industry, the data used, and the measurement issues

associated with studying productivity, spatially defined markets, and competition indexes. Section

3 captures the correlation between competition and productivity with a reduced-form instrumental

variables approach. In section 4 and 5 the theoretical foundations for the two effects conflated in that

correlation are explored, and section 6 expounds on and implements two strategies for separating

them econometrically. Section 7 concludes.

2.2 Data and Measurement

2.2.1 The Ready-Mix Concrete Industry

This paper uses US Census of Manufactures data for the ready-mix concrete industry (SIC 3273)

for years 1982, 1987, and 1992. Ready-mix concrete is a mixture of cement, water, gravel, and

a handful of chemical additives. Stockpiles of these materials are stored at the plant, mixed on

demand, and loaded in liquid form into a ready-mix concrete truck for delivery at the construction

3Syverson (2004) is built on a variant of the dynamic selection story and finds an average productivity effect aswell, however notes (see footnote 6) that this effect would be conflated with X-inefficiency, and that it is beyond thescope of that paper to disentangle the two effects.

5

site, where the concrete is poured.

The liquid mixture begins to set as soon as it is loaded into the ready-mix concrete truck; besides

the potential for wasted materials, there are costs associated with removing hardened concrete from

the inside of the drums of ready-mix concrete trucks. These two factors both contribute to the

high transportation costs which render this industry markedly local in scope. Geographic market

definition is discussed below, however it is this uniquely local character which makes ready-mix

concrete such an attractive industry for study; in order to measure the effect of competition on

productivity, one requires variation in competitive structure. This is difficult to obtain for most

manufacturing industries, which compete in an increasingly integrated world market.

A second important feature of the industry is the homogeneity of the output. Though the compo-

sition of the chemical additives may differ some by application, this is thought to generate very little

product differentiation. For this reason, in the years 1982, 1987, and 1992 the Products Supplement

to the Census of Manufactures includes output data in cubic yards, which obviates many of the

concerns that would accompany the use of deflated revenue in estimating productivity. Using phys-

ical output to measure productivity is especially apposite to this application because productivity

residuals based on revenue measures will be reflect market-level and idiosyncratic demand shocks

through firms’ mark-ups, generating a spurious correlation between competition and productivity. 4

The Census of Manufactures offers extensive data on inputs of production which are used to

estimate productivity residuals, as discussed below. For more extensive discussion of the data and

the ready-mix concrete industry, the reader is referred to Syverson (2008).

2.2.2 Sample Inclusion

There are over five thousand ready-mix concrete establishments observed by the Census of Man-

ufactures in each year of my sample. Unfortunately, roughly one-third of these establishments are

”administrative records” establishments; that is, small enough to be exempt from completing census

forms. Data for these is a combination of administrative records from other agencies and imputation,

and is therefore unusable for calculating productivity residuals.

A small handful of establishments are extensively diversified and operate in multiple SIC codes.

Here they are excluded if less than fifty percent of their total sales is composed of ready-mix concrete.

For diversified establishments which survive this exclusion, inputs devoted to ready-mix concrete are

approximated by multiplying the fraction of sales from ready-mix concrete by the conflated input

4This is less of an issue to the extent that one finds a positive correlation between competition and productivity;mark-ups in the measurement error of productivity would be negatively correlated with competition and thereforemerely attenuate the result.

6

variable. Finally, the establishment-level price of a cubic yard of concrete is calculated by dividing

revenues by quantity, and a small number of firms with extremal values are excluded from the

sample.

It is important to note that while these establishments are excluded for regressions that depend

on estimates of the productivity residuals, they are not excluded in the calculation of market-level

variables– in particular the competition indexes discussed below in section 2.4.

2.2.3 Market Definition

This paper employs the Component Economic Area (CEA) market definition to study ready-mix

concrete markets. CEAs are a complete and mutually exclusive categorization of the nation’s over

three thousand counties into 348 economic markets5. In contrast with the sometimes arbitrary size

and shapes of counties (see Figure 2.1), the typical CEA is defined first by the identification of

an economic node, and then the assignment of non-nodal counties to economic nodes by newspaper

readership and traffic commuting patterns (see Figure 2.2). Johnson and Kort (2004) offers more

discussion of the assignment of counties to CEAs, and Syverson (2004), which pioneered the use of

CEAs in the study of ready-mix concrete, offers still more motivation for their use.

2.2.4 Measuring Competition

In a Markov-perfect industry dynamics model with full information (e.g., Ericson and Pakes

(1995)), the competitive structure of the market enters the payoff and value functions of the firm

through a high-dimensional state variable which includes the type of every active firm in the market.

As the explicit inclusion of such a variable is infeasible for empirical work, two indexes are constructed

which capture the salient features of the state of the market.

On the extensive margin, the size of the market is captured by the number of ready-mix concrete

firms per square mile. Informally, the more ready-mix concrete firms there are in a fixed geographic

space, the more substitutable they are, and therefore the more intense the competition between

them.

The second measure is meant to capture the intensive margin. The Herfindal-Hirschman Index

is constructed from the revenue of active firms. Though this variable will be negatively correlated

with the number of firms, it also captures the allocation of demand between firms, and therefore

reflects the dispersion of firm types.6

5The number of CEAs was revised to 344 in 2004, however this paper employs the pre-2004 CEA definitions.6Here firm type is meant to be interpreted very loosely. One firm may be dominant because it has idiosyncratically

low costs; alternatively, it may have strong idiosyncratic demand, e.g. informal ties with contractors.

7

Both of these measures can be sensibly computed using either establishments or firms as the

unit of observation. This paper presents results for both. Summary statistics for these competition

indexes can be found in Table 2.1. As noted above, the calculation of the competition indexes

includes the administrative record and diversified firms discussed in section 2.2.

2.2.5 Productivity Measurement

Establishment-level productivity, denoted by ωit, is measured as the additive residual from a

Cobb-Douglas gross output production function in log form. That is,

(2.1) ωit = yit − αltlit − αk(s)tk(s)it − αk(e)tk

(e)it − αmtmit − αeteit

–where yit is output, lit is labor, k(s)it is capital in structures, k

(e)it is equipment capital, mit is

materials, and eit is energy. Inputs and output are in logs. Input elasticities αt are estimated using

industry level cost shares, which are calculated from the NBER productivity database (therefore

indirectly, from the Census of Manufacturers).7 Equipment and structure capital shares are con-

structed using reported stocks multiplied by rental rates for the two-digit industry from the BLS.8

In what follows, these productivity residuals will be the dependent variables in a series of regres-

sions designed to look for- and to explain- the correlation between competition and productivity.

Two assumptions employed in the derivation of these residuals are suspect: first, constant returns to

scale is assumed and has been tested in Syverson (2004).9 Second, the hypothesis of X-inefficiency

may be conflated with optimization failure. As discussed below, this paper remains agnostic as to

the particulars, but models of X-inefficiency have been developed which are not inconsistent with

optimal input choice. Still, one way to deal with this would be to wrap the entire selection correc-

tion procedure described below into a one-stage structural production function estimator based on

Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer (2006)10. This paper obtains the productivity residuals in a first stage

for the sake of expositional clarity.

7This contains an implicit assumption of constant returns to scale. Syverson (2004) tests this assumption for theready-mix concrete industry, and finds the results supportive.

8For a discussion of the use of index methods for estimating TFP with CMF data, see Syverson (2004).9In the next draft of this paper, the assumption is tested by regressing ωit on the predicted level of output and cit,

both instrumented by the set of demand shifters. Results for this robustness check are still pending disclosure reviewwith the US Census Bureau.

10This exercise would require additional timing assumptions on the choice of materials in order to avoid the collinear-ity problems described in Bond and Sderbom (2005). For instance, one might assume that materials are chosen atsome point in time just prior to t, following Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer’s (2006) assumptions on the choice of labor.This is not implausible; one can think of material usage as being dictated by contracts which are agreed upon priorto production. However, one additional advantage of the fully structural approach would be the incorporation of anunobservable (to the firm) idiosyncratic productivity shock.

8

2.3 The Productivity Effect of Competition

Taking a reduced-form approach to measuring the relationship between competition and produc-

tivity, the following regression is standard:

(2.2) ωit = β0 + βccm(i)t + εit

This regression is constitutive of the literature on competition and productivity, and carries

hefty baggage: The first challenge is to obtain sufficient variation in competitive structure. One

solution, now largely outmoded, is to run cross-industry regressions. This paper avoids the problems

associated with cross-industry regressions by focusing on an industry with many local markets.

Second, to the extent that productivity is estimated using deflated revenue as output, the error

introduced will be correlated with the competition index via mark-ups. Foster, Haltiwanger, and

Syverson (2008) identify a set of industries (including ready-mix concrete) for which both physical

and revenue output data are available, and explore the relationship. As in their work, this problem

is obviated by the availability of physical output data for ready-mix concrete.11

OLS results for (2.2) are presented in Table 2.2. For all four competition indexes there is a pos-

itive and statistically significant correlation between competition and productivity. The regressions

using count indexes are run in log-log form, and therefore the coefficients βOLS can be interpreted

as elasticities of output with respect to competition12. The HHI indexes are scaled between zero

and one and unlogged; the coefficient is therefore interpreted as the efficiency difference between two

extrema: complete dispersion and absolute monopoly.

An obvious concern with these results is the endogeneity of competition. The presence of high-

type firms will likely discourage entry, and therefore generate a non-causal correlation between

concentration and productivity which biases the estimates.13 One strategy for dealing with this

problem is to identify an exogenous regulatory shock to the level of competition. In the trade

literature, liberalization of trade regulations provides extensive data on this front; Olley and Pakes

11In the next draft of this paper, results will be also available for all of the estimation results with productivitycalculated using revenue output, rather than physical output. It is interesting to know whether, as a simple modelwould predict, the use of revenue measures attenuates the results, and whether the methods can be applied to industrieswhere physical output data is unavailable. These results are pending disclosure review at the US Census Bureau.

12It is important to remember that the percentage change interpretation of elasticities is based on consideration ofsmall changes, and therefore breaks down here for some common and interesting cases, e.g. the addition of a secondcompetitor in a low-demand CEA– a 100% increase in the number of competitors.

13Nickell (1996) notes that this source of endogeneity, like that stemming from the use of revenue-based productivitymeasures, works in the ”right direction” in that it attenuates any positive correlation between competition andproductivity.

9

(1996) use the forced breakup of a monopsonistic downstream firm. There are limitations to this

approach. On the one hand, they are often one-shot or at best finitely staged events. Moreover,

because they are typically common shocks, they are absorbed entirely by time effects, and therefore

conflated with other sources of variation. To the extent that the shocks are not common, the

identifying comparison is made either across industry or across geographic regions. An alternative

approach, pioneered by Syverson (2004), builds on the insight of Sutton (1991) that competition

in the long run is dictated by market fundamentals. A market-level demand shifter is an eligible

instrument generating exogenous variation in competitive structure. Higher demand encourages

entry, and more entry implies lower transportation costs and increased substitutability.

This paper employs a number of instruments to capture the level of demand for ready-mix

concrete: construction employment (SIC 15), the total number of residential building permits issued,

single-family building permits, five or more family building permits, and local government highway

and road expenditure.14 Summary statistics are presented in Table 1. In the regressions which

follow, however, the instruments are divided by area, in square miles, to approximate the density of

demand and then logged.

More firms in a finite geographic space implies more substitutability, and therefore relevance to

our indexes of competition. Exogeneity is maintained by arguing that ready-mix concrete typically

comprises a small portion of a construction budget, and therefore the decision whether to build is

unlikely to reflect variation in mark-ups stemming from competitive structure. Using these demand

shifters to instrument for the endogenous index cm(i)t, the following regression is run:

(2.3) ωit = β1 + βIV cm(i)t + εit

Results for the baseline IV model under a variety of specifications are presented in Table 2.3. For

all specifications, a strong and robust effect of competition is found on productivity. For comparison,

the standard of deviation of ωit over the period of the sample is found to be 0.2768. The first-stage

F-statistics are presented at the bottom of the table, and suggest some concern for the strength of the

instruments at predicting the endogenous regressor for those specifications using HHI. The results

are rather stronger than those obtained by OLS in Table 2.2, which seems to support Nickell’s (1996)

argument that the endogeneity bias will attenuate, rather than exaggerate, the positive correlation.

The results are reported for both lagged and contemporary instruments, for comparison with

14Construction employment is calculated directly from the LBD. The last four instruments are taken from the USACounties data available online from the US Census Bureau.

10

the selection correction model presented in section 6, where the importance of the distinction will

be apparent. Though strong, the results have no structural interpretation. They conflate the direct

effect of X-inefficiency with the bias induced by dynamic selection. The next two sections expand

on the theory behind these two stories, with the ultimate goal of disambiguating them empirically.

2.4 X-Inefficiency

The term X-inefficiency was coined by Leibenstein (1966) and born to immediate controversy.

The concept was originally posed as a counterpoint contemporary optimal choice theory, which

sparked a heated debate and some very colorfully titled papers (Stigler (1976), Leibenstein (1978)).

Despite the controversy, two salient points were made: first, that there is an empirical correlation

between competition and productivity; second, that if productive efficiencies of competition such as

X-inefficiency do exist, they are potentially more significant in welfare terms than the more familiar

allocative inefficiencies from market power. Figure 2.3 illustrates this comparison; the welfare loss of

an increase from p to p’ is represented by the colored deadweight loss triangle, and the welfare gain

of a decrease in costs from c to c’ is represented by the much larger rectangle. The intuition is simple

and hearkens to Harberger (1954): productive efficiencies are bigger because they are compiled on

infra-marginal sales, whereas allocative efficiencies are compiled on the margin.

Here the term X-inefficiency is used with important caveats. The “X-” has been nuanced by

the development of models of asymmetric information that reconcile suboptimal outcomes with

optimal choice theory. Because of this, the “inefficiency” as well is subject to caveat: opening up

the black box also implies the possibility of costs which are not represented in Figure 2.3. A more

complete model is necessary to make decisive arguments about welfare. The theoretical literature

on X-inefficiency is small but varied; though it is beyond the scope of this paper to commit to one

or another, a handful of such models are described by way of example.

One explanation advocated by Nalebuff and Stiglitz (1983) and Mookherjee (1983) for the em-

pirical evidence of X-inefficiency is grounded in informational externalities of competition. The

presence of competitors in the same market allows firms to statistically separate randomness in

market-level demand from unobservable effort exerted by managers; in the limit, firms attain the

first-best equilibrium outcome. An alternate explanation is that firms are especially motivated to

improve efficiency by the threat of bankruptcy. By forcing all firms to operate at a thinner price-

cost margin, competition motivates all firms to expend more resources on improving productivity

(e.g., by providing stronger incentives for managers). As Schmidt’s (1997) paper notes, however,

11

the effect depends strongly on parametric assumptions. More recently, Raith (2003) offers an ex-

planation that hinges on market dynamics. He identifies two competing effects; a business stealing

effect which increases returns to improving productivity when competition is more intense, and a

scope effect, which decreases the returns to improving productivity when competing firms have low

prices. He shows that while these effects cancel out in a static model, endogenous exit makes the

prediction unambiguous: the business stealing effect dominates, and firms have more incentive to

improve productivity in more competitive markets.

The set of explanations described here is both rich and incomplete; moreover, is likely that at

this level of analysis, the particular industry and institutional context is likely to play an important

role. Rather than advocating a particular explanation, the argument here will remain agnostic,

characterizing by X-inefficiency any story such that, at equilibrium, the production function can be

represented as if the competitive structure of the market were an input of production:

(2.4) yit = f(xit, cm(i)t) + φit

The generality here highlights the common and essential feature of stories of X-inefficiency which

will be econometrically identified: the direct, causal effect of competition on productivity. If one

could take a firm out of a less competitive market and put it into a more competitive one, X-

inefficiency implies that the firm would experience an increase in productivity.

2.5 Dynamic Selection

The dynamic selection effect is a story that has gained traction in the international trade lit-

erature and owes its intellectual heritage to Melitz’s (2003) innovative extensions to the general

industry dynamics model of Hopenhayn (1992a). In contrast to the direct productivity effect that

drives X-inefficiency, dynamic selection is a story about the selection of the set of firms that are

observed in equilibrium. Unprofitable firms exit, spurring entry of new firms. If the break-even

threshold is stricter in more competitive markets, it will be the case that the set of firms which

survive this stricter survival rule will be, on average, more productive.

Three essential features drive models which explain dynamic selection: Idiosyncratic types, an

unlimited pool of ex-ante identical entrants, and endogenous exit. Particularly apposite to ready-

mix construction, Syverson (2004) presents a two-stage entry game in which entrants pay a fixed

12

cost to learn their marginal costs, exit if the costs are too high, and then compete for the business of

consumers arranged on a circle with transportation costs. Though the model does not capture the

repeated play of other industry dynamics approaches, the payoff is the explicitly spatial character

of stage-game competition. As demand density on the circle increases, more firms enter, and the

exit cutoff becomes stricter, in turn lowering average observed marginal cost. Melitz and Ottaviano

(2008), exemplary of the trade literature approach, employs parametric assumptions and structural

assumptions on demand and the form of competition in exchange for closed-form analytic compar-

ative statics. As in Hopenhayn (1992a), firm types evolve according to a Markov process, and firms

exit should the expected discounted value of future profits ever become negative. That exit threshold

is shown to be stricter in larger markets. Finally, Backus (2011) generalizes the Hopenhayn (1992a)

approach to derive comparative statics without parametric restrictions or assumptions on the form of

competition. In comparison with Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), the trade-off is closed-form solutions

for generality.

None of these models treat competition as exogenous. While in principle one could parameterize

the degree of substitutability of firms’ products, the prediction would have limited empirical content

for lack of natural experiments. Instead, competition is related to a plausibly exogenous shock to

market size (e.g., a demand shifter). Figure 2.4 depicts in broad strokes the logic of the argument.

Panel (a) illustrates the value function.15 In Syverson (2004), the value function is simply second

stage profits. In Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) and Backus (2011) it represents the expected dis-

counted value of all future profits. The exit strategy is manifested by a kink; sufficiently low types

have negative expected value to participating in the market, and therefore exit to obtain zero. The

role of entry is more subtle; equilibrium entry requires that the expected value of entry, which is

obtained by integrating the value function over the distribution of entrants’ types, is equal to the

cost of entry. Assuming for convenience that the type space is bounded [0, 1] and the distribution

of entrants uniform with full support, this can be measured as the area under the value function.

An increase in market size has two countervailing effects. First, there is a direct and positive

effect on all types’ profits, which is represented in panel (b). However, the value function cannot

be strictly higher for every type, because this would violate the equilibrium entry condition that

the expected value of entry equal the cost of entry. Therefore the value function shifts back in, as

in panel (c). The comparative static of interest, however, hinges on the subtle detail that at the

new equilibrium, the x-intercept of the value function moves to the right, which is interpreted as

15Here it is assumed that the payoff is increasing in type, consistent with the productivity interpretation. In termsof cost, as in Syverson’s (2004) model, the graph would be reflected across the y axis.

13

a stricter selection rule. All of the models discussed above impose special structure to obtain this

counter-clockwise rotation of the value function. In Syverson (2004), it stems from the fact that

greater entry on a circle of finite size implies greater substitutability of firms, reallocating profits

from lower to higher types. In Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) this is accomplished by parametric

restrictions on demand and competition. Backus (2011), in contrast, achieves this by considering

the broad set of stage games for which competition reallocates profits from low to high-type firms.16

The key to the dynamic selection story is this idea that competition reallocates profits from

low-type firms to high-type firms, an idea which manifests itself in a variety of different assumptions

in each of these models17. This reallocation drives the result that in more competitive markets, the

exit rule is stricter. Where the exit rule is stricter, the set of surviving firms is on average more

productive, without any direct causal effect of competition on productivity.

2.6 Methodology and Estimation

The object of the structural part of this paper is to separate the two classes of stories for why more

competitive markets harbor more efficient firms: static and dynamic. The first strategy, described

in section 6.1, is based on cross-sectional comparisons of markets in long-run equilibrium, and the

different effects that X-inefficiency and dynamic selection have on the ergodic distribution of types.

The second strategy, which is the focus of section 6.2, nests both effects in a single econometric

model and is able to measure their relative contributions to the conflated effect, βIV from section 3.

Results for both models strongly favor the X-inefficiency story.

2.6.1 The Quantile Approach

The identification strategy in this section hinges on the distinct predictions of the X-inefficiency

and the dynamic selection story for the ergodic distribution of types. Combes, Duranton, Gobillon,

Puga, and Roux (2010) develop a related strategy for distinguishing economies of agglomeration from

dynamic selection in cross-industry data on French establishments. The key insight of their paper

is that within-firm effects (for them, agglomeration, here X-inefficiency) will shift the entire distri-

bution, while the dynamic selection story hinges on a shifting left-truncation, thereby contracting

and distorting the distribution.

16Formally, this is accomplished by assuming that the reduced-form stage game profit function has increasingdifferences between completely ordered measures of types and the demand shift parameter.

17Boone (2008) argues that the reallocation of profits from low types to high types is not merely correlated withcompetition, but essential to it. He proposes relative profits of high types to low types as a measure of competition,and shows in a number of examples that it performs better than some other measures at predicting welfare gains.

14

2.6.1.1 X-Inefficiency vs. Dynamic Selection

A visual motivation for the distinction is presented in Figure 5: Panel (a) illustrates a constant

additive shift of the entire distribution; an implication of the linear baseline model for X-inefficiency.

Panel (b) illustrates a shift only of the truncation point; the left side moves substantially, but the

right tail is fixed and the distribution contracts. The interpretation of this truncation shift as the

dynamic selection effect hinges on the assumption that optimal exit strategy is characterized by a

simple threshold rule for idiosyncratic type, a common implication of industry dynamics that follow

Hopenhayn (1992a).18

The prediction of the top panel depends heavily on the assumption that the effect of X-inefficiency

does not depend on φit, an assumption inconsistent with, for instance, Schmidt’s (1997) story of

bankruptcy aversion. The prediction of the lower panel, however, is not driven by parametrics:

it implies that if the dynamic selection story is dominant, most of the productivity gains from

competition should be evident in the left side of the distribution.

2.6.1.2 Estimation

The empirical strategy adopted here is to regress deciles of the CEA-level distribution of observed

ωit on the competition index cm(i)t, instrumented for by the set of demand shifters:

(2.5) ρ(k)mt = β

(k)d cmt + νmt

– where ρ(k) is the kth decile (so that k ∈ 1, . . . , 9) of the distribution of ωit in market m, and the

unit of observation is the market.

The implication of figure 2 from section 6.1.1 is clear: β(k)d should be decreasing in k. The

prediction of the X-inefficiency story is dependent on the parametric assumption of a constant

effect, therefore the main interest is to ask whether the movement of β(k)c in k is consistent with the

truncation shift.

18The argument made by figure 2 is impressionistic, and the figures depict a normal distribution. A more completemodel would require substantial additional assumptions, parametric and otherwise, to capture the dynamic implica-tions of a linear shift or a shift in the truncation point, however the intuition here is clear: mechanisms that workvia shifts affect the entire distribution, while mechanisms that operate on the truncation point will affect primarilythe left tail. An fully specified example of an industry dynamics model which generates these results is offered byCombes, Duranton, Gobillon, Puga, and Roux (2010).

15

2.6.1.3 Results

Though the argument has been somewhat informal, the results offered in Table 2.4 and depicted

graphically in Figures 6-9 are stark. Contrary to the prediction of the dynamic selection story, β(k)d

seems to be constant or increasing in k; sharply increasing at the far right tail.19

The above is not a formal statistical test, but offers strong evidence against the null that dynamic

selection is the primary story. To develop this identification strategy more rigorously would require

extensive assumptions, parametric and otherwise. The next section offers a rigorous, structural

identification strategy without such assumptions and, further, can measure the relative contribution

of both stories to the observed correlation.

2.6.2 The Selection Correction Approach

Reconsider briefly the reduced-form IV regression run in section 3, where the competition index

cm(i)t is instrumented for using the set of demand shifters:

ωit = β1 + βIV cm(i)t + εit

The elasticity coefficient βIV was interpreted as the reduced-form correlation coefficient of pro-

ductivity and competition. However, by imposing additive separability of X-inefficiency and idiosyn-

cratic productivity as well as linearity of the effect of competition20 one can go further:

(2.6) ωit = βXcm(i)t + φit

The coefficient βX is interpreted as a structural primitive describing X-inefficiency, and the

divergence between the true βIV and the correlation coefficient estimated in section 3 stems from

selection biased induced by dynamic selection. The error term, φit, has a structural interpretation

as well, as establishment-level idiosyncratic productivity.

With parametric restrictions, one could proceed with a selection correction in the spirit of Heck-

man (1979). Alternatively, with data on the selection-relevant observables for non-selected firms, a

nonparametric selection-correction would be viable. An aversion to parametric restrictions and a

lack of such data makes the selection problem difficult.

19Because HHI is a measure of concentration rather than competition, both the prediction and the results are ofopposite sign.

20Linearity is assumed for comparison with βIV . The relationship between cm(i)t and ωit is nonparametricallyidentified.

16

A way forward, borrowed from Olley and Pakes (1996), is to give up one year of data and impose

a stricter selection rule: that the firm was observed at time t− 1. If the bias induced can be written

in terms of time t and t − 1 observables, a control function can be used to solve the endogeneity

problem. In the next two sections, just such a control function is derived from a model of the decision

problem of the firm.

2.6.2.1 The Firm’s Decision Problem

In order to capture the bias explicitly, a fuller model of the firm’s exit choice is presented. It is a

finite-firm model with multidimensional states in the spirit of Ericson and Pakes (1995) as extended

by Doraszelski and Satterthwaite (2010).

Stage-game profits are given by R(φit, xit, Sm(i)t, dm(i)t), where φit represents, as before, the

idiosyncratic establishment-level productivity shock, xit is a vector of firm-specific state variables

(e.g., capital, age, and idiosyncratic establishment-level demand), the state of the market Sm(i)t

includes all firms’ types, and dm(i)t is a vector of exogenous demand shifters. The first assumption

is the timing of play:

(A1) φ evolves→ stage game → entry and exit

The conclusions here are robust to entry before exit and vice versa, as well as to the inclusion of

choice variables which affect the firm specific state in xit. What is important about (A1) is that the

stage game is played at the new productivity level and before the exit decision, which implies that

in the data-generating process, observables are generated even for exiting firms. At the time of the

exit choice, the firm is assumed to condition on the following information set:

(A2) Iit ≡< φit, xit, Sm(i)t, dm(i)t >

Firms’ decisions may affect both their owns states and the state of the market. However, φit is

assumed to evolve according to an exogenous Markov process. Formally,

(A3) p(φit|Iit−1) = p(φit|φit−1)

Additional assumptions are required to guarantee existence of equilibrium with a nonempty set

17

of active firms in this market, however that is beyond the scope of this paper. The interested reader

is referred to Doraszelski and Satterthwaite (2010). These assumptions are made for the purposes

of identification, as discussed below, where one can also find a discussion of the implications of

weakening or reversing them.

2.6.2.2 Identification

Recall (2.6), which formally nests the X-inefficiency hypothesis:

ωit = βXcm(i)t + φit

The stricter selection rule allows one to condition both on the information set of the firm at

time t− 1 as well as survival from t− 1. Let φ∗it be the minimum φ required to sustain nonnegative

expected discounted profits; then, survival from t − 1 implies φit−1 ≥ φ∗m(i)t−1. In order to derive

the selection correction in terms of observables, one takes the expectation of both sides of (2.6)

conditional on < Iit−1, φit−1 ≥ φ∗m(i)t−1 >:

E[φit|Iit−1, φit−1 > φ∗m(i)t−1] =β0 + βXE[cm(i)t|Iit−1, φit−1 > φ∗m(i)t−1]

+ E[φit|Iit−1, φit > φ∗m(i)t](2.7)

Focusing on the last term, which represents selection bias, note that (A1) and (A2) imply that

φit−1 > φ∗m(i)t−1 is fully determined by Iit−1. Therefore,

(2.8) E[φit|Iit−1, φit > φ∗m(i)t] = E[φit|Iit−1]

Moreover, the exogeneity of the Markov process (A3) implies that the only relevant information in

Iit−1 for the expected value of φit is φit−1

E[φit|Iit−1] = E[φit|φit−1]

= ψ(φit−1)

– where ψ is some unknown function. Though φit−1 is not directly observable, the model implies

φit−1 = ωit−1 − βXcm(i)t−1. As the arguments of the selection bias can be rewritten in terms of

18

observables, a control function can account for the bias:

ωit = β2 + βXcm(i)t + ψ(ωit−1 − βccm(i)t−1) + εit

The function ψ is estimated by sieve, which allows for flexible parametric form that is increasing in

complexity and nonparametric in the limit (see Chen (2007)). That ψ is treated flexibly is important

because its is unknown without substantial further structure and solving a dynamic programming

problem. Since ψ(·) captures the bias conditional on prior type and survival, the remaining error

εit is mean-zero conditional on Iit−1 by construction. Consistent with (A2), lagged demand shifters

are used to instrument for cm(i)t. Alternatively, one could modify (A2) to give firms foresight, in

which case contemporary instruments would be appropriate.

Given an estimate of βX , one can go a step further to capture the dynamic selection effect by a

reduced-form parameter denoted βDS , which will offer a useful point of comparison. First, net out

βXcm(i)t from ωit to obtain φit. Then run the following regression, instrumenting for cm(i)t using

the set of demand shifters:

(2.9) φit = β3 + βDScm(i)t + ξit

The null of X-inefficiency only implies that βDS = 0. The story captured by βDS is the selection

effect. The limited modeling assumptions imposed by this paper offer no structural interpretation,

however βDS can be thought of as the reduced-form average dynamic selection effect weighted by

the sample of markets observed, which can be compared in magnitude to βX . In this sense, the

model nests both X-inefficiency and dynamic selection as explanations for the correlation found in

the IV regressions of section 3.

Intuitively, identification hinges on being able to write the bias introduced by selection as a

function of objects which are either observed or implied by the model. By controlling for φit−1

nonparametrically, the variation which remains is innovation in productivity. Some of this innovation

may be explained by exogenous shocks to competition as predicted by the set of instruments for

demand, and the rest is explained by the Markov evolution (A3) of productivity types.

19

2.6.2.3 Results

Estimates from the selection correction model are presented in Table 2.5 for each of the eight

specifications presented in the IV and quantile approaches. The first set of results present the

nonlinear two-stage least-squares estimates of βX , the primitive describing the direct effect of X-

inefficiency. The second set offer a reduced-form estimate of the contribution of the dynamic selection

story, βDS . These results are condensed and presented in comparison with the IV estimates from

section 3 in Table 2.6.

After taking out the direct causal effect, only in models (2) and (4) does one obtain a statistically

significant (at the 0.05 level) βDS . The results suggest that X-inefficiency explains the majority of

the correlation identified by βIV . To ask this question in another way, probits were run to ask how

whether competition, instrumented by the set of demand shifters, predicts survival into the next

period, conditional on type and other observable characteristics of the establishment. Coefficient

estimates are presented in Table 2.7. Confirming intuition, productivity is clearly correlated with

survival; however the insignificance of the coefficient on cm(i)t supports the conclusion that dynamic

selection is not an economically significant story in this industry.21

2.7 Conclusion

This paper has offered evidence for a correlation between competition and productivity in ready-

mix concrete. Two explanations were identified from the literature: X-inefficiency and dynamic

selection, and two empirical strategies were developed and implemented to nonparametrically dis-

tinguish between them. The quantile approach yielded results directly opposite those predicted by

the dynamic selection story: the biggest movements in the distribution of productivity residuals was

in the right tail rather than in the left. The selection correction approach, on the other hand, was

able to measure the relative contribution of the two stories, and weighed in emphatically behind

X-inefficiency.

In some ways this result is unsatisfying; X-inefficiency is the less-specified of the two stories, and

the conclusion here begs the question of what is driving the within-firm response to competition.

Some reflections can be gleaned from the evidence compiled here. For instance, the movement of

the right tail would imply that bankruptcy aversion is not the primary story in ready-mix concrete.

A fuller treatment of this question is beyond the scope of this paper, but an important direction for

21Results in Table 2.7 are coefficients and not marginal effects; the emphasis here is on the insignificance, ratherthan the magnitude of the effect. See Collard-Wexler (2011) for extensive further work on the determinants of selectionin the ready-mix concrete industry.

20

future research. It is only with a theoretical framework to explain the direct productivity response

that one can begin to assess the welfare implications of these productive efficiencies.

Leibenstein (1966) observed that if productivity and competition are correlated, then the Econ

101 story of deadweight loss triangles may not be the most compelling reason to worry about fostering

robust competition. The first step towards turning that observation into policy prescription is to

understand the source of the correlation, a matter on which no consensus has been reached. The

evidence compiled here suggests that the way forward is to look within the firm at the organization

of production.

21

Table 2.1: Summary Statistics by CEA

1982 1987 1992

HHI (firms) 0.2869 0.2831 0.2739

(0.1947) (0.1898) (0.1817)

HHI (estab.) 0.2358 0.2450 0.2383

(0.1881) (0.1923) (0.1804)

no. ready-mix concrete estab. 14.9167 14.9856 14.6322

(14.8358) (15.7969) (15.5931)

no. ready-mix concrete firms 10.1700 11.2557 11.2040

(8.4732) (10.2049) (10.2581)

area 10805.9560 10805.9560 10805.9560

(33851.9390) (33851.0000) (33851.9390)

construction employment 2740.7902 3531.4943 3127.8764

(4197.1217) (5667.1252) (4748.9594)

residential building permits 2741.1925 4404.3937 3140.8736

(5597.7480) (7826.0237) (4482.5234)

single-family permits 1487.1523 2937.9368 2611.5862

(2703.0781) (4893.4924) (3863.4182)

5+ family permits 1012.2615 1209.9914 397.6552

(2921.0631) (3003.9534) (686.7842)

local highway and road spending 41425.4570 59956.4170 77196.7130

(61114.3630) (95423.6860) (124830.3000)

Table 2.2: OLS Results

firm-level competition index estab.-level competition index

no. firms HHI-firms no. estab. HHI-estab.

const. -1.9043*** -2.1300*** -1.9353*** -2.1321***

(0.0333) (0.0094) (0.0299) (0.0090)

βOLS 0.0392*** -0.1002** 0.0362*** -0.1193***

(0.0054) (0.0407) (0.0051) (0.0440)

N 8829 8829 8829 8829

R2 0.0167 0.0021 0.0147 0.0024

Regressions of ωit on each of the four competition index variables separately.

22

Tab

le2.3

:In

stru

men

tal

Vari

ab

les

Res

ult

s

firm

-lev

elco

mp

etit

ion

ind

exes

tab

.-le

vel

com

pet

itio

nin

dex

c m(i

)tnu

mb

erof

firm

sH

HI-

firm

snu

mb

erof

esta

b.

HH

I-es

tab

.

inst

rum

ents

lagg

edco

nte

mp

orar

yla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ry

mod

el(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)

con

st.

-1.7

837*

**-1

.770

3***

-1.9

261***

-1.7

548***

-1.8

142***

-1.8

191***

-1.9

643***

-1.9

183***

(0.0

398)

(0.0

429)

(0.0

346)

(0.0

776)

(0.0

346)

(0.0

364)

(0.0

229)

(0.0

375)

βIV

0.05

06**

*0.

0625

***

-0.9

231***

-2.1

304***

0.0

479***

0.0

576***

-0.9

263***

-1.6

077***

(0.0

064)

(0.0

068)

(0.2

002)

(0.4

283)

(0.0

059)

(0.0

061)

(0.1

755)

(0.2

760)

N57

7185

215771

8521

5771

8521

5771

8521

firs

t-st

age

F-t

est

188.

0519

9.41

3.0

81.7

0238.9

3245.5

13.7

92.4

8

IVre

gres

sion

sofωit

onco

mp

etit

ion

ind

exva

riab

les

usi

ng

the

foll

owin

gin

stu

men

ts,

eith

erla

gged

or

conte

mp

ora

ry:

gen

eral

con

stru

ctio

nem

plo

ym

ent,

resi

den

tial

bu

ild

ing

per

mit

s,si

ngle

-fam

ily

resi

den

ceb

uil

din

gp

erm

its,

5+

fam

ily

resi

den

cebu

ild

ing

per

mit

s,an

dlo

cal

gov

ern

men

th

ighw

ayex

pen

dit

ure

s,al

lp

ersq

uar

em

ile.

Th

efi

rst-

stage

F-t

est

isfr

om

ase

para

te,

CE

A-l

evel

regre

ssio

nof

the

com

pet

itio

nin

dex

on

inst

rum

ents

.

23

Tab

le2.4

:D

ecil

eE

ffec

ts(β

(k)

d)

mod

el1st

2nd

3rd

4th

5th

6th

7th

8th

9th

(1)

0.05

39**

*0.

0566

***

0.0

543***

0.0

540***

0.0

494***

0.0

478***

0.0473***

0.0

531***

0.0

712***

(0.0

109)

(0.0

096)

(0.0

092)

(0.0

076)

(0.0

074)

(0.0

078)

(0.0

091)

(0.0

107)

(0.0

139)

(2)

0.05

29**

*0.

0622

***

0.0

619***

0.0

589***

0.0

519***

0.0

444***

0.0426***

0.0

509***

0.0

631***

(0.0

092)

(0.0

088)

(0.0

085)

(0.0

067)

(0.0

067)

(0.0

071)

(0.0

076)

(0.0

087)

(0.0

114)

(3)

0.03

53-0

.424

3-0

.4610*

-0.4

641*

-0.5

836**

-0.5

793**

-0.5

291**

-0.7

889**

-1.4

635**

(0.2

799)

(0.2

691)

(0.2

524)

(0.2

376)

(0.2

387)

(0.2

409)

(0.2

685)

(0.3

032)

(0.4

293)

(4)

-2.1

660*

*-2

.345

3**

-2.2

692***

-2.3

225***

-2.0

275***

-1.7

842***

-1.7

392***

-1.8

826***

-2.3

333***

(0.9

798)

(0.9

584)

(0.8

805)

(0.8

757)

(0.7

603)

(0.6

855)

(0.6

680)

(0.6

800)

(0.7

788)

(5)

0.05

25**

*0.

0548

***

0.0

524***

0.0

524***

0.0

482***

0.0

467***

0.0459***

0.0

517***

0.0

698***

(0.0

108)

(0.0

093)

(0.0

088)

(0.0

073)

(0.0

071)

(0.0

075)

(0.0

088)

(0.0

103)

(0.0

133)

(6)

0.05

03**

*0.

0587

***

0.0

583***

0.0

563***

0.0

490***

0.0

416***

0.0409***

0.0

484***

0.0

589***

(0.0

091)

(0.0

085)

(0.0

082)

(0.0

065)

(0.0

064)

(0.0

068)

(0.0

074)

(0.0

084)

(0.0

109)

(7)

-0.0

630

-0.5

096*

-0.5

560**

-0.5

698**

-0.6

689***

-0.6

813***

-0.6

318**

-0.8

702***

-1.5

342***

(0.2

697)

(0.2

620)

(0.2

419)

(0.2

330)

(0.2

315)

(0.2

391)

(0.2

645)

(0.2

924)

(0.4

081)

(8)

-1.5

186*

*-1

.594

7***

-1.5

411***

-1.5

172***

-1.2

423***

-1.0

709***

-1.1

209***

-1.3

330***

-1.7

023

(0.6

550)

(0.5

919)

(0.5

317)

(0.4

992)

(0.4

085)

(0.3

758)

(0.3

978)

(0.4

319)

(0.4

991)

Res

ult

sfr

omC

EA

-lev

elin

stru

men

tal

vari

able

sre

gre

ssio

ns

wh

ere

the

dep

end

ent

vari

ab

leis

then

thd

ecil

eof

the

dis

trib

uti

on

ofωit

by

CE

A.

Th

em

od

els,

ind

exed

from

1to

8,co

rres

pon

dto

thos

ein

Tab

le2.3

:1-4

use

firm

-lev

elco

mp

etit

ion

ind

exes

,an

d5-8

use

esta

bli

shm

ent-

leve

l.1-2

an

d5-6

use

the

cou

nt

ind

exof

com

pet

itio

n,

wh

erea

s3-

4an

d7-8

use

HH

I.F

inall

y,od

d-n

um

ber

edm

od

els

use

lagged

vari

ab

les,

wh

erea

sev

en-n

um

ber

edon

esu

seco

nte

mp

orar

y.T

he

resu

lts

of

this

tab

leare

dep

icte

dgra

ph

icall

yin

Fig

ure

s2.6

-2.9

.

24

Tab

le2.5

:In

stru

men

tal

Vari

able

sw

ith

Sel

ecti

on

Corr

ecti

on

Res

ult

s

firm

-lev

elco

mp

etit

ion

ind

exes

tab

.-le

vel

com

pet

itio

nin

dex

c m(i

)tnu

mb

erof

firm

sH

HI-

firm

snu

mb

erof

esta

b.

HH

I-es

tab

.

inst

rum

ents

lagg

edco

nte

mp

orar

yla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ry

mod

el(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)

con

st.

-3.2

914*

**-0

.444

8*1.3

591**

-0.1

113

0.5

798

-0.5

795**

0.7

297

0.5

465

(0.3

548)

(0.2

575)

(0.6

670)

(0.3

860)

(0.4

866)

(0.2

478)

(0.5

162)

(0.6

295)

βX

0.04

24**

*0.

0461

***

-0.6

955***

-1.1

115***

0.0

397***

0.0

461***

-0.7

231***

-1.0

628***

(0.0

092)

(0.0

079)

(0.2

441)

(0.1

755)

(0.0

080)

(0.0

074)

(0.1

958)

(0.1

722)

N36

0035

133600

3513

3600

3513

3600

3513

con

st.

-1.7

837*

**-1

.770

3***

-1.9

261***

-1.7

548***

-1.8

142***

-1.8

191***

-1.9

643***

-1.9

183***

(0.0

398)

(0.0

429)

(0.0

346)

(0.0

776)

(0.0

346)

(0.0

364)

(0.0

229)

(0.0

375)

βDS

0.00

820.

0163

**-0

.2276

-1.0

189**

0.0

082

0.0114*

-0.2

032

-0.5

449*

(0.0

064)

(0.0

068)

(0.2

002)

(0.4

283)

(0.0

059)

(0.0

061)

(0.1

755)

(0.2

760)

N57

7185

215771

8521

5771

8521

5771

8521

Th

isp

anel

dep

icts

two

sets

ofre

sult

sfo

rea

chm

od

el.

Th

efi

rst

ob

tainβX

from

the

sele

ctio

nco

rrec

tion

pro

ced

ure

wh

ich

contr

ols

non

para

met

rica

lly

forφit−

1.

Th

ese

con

dse

tof

resu

lts

obta

inβDS

by

an

inst

rum

enta

lva

riab

les

regre

ssio

nof

the

imp

lied

φit

on

com

pet

itio

nin

dex

es.

25

Tab

le2.6

:C

om

pari

son

of

Res

ult

s

firm

-lev

elco

mp

etit

ion

ind

exes

tab

.-le

vel

com

pet

itio

nin

dex

c m(i

)tnu

mb

erof

firm

sH

HI-

firm

snu

mb

erof

esta

b.

HH

I-es

tab

.

inst

rum

ents

lagg

edco

nte

mp

orar

yla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ryla

gged

conte

mp

ora

ry

mod

el(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)

βIV

0.05

06**

*0.

0625

***

-0.9

231***

-2.1

304***

0.0

479***

0.0

576***

-0.9

263***

-1.6

077***

(0.0

064)

(0.0

068)

(0.2

002)

(0.4

283)

(0.0

059)

(0.0

061)

(0.1

755)

(0.2

760)

βX

0.04

24**

*0.

0461

***

-0.6

955***

-1.1

115***

0.0

397***

0.0

461***

-0.7

231***

-1.0

628***

(0.0

092)

(0.0

079)

(0.2

441)

(0.1

755)

(0.0

080)

(0.0

074)

(0.1

958)

(0.1

722)

βDS

0.00

820.

0163

**-0

.2276

-1.0

189**

0.0

082

0.0114*

-0.2

032

-0.5

449*

(0.0

064)

(0.0

068)

(0.2

002)

(0.4

283)

(0.0

059)

(0.0

061)

(0.1

755)

(0.2

760)

Su

mm

ary

ofre

sult

sfr

omT

able

s2.

3an

d2.

5.T

his

tab

lep

rese

nts

for

dir

ect

com

pari

son

the

dec

om

posi

tion

of

the

IVes

tim

ato

rin

toX

-in

effici

ency

an

dd

yn

am

icse

lect

ion

com

pon

ents

.

26

Fig

ure

2.1

:C

ou

nty

Map

of

the

US

A

27

Fig

ure

2.2

:C

EA

Map

of

the

US

A

28

Figure 2.3: Allocative vs. Productive Efficiencies

Comparison of allocative and productive efficiencies from comparable changes in price and cost,respectively. Deadweight loss, the allocative inefficiency, is represented by the shaded triangle.

Productive efficiencies are represented by the much larger shaded rectangle.

29

Figure 2.4: Value Function Response to Change in Market Size.

(a)

(b)

(c)

30

Figure 2.5: Predicted effect of two narratives on productivity residual distribution.

(a) X-Inefficiency

(b) Dynamic Selection

31

Figure 2.6: Effect of the number of ready-mix concrete firms on deciles of the productivity residualdistribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (1) and (2).

(a) instruments: lagged

(b) instruments: contemporary

32

Figure 2.7: Effect of HHI (calculated using firms) on deciles of the productivity residual distributionby CEA. Corresponds to models (3) and (4).

(a) instruments: lagged

(b) instruments: contemporary

33

Figure 2.8: Effect of the number of ready-mix concrete establishments on deciles of the productivityresidual distribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (5) and (6).

(a) instruments: lagged

(b) instruments: contemporary

34

Figure 2.9: Effect of HHI (calculated using establishments) on deciles of the productivity residualdistribution by CEA. Corresponds to models (7) and (8).

(a) instruments: lagged

(b) instruments: contemporary

35

Table 2.7: Probit Results

firm-level competition index estab.-level competition index

no. firms HHI-firms no. estab. HHI-estab.

constant 0.9993*** 0.9900*** 0.9821*** 0.9631***

(0.1910) (0.1740) (0.1858) (0.1640)

cm(i)t 0.0170 -0.5981 0.0143 -0.6321

(0.0197) (0.5460) (0.0190) (0.5238)

ωit 0.3131*** 0.3069*** 0.3151*** 0.3061***

(0.0590) (0.0599) (0.0590) (0.0598)

K (structures) 0.0169 0.0166 0.0165 0.0158

(0.0250) (0.0250) (0.0250) (0.0250)

K (equipment) 0.1179*** 0.1164*** 0.1185*** 0.1182***

(0.0234) (0.0235) (0.0234) (0.0234)

age -0.0219*** -0.0223*** -0.0218*** -0.0220***

(0.0032) (0.0032) (0.0032) (0.0032)

Results from instrumental variables probit regressions of survival dummies (χt = 1 iff the firm ispresent at time t+ 1) on firm observables. The competition index cm(i)t is defined by the model.Capital is observed in two forms in the Census of Manufactures data, structures (e.g., buildings)

and equipment (e.g., ready-mix concrete trucks). Age is constructed from the LBD. Allinstruments are contemporary.

36

CHAPTER III

General Comparative Statics for Industry Dynamics inLong-Run Equilibrium

3.1 Introduction

When claims are made about long-run supply, barriers to entry, or the decision to close down

a plant, some notion of industry dynamics is usually implicit in the motivation. However, the

formalization of that motivation often relies on static, two-stage, or highly parameterized models,

due in large part to the intractability and nonlinearity of dynamic models. This paper builds on

the framework of Hopenhayn (1992a) to show that comparative statics results can be obtained in a

general industry dynamics model from a set of intuitive and economically meaningful assumptions.

The results offer new intuition for why industry groups lobby for strict licensing requirements, both

the transience and high quality of New York restaurants, and why there is little turnover in industries

with high sunk costs.

A surprising and salient feature of micro production data is the persistence of productivity

differences among firms, even in seemingly narrow and homogeneous industries. Matching this

heterogeneity was an important hurdle for the early industry dynamics literature. The critical

innovation which permits of modeling heterogeneity in equilibrium is the introduction of firm-level

idiosyncratic shocks, an idea which traces its roots to Alchian (1950). Lippman and Rumelt (1982)

formalizes Alchian’s argument for luck as “uncertain imitability,” presaging two important features of

the literature to come: free entry by an unlimited pool of ex-ante identical competitors and rational

behavior by participants conditional on their idiosyncratic type. The seminal paper, Hopenhayn

(1992a), extends that model to an infinitely repeated game with Markov idiosyncratic types and

demonstrates the existence of an equilibrium with an ergodic distribution of types that sustains

heterogeneity.

One of the great challenges of this literature is obtaining comparative statics. A change in market

37

fundamentals changes firm payoffs and subsequently entry and exit, which in turn affects the ergodic

distribution of active types. Because the usual objects of interest (e.g., average type) are functionals

of that ergodic distribution, it is inherently difficult to relate them back to market fundamentals.

Though a handful of comparative static results are obtained in Hopenhayn (1992a) and Hopenhayn

(1992b), the assumptions required aree restrictive and the proofs are difficult.

Insofar as Hopenhayn (1992a) found great success as a general modeling framework and limited

power as a predictive engine, Melitz (2003) paved the way for a literature with the opposite strengths.

By imposing strong parametric structure on the problem, this literature was able to obtain closed-

form analytic solutions for a broad set of comparative statics and further, a model with which to

analyze trade liberalization from an industry dynamics perspective.

This paper will vindicate a number of those comparative statics, in particular those with respect

to market size, and demonstrate the generality of the economic logic which underlies them. Section

2 develops the formal model; Section 3 formalizes the idea of competitive stationary equilibrium and

proves existence and uniqueness; Section 4 develops the comparative statics of interest, and Section

5 concludes.

3.2 Model

This section elaborates a model of industry dynamics with heterogeneous firms and endogenous

entry and exit. All firms are endowed with an idiosyncratic type, which can be interpreted as pro-

ductivity or cost advantages that are unique to the firm and not purchased as a factor of production.

Firms pay a fixed cost of entry to learn their initial type and participate in the market. These id-

iosyncratic types evolve over time, and every period firms compete in the marketplace to generate

profits which depend on their type, the types of other competing firms, and exogenous market fun-

damentals. Every period firms also decide whether to exit the market. Combined, these entry and

exit decisions imply an endogenous transition dynamic for the set of active firms’ types. The object

of this model is to show transparently how the steady state of that transition dynamic depends on

the exogenous parameters of profit function and the entry cost.

3.2.1 Idiosyncratic Types

Every firm is endowed with an idiosyncratic type ϕ which is assumed to lie in [0, 1]. Firms are

atomless; at any period t, there is some mass Mt ∈ R+ of firms that are active in the market. Let µt

be a continuous probability density with support [0, 1] which represents the density of active firms’

38

types. Next, let µt ≡Mt · µt; this is the measure of active firms’ types. It captures both the extent

and the character of competition.

Idiosyncratic types are not fixed; every period they evolve as a Markov process according to

F (ϕ′|ϕ). The following assumption is made on that transition rule:

Assumption 1. F (ϕ′|ϕ) is a continuous distribution with following properties:

(a) F has full support on [0, 1] for any ϕ.

(b) F is increasing in ϕ in the sense of first-order stochastic dominance.

The terms “increasing” and “decreasing” are meant weakly in all of what follows unless otherwise

noted. Continuity and full support are technical conveniences, but part (b) carries some economic

intuition. If ϕ is interpreted as productivity, this condition implies serial correlation in idiosyncratic

productivity levels, an stylized fact from the empirical literature on plant-level productivity.

3.2.2 Stage Game

Firms compete to generate profits every period. This model is agnostic about the form of that

competition. Instead, π(ϕ, µ;D) is used to represent the outcome, which is allowed to depend on

firm type ϕ; the measure of competing firms’ types µ, and an exogenous profitability shifter D.

The parameter D is treated as exogenous and fixed, and therefore has no import for considerations

of existence or uniqueness. It is discussed at length in the section on comparative statics. Firms

discount future stage game profits according to a common discount rate β.

Assumption 2. The stage-game profit function π(ϕ, µ;D) is a bounded and continuous function

with the following properties:

(a) π is strictly increasing in ϕ.

(b) π is decreasing in µ with respect to an ordering ≺ that has the following properties:

• ≺ is a complete ordering on the set of bounded continuous functions over the range [0, 1].

• For two distributions µ1 and µ2, with µ2(A) > µ1(A) for some open set A ⊆ [0, 1] and

µ2 ≥ µ1 elsewhere, µ1 ≺ µ2.

(c) For any D, ∃ µ such that ∀ϕ, π(ϕ, µ;D) < 0 as well as a µ′ ≺ µ such that ∀ϕ, π(ϕ, µ′, D) > 0.

Assumption 2 imposes structure on the stage-game profit function. Part (a) is a monotonicity

condition, consistent with the interpretation of type as productivity, costs, or quality. The second

39

restriction (b) imposes a complete order on measures µ. That π is decreasing with respect to a

common ordering ≺ can be interpreted as meaning that firms of all types agree on what constitutes

a more or less competitive market. This rules out most forms of horizontal competition. While ≺

is left mostly unspecified, (b) imposes that adding more competing firms always reduces profits.1

Finally, (c) will be useful for guaranteeing the existence of an interior solution.

Remark

The fact that ≺ is a complete ordering on the set of bounded, continuous functions over [0, 1]

implies that there is a function C(µ) which maps into [0, 1] such that π(ϕ, µ;D) > π(ϕ, µ′;D) ⇒

C(µ) < C(µ′). This function C can be thought of as a theoretical counterpart to competition indexes

such as Herfindal-Hirschman Index and the CRn.

3.2.3 Entry and Exit

There is an unlimited pool of ex-ante identical entrants, who each period choose to either enter

the market or not. Entrants pay a fixed cost cf and learn their initial type ϕ, which is drawn from

F (ϕ|ϕE). The term ϕE is a fixed, exogenous parameter of the model which affects the quality of

new entrants. Let λt denote the endogenous mass of entrants.

The assumption that there is an infinite supply of entrants is important for the comparative

statics and has some bite: for instance, it may be inappropriate to assume that there is an unlimited

pool of firms who could produce high-end computer chips. It may also be implausible in some

markets to assume that, as more and more firms enter, the type of the marginal firm is drawn from

the same distribution as early entrants (i.e., that ϕE does not depend on µt). The importance of

the entry process for proving the results that follow is discussed further in the conclusion.

At the end of each period, firms make an exit choice. Let Xt(ϕ) : [0, 1]→ 0, 1 be the exit rule

at t, with 0 representing exit and 1 representing continued participation in the market2. Exiting

firms receive a payoff normalized to 0.

3.2.4 Timing and Dynamics

The model described above differs somewhat from the literature in the assumption that exit

happens at the end of each period, rather than immediately after entry. To summarize the structure

of each time period:

1This is a standard assumption used by both Hopenhayn (1992a) and Asplund and Nocke (2006).2Xt(ϕ) will be assumed integrable for now, and shown later to take the form of a threshold rule in equilibrium.

40

entry → stage game → exit → types evolve

Intuitively, this is consistent with the idea that firms learn their productivity types by producing

rather than by introspection. This structure has implications for empirical work because the stage

game is the point at which data is generated; see Backus (2011) for more discussion on this point.

The results here are more elegant thanks to, but do not depend on the timing of exit. Note that µt

evolves at several points within each period, therefore it is important to note that by µt this paper

will refer to the measure of types during the stage game.

The timing assumptions above, an entry rate λt+1 and an exit rule Xt(ϕ) together define a law

of motion for µ:

(3.1) µt+1([0, ϕ′]) =

∫ ϕ′

0

∫ 1

0

F (ϕ′|ϕ)Xt(ϕ)dµt(ϕ) + λt+1F (ϕ′|ϕE)

The first term on the right is the measure of incumbents from period t, while the second is

the measure of new entrants at t + 1. Note that despite the introduction of stochastic firm-level

innovations in productivity types, the law of motion for µ is deterministic. This follows from the

decision to model firms as atomless, so that the variance in the realization of their productivity

shocks washes out in the aggregate.

The model specified in this section can be fully characterized by the following set of elements:

π, F,D, cf , ϕE. Given an initial measure µ0 and a strategy profile λt, Xt(ϕ, µt;D), the evolution

of the industry is deterministic. As discussed below in section 3, attention will be restricted to

stationary strategies and a unique ergodic µ, so that the need to specify an initial measure µ0 is

obviated.

3.3 Equilibrium

The value function of the firm may be defined recursively by:

(3.2) vt(ϕ, µt, D) = π(ϕ, µt, D) + max0, β∫vt+1(ϕ′, µt+1, D)dF (ϕ′|ϕ)

Standard dynamic programming arguments demonstrate that firms’ exit strategies can be sum-

marized by a threshold rule, which is denoted by x∗t . All firms with ϕ < x∗t exit the market, and

41

firms of type x∗t are just indifferent:

(3.3)

∫vt(ϕ

′, µt+1, D)dF (ϕ′|x∗t ) = 0

There is also an unlimited pool of potential entrants who have the option to pay a fixed cost cf

to enter and draw iid types from F (ϕ|ϕE). Each period, a mass of firms λt ≥ 0 enter such that

either λt = 0 or the expected value of entry is zero:

(3.4)

∫vt(ϕ, µt, D)dF (ϕ|ϕE)− cf = 0

Given λt+1 and x∗t , the law of motion (3.1) can be simplified:

(3.1’) µt+1([0, ϕ′]) =

∫ 1

x∗t

F (ϕ′|ϕ)dµt(ϕ) + λt+1F (ϕ′|ϕE)

The first integral in (3.1’) is comprised of firms with ϕ > x∗ in period t and the latter, a mass

λt+1 of entrants. Recall that while firms face uncertainty via innovations in idiosyncratic type,

they are atomless and there are no industry-level shocks; therefore dynamics in the aggregate are

deterministic.

Attention is restricted to equilibria in stationary strategies, which will imply an ergodic distri-

bution; a fixed point of 3.1’. In this sense the solution concept characterizes industry dynamics

in long-run equilibrium, and for this reason time subscripts will henceforth be dropped. Moreover,

define:

(3.5) Ψ(ϕ) ≡∫v(ϕ′, µ;D)dF (ϕ′|ϕ)

Intuitively, Ψ(ϕ) is the continuation value of a firm of type ϕ today. βΨ(ϕ) is the relevant

expected payoff for firms deciding whether to exit the market; similarly, Ψ(ϕE) is the expected

payoff to entry. These expressions are useful for characterizing the equilibrium conditions.

A stationary competitive equilibrium of this game is a triple < µ, x∗, λ > such that:

42

1. The measure of active types is self-generating in the sense of (3.1’), so that:

(E1) µ([0, ϕ′]) =

∫ 1

x∗F (ϕ′|ϕ)dµ(ϕ) + λF (ϕ′|ϕE)

2. The marginal incumbent is indifferent:

(E2) Ψ(x∗) = 0

3. The expected value of entry is zero:

(E3) Ψ(ϕE) = cf

The first condition implies stationarity in a strong sense, which obtains from the absence of

market-level shocks. The second implies an optimal exit rule: firms exit if their expected profits are

negative. Finally, the third equilibrium condition requires that the per-period mass of entrants λ is

sufficient to guarantee zero expected profits on entry.

Proposition 1. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: For cf not too large, there exists a at least one equilibrium

with λ > 0.

Proof. See Appendix.

It is a testament to the creativity of that original paper that the proof extends to the imperfectly

competitive case. This is true because it does not rely at all on the perfectly competitive structure or

the price mechanisms in that model. In all of what follows, attention is restricted to the equilibrium

with λ > 0.

Proposition 2. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: The equilibrium of the above game is unique.

Proof of Proposition 2: Suppose by way of contradiction, that there are two distinct equilibria

< µ1, x∗1, λ1 > and < µ2, x

∗2, λ2 >. Suppose µ1 ∼ µ2. Then E2 implies x∗1 = x∗2, which implies

λ1 = λ2. Suppose instead and without loss of generality µ1 ≺ µ2. Then E2 implies x∗1 < x∗2.

However, this yields Ψ1(ϕE) > Ψ2(ϕE), which contradicts E3.

The proof here is rather different from that in Hopenhayn (1992a). In place of assumptions

on factor market prices or the production function, this paper follows Asplund and Nocke (2006)

in taking the more general approach of imposing a complete and common order on the space of

measures µ.

43

3.4 Comparative Statics

The practice of obtaining comparative statics from industry dynamics models is difficult because

the objects of interest are typically functionals of µ, the measure of active types in a stationary

competitive equilibrium. This depends in a non-transparent way on the fundamentals which affect

the rules of transition. In a general setting, it is not possible to obtain explicit solutions.

It is a bit counter-intuitive to talk of comparative statics in an industry dynamics model. The

thought experiment is not a shock to exogenous parameters; no impulse response functions are de-

rived here. Instead, the comparison is between two equilibria, each at their long-run stationary

state. Introducing market-level shocks would require additional assumptions on firms’ beliefs about

the evolution of idiosyncratic types. Simulating them would require significant parametric structure

on the evolution of those shocks and firm profits. Moving in this direction would obviate the primary

advantage of working with a continuum of firms; the ability to do analysis with general functions

because uncertainty washes out in the aggregate. The competing industry dynamics literature fol-

lowing Ericson and Pakes (1995), which works in a discrete environment that lends it to computation

and simulation, is well-suited to modeling short-run dynamics and market-level shocks.

Two comparative statics are derived here for two different exogenous variables. The two outcome

variables of interest are turnover and average type, and the two exogenous variables are fixed costs

of entry and market size. Formally, define the following measure of turnover:

(3.6) T ≡ λ∫µ(ϕ)dϕ

This index is meant to represent the rate of churning in the industry; it is the size of the entering

cohort (equal, by stationarity, to the size of the exiting cohort) relative to the mass of firms in the

industry. Next, define:

(3.7) ϕ ≡∫ϕµ(ϕ)dϕ∫µ(ϕ)dϕ

This term represents the average type in the market. No prior work has been done establishing

results for average type in the general industry dynamics framework. Existing results for average

type stem from the parametric literature following Melitz (2003), e.g., Melitz and Ottaviano (2008),

which address the question of whether average productivity responds to market size and extend that

44

logic to trade liberalization.

Deriving comparative statics for functionals of µ is made tractable by a convenient decomposition

of the ergodic measure proposed by Hopenhayn (1992a). Let µt be a measure over firm types that

have survived into their tth period of existence (e.g., µ1(ϕ) = f(ϕ|ϕE)). Formally, the series of

expressions µt(ϕ)t=1,... is written in terms of x∗ and primitives of the model:

µ1(ϕ) = f(ϕ|ϕE)

µ2(ϕ) =

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|ϕ1)f(ϕ1|ϕE)dϕ1

µk(ϕ) =

∫ 1

x∗· · ·∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|ϕk−1)f(ϕk−1|ϕk−2) · · · f(ϕ2|ϕ1)f(ϕ1|ϕE)d(ϕk−1) · · · dϕ1

The terms µt(ϕ) are measures with the following convenient property: they integrate to the proba-

bility of surviving t periods upon entry. Moreover, they comprise a decomposition of µ:

(3.8) µ = λ

∞∑k=1

µk

In equilibrium µ is completely determined by λ and x∗. This decomposition affords, in principle,

the opportunity to take derivatives of µ with respect to both of these objects.

3.4.1 Fixed Costs of Entry

A staple of the industry dynamics literature is to ask how fixed costs of entry affect market

outcomes. Under a somewhat stronger set of assumptions than those made here, Hopenhayn (1992a)

shows that x∗ is decreasing in cf .3 Propositions 3 and 4 should be thought of as generalizations of

that result to a weaker set of assumptions and a formalization of the implications for turnover and

average type.

Fixed costs of entry cf are incarnated in the real world as irrecoverable investments, such as

highly specific or immobile capital, franchising fees, or licensing fees. Industry groups have been a

powerful force in erecting barriers to entry, especially in the form of licensing fees. While this might

seem counterintuitive at first glance, Figure 3.2 offers some intuition: raising the fixed costs of entry

reduces pressure from entrants, weakening the distribution of competing firms’ types and increasing

3The assumption required is that the profit function is multiplicatively separable into two pars: a function of firms’idiosyncratic types, and a function of market aggregates. This assumption implies, but is not implied by, the existenceof a complete ordering ≺ from Assumption 2 above.

45

profits. The entire continuation value function Ψ(ϕ) shifts up with (ϕE , cf ); it is apparent that

incumbents are beneficiaries of the change.

Proposition 3. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: At the stationary competitive equilibrium, T is decreasing

in cf .

Proof. Lemma 8 of the Appendix demonstrates that T can be written as an increasing function of

x∗. Lemma 6 closes the argument by showing that x∗ is increasing in cf .

The measure of turnover T is normalized with respect to the size of the industry, so it is strictly

increasing in x∗, which determines the likelihood of exit F (x∗|ϕ) for a firm of type ϕ. That exit

threshold x∗ decreases as the entire curve Ψ(ϕ) shifts up; see Figure 3.2.

Proposition 4. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: At the stationary competitive equilibrium, ϕ is decreasing

in cf .

Proof. Lemma 9 of the Appendix demonstrates that ϕ can be written as an increasing function of

x∗. Lemma 6 closes the argument by showing that x∗ is increasing in cf .

As above, the intuition is that x∗ is decreasing because the entire curve Ψ(ϕ) is shifting up;

see Figure 3.2. Getting from there to a decrease in ϕ takes more work; the intuition is that more

low-type firms are sticking around and replacing entrants. Because those entrants have a higher

type on average than the marginal incumbent (see Lemma 3), this lowers average type.

3.4.2 Market Size

Market size in this model is represented by D, which enters the profit function directly. It is

important for the sake of generality to impose minimal parametric form on the way thatD affects firm

profits. Note that while D is construed here as market size, this is merely meant as an interpretive

justification for the set of assumptions which are imposed on the way it enters π. In general, D is a

profitability shifter, and could be used to analyze other exogenous changes, as for instance a change

in corporate tax rates.

Comparative statics with respect to market size are of central importance in recent applications

of industry dynamics because their logic underlies the argument for productivity gains from trade,

e.g. Melitz and Ottaviano (2008). Moreover, they are hard to obtain because the effect of market size

is prima fascia ambiguous. The direct effect of greater market size is to make firms of all types better

off; this should sustain low-type firms, lower x∗, and decrease average productivity and turnover.

46

Entry is the countervailing force. As market size makes all firms better off, more firms enter the

market, reducing profits. Without further structure, parametric or otherwise, it is impossible to sign

the effect.

Two additional assumptions are introduced to obtain comparative statics in D:

Assumption 3 (Competition Reallocates Profits). The stage-game profit function π(ϕ, µ;D) has

increasing differences in ϕ and µ.

This assumption means that competition tends to reallocate profits from low-type to high-type

firms. In this spirit Boone (2008) argues that relative profits between high- and low-type firms is in

fact a direct measure of competition, superior to conventional techniques such as HHI or the number

of firms.

Assumption 4. π(ϕ, µ;D) is continuous and strictly increasing in D and has increasing differences

in ϕ and D.

This assumption means that high-type firms benefit more from an increase in D than low-type

firms. It can be thought of as a restriction on the sorts of profitability shifters under consideration.

Under many models of competition, this is a reasonable property to impose on demand shifters.4

Both of the comparative statics expounded below are corollaries of the core result, stated and

proven as Lemma 7 of the Appendix, that x∗ is increasing in D. This non-obvious result implies that

an increase in D makes low-type firms relatively worse off, despite its direct and positive impact on

profits. The mechanism is that higher profits induce entry, which dominates the direct profit effect

on account of Assumptions 3 and 4, allowing one to sign the ambiguity discussed above. See Figure

3.3 for an illustration: at both levels of D the continuation value function must intersect (ϕE , cf );

the assumptions made imply that for larger markets, the function rotates counter-clockwise, raising

x∗.

This is an excellent example, in the spirit of Vives (2009), of a case where the monotone com-

parative statics properties of the stage game profit function do not carry over to the value function.

It is somewhat redemptive, therefore, that those properties are so critical in the argument for the

comparative statics.

4For intuition, consider Cournot competition between two firms with differing costs. Supposing an inverse demandfunction of the form p(Q) = A− bQ, the firms’ equilibrium profit function is

πi =1

9b(A+ cj − 2ci)

2

Here, increasing differences in A (standing in for D) and −ci (standing in for ϕ) is proven by the positive cross-partial:

∂2πi

∂A∂(−ci)=

4

9b

47

Proposition 5. Under Assumptions 1 - 4: At the stationary competitive equilibrium, T is increasing

in D.

Proof. Lemma 8 of the Appendix demonstrates that T can be written as an increasing function of

x∗. Lemma 7 closes the argument by showing that x∗ is increasing in D.

This proposition follows easily once it is shown that x∗ is increasing in D. Intuitively, a higher

cutoff threshold implies a higher fraction of active firms exiting the market. The result is likely to

resound with those familiar with the transience of New York restaurants.

Proposition 6. Under Assumptions 1 - 4: At the stationary competitive equilibrium, ϕ is nonde-

creasing in D.

Proof. Lemma 9 of the Appendix demonstrates that ϕ can be written as an increasing function of

x∗. Lemma 7 closes the argument by showing that x∗ is increasing in D.

That ϕ increases with x∗ is somewhat less transparent, because more turnover means relatively

more draws from F (ϕ|ϕE), which does not obviously improve productivity. This is addressed by

Lemma 3 of the appendix, which shows that x∗ is always lower than ϕE , so that new entrants always

dominate firms on the margin of exit in type. This result is likely to resound with those familiar

with the quality of New York restaurants.

3.5 Conclusion

Industry dynamics models are enjoying more attention than ever, thanks to the success of the

international trade literature in applying parametric variations to match empirical stylized facts

and bolster the argument for gains from trade. This paper vindicates a number of those results by

demonstrating that the economic logic of the argument does not depend on CES utility functions

or monopolistic competition, but instead a basic economic assumption that increases in market

competitiveness reallocate profits from less to more productive firms.

There are still a number of important assumptions of the Hopenhayn (1992a) framework to

weaken. All of the proofs in this paper take advantage of the construction of idiosyncratic firm type

as being one-dimensional. This has the very convenient implication that for the unique equilibria

of any two distinct parameterizations of the model, there is an explicit ranking by x∗. Therefore

the set of survivors in one equilibrium is always either a strict subset or a strict superset of those in

another equilibrium. This would not be true if the threshold rule were a frontier in multidimensional

48

space. It is easy to imagine that a change in the exogenous parameters could generate a survival rule

which is weaker on one dimension but stronger on another, which would make proving comparative

statics very difficult. The construction of entry - in particular that there is an infinite pool of ex-ante

identical entrants - is also restrictive. It is not difficult to imagine industries, especially high-tech

industries, where this would not be true. Moreover, it is easy to reverse some of the results with

alternative entry models. For instance, if there is a fixed distribution of entrants who know their type

prior to entry, then larger market size would simply induce entry by lower-type firms, decreasing

average type.

These limitations aside, the results here demonstrate that there is a common economic logic

underlying the parameterizations of industry dynamics models that have been used to such great

success in understanding plant-level data by IO and trade economists. The contribution of this

paper is to make that logic explicit in the hope and expectation that it will yield still more testable

predictions in a wider set of markets and environments.

3.6 Appendix

Lemma 1. For F (ϕ′|ϕ) on [0, 1] stochastically increasing in ϕ: if γ(ϕ,D) has increasing differences

in D and ϕ, so too does Γ(ϕ,D) ≡∫ 1

0γ(ϕ′, D)dF (ϕ′|ϕ).

Proof: This is a special case of Theorem 2 from Athey (2000). For an intuitive proof, consider the

following: Without loss of generality, let D1 < D2. It suffices to show that the following expression

is nondecreasing:

Γ(ϕ,D2)− Γ(ϕ,D1) =

∫ 1

0

[γ(ϕ′, D1)− γ(ϕ′, D2)] dF (ϕ′|ϕ)

Note that the expression in brackets is nondecreasing because v(ϕ,D) has increasing differences in

D and ϕ. Therefore, recalling that F (ϕ′|ϕ) is stochastically nondecreasing in ϕ, it must be that the

expectation of the difference is increasing in ϕ.

Lemma 2. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: The value function v(ϕ, µ,D) is strictly increasing in D and

ϕ, and strictly decreasing in µ.

Proof: That v is strictly increasing in D and ϕ, and decreasing in µ follows from standard results,

see SLP. That v is strictly decreasing in µ is implied by the full support condition of Assumption

1: π(ϕ, µ;D) is strictly decreasing in µ for some open set in [0, 1], and that set is in the support of

F (ϕ′|ϕ) for any ϕ.

49

Lemma 3. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: In any equilibrium with nonzero entry, x∗ < ϕE.

Proof. Combining equilibrium conditions 2 and 3, we have:

∫v(ϕ′, µ,D)dF (ϕ′|ϕE) = cf

>

∫v(ϕ′, µ,D)dF (ϕ′|x∗)

Because v is increasing in its first argument by Lemma 2 and F (ϕ′|ϕ) is stochastically increasing in

ϕ, it must be that ϕE > ϕ∗.

Lemma 4. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: For two equilibria with D1 < D2, then µ1 µ2.

Proof: Suppose by way of contradiction that µ2 ≺ µ1. Then,

0 =

∫v(ϕ, µ1, D1)dF (ϕ|ϕE)− cf

<

∫v(ϕ, µ2, D2)dF (ϕ|ϕE)− cf

= 0

The first and last equalities are based on equilibrium condition 3, the entry condition. The middle

inequality follows from D1 < D2, µ1 µ2, and Lemma 2. Combined, they imply a contradiction.

Lemma 5. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: Let π(ϕ,D) ≡ π(ϕ, µ(D), D), where µ(D) is the unique

equilibrium µ associated with D. Then π(ϕ,D) has increasing differences in ϕ and D.

Proof: Existence and uniqueness follow from Proposition 1. Complementarity of µ and D follows

from Lemma 4, so that Assumptions 3 and 4 implies increasing differences for π(ϕ,D).

Lemma 6. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: For two equilibria with cf1 < cf2 , it must be that x∗1 ≥ x∗2.

Proof: From the entry condition:

∫v(ϕ, µ1;D)dF (ϕ|ϕE)− cf2 < 0

Therefore µ1 ≺ µ2. Then from the exit condition:

∫v(ϕ, µ2;D)dF (ϕ|x∗1) ≥ 0

50

So that x∗2 ≤ x∗1, strictly if the above inequality is strict.

Lemma 7. Under Assumptions 1 - 4: For two equilibria with D1 < D2, it must be that x∗1 ≤ x∗2.

Proof: Suppose by way of contradiction that x∗2 < x∗1.

First, consider the following distortion of the value function mapping:5

S(z(ϕ,Di)) ≡

π(ϕ,D) + β

∫z(ϕ′, D)dF (ϕ′|ϕ) if ϕ ≥ x∗

π(ϕ,D) + β∫z(ϕ′, D)dF (ϕ′|x∗) else

Using Blackwell’s Sufficient Conditions it is straightforward to confirm that this is a contraction

mapping. Iterating Sn as n→∞, the contraction converges to v(ϕ,D) by the optimality of x∗: the

contraction mapping has a unique fixed point, and it is easy to check that S(v(ϕ,D)) = v(ϕ,D).

Any property that is preserved both by limits and the contraction mapping S must be true of

v(ϕ,D). Three important properties of v(ϕ,D) can be established on this basis:6

1. Monotonicity of v(ϕ,D) in ϕ: it is easy to see that if z(ϕ,D) is monotone increasing in ϕ, so

too is S(z(ϕ,D)).

2. Continuity of v(ϕ,D) in ϕ: This follows from continuity of π in ϕ. One might worry about

a jump discontinuity at x∗, but the normalization of the exit value guarantees continuity at

that point.

3. Increasing Differences: Let z be chosen from the set of functions satisfying monotonicity and

continuity as above. If z(ϕ,D) has increasing differences, then so too does S(z(ϕ,D)). To see

this, posit z(ϕ,D) with increasing differences. In a slight abuse of notation, let Tz(ϕ,D) be the

function S(z(ϕ,D)) evaluated at (ϕ,D). It remains to show that for ϕ1 ≤ ϕ2 and D1 ≤ D2,

(ID) Sz(ϕ2, D1)− Sz(ϕ1, D1) ≤ Sz(ϕ2, D2)− Sz(ϕ1, D2; )

The proof proceeds by dividing [0, 1] into three regions and showing that the above property

holds for any (ϕ1, ϕ2) drawn from the same region. It is closed by using continuity at the edges

of these regions to extend this argument to (ϕ1, ϕ2) pairs drawn from separate regions.

5The sense in which this is a distortion is that the payoff to exit is normalized to β∫z(ϕ′, D)dF (ϕ′|x∗), where x∗

is the true exit threshold at D. At the correct value function this term goes to zero, by equilibrium condition 2. Thereason this distortion is introduced is to generate continuity for any arbitrary z, which is explored below.

6Note that these properties are proven under the assumption, made by way of contradiction, that x∗2 < x∗1. Theseproperties are proven only for the sake of demonstrating a contradiction, and may not all hold at the true equilibrium.

51

(a) In the region [0, x∗2) :

Sz(ϕ,Di) = π(ϕ,Di) + β

∫z(ϕ′, Di)dF (ϕ′|x∗i )

ID holds by Lemma 5.

(b) In the region [x∗2, x∗1) :

Sz(ϕ,Di) =

π(ϕ,D1) + β

∫z(ϕ′, D1)dF (ϕ′|x∗1) for i = 1

π(ϕ,D2) + β∫z(ϕ′, D2)dF (ϕ′|ϕ) for i = 2

Therefore ID holds from ID of π in ϕ and D as well as the monotonicity of z.

(c) In the region [x∗1, 1] :

Sz(ϕ,Di) = π(ϕ,Di) + β

∫z(ϕ′, Di)dF (ϕ′|ϕ)

Using Lemmas 1 and 5, this is simply the sum of two functions with ID in ϕ and D, and

therefore ID holds for Sz.

Finally, consider (ϕ1, ϕ2) drawn from different regions. The concern here is that there may

be discontinuities, either in Sz(ϕ,D1) at x∗1 or in Sz(ϕ,D2) at x∗2. This is alleviated by the

normalization of the continuation value for β∫z(ϕ′, D)dF (ϕ′|x∗), so that limϕ→x∗ Sz(ϕ,D) =

Sz(x∗, D). Then ID across regions is implied by ID within. For intuition, consider x∗2 < ϕ1 <

x∗1 < ϕ2. ID requries:

Sz(ϕ2, D1)− Sz(x∗1, D1) + Sz(x∗1, D1)− Sz(ϕ1, D1)

≤ Sz(ϕ2, D2)− Sz(x∗1, D2) + Sz(x∗1, D2)− Sz(ϕ1, D2)

Continuity of Sz(ϕ,D) at x∗ implies that (a) is extended to [0, x∗2] and (b) is extended to

[x∗2, x∗1], so that ID here can be obtained by comparing the first two terms and the second two

terms on either side of the inequality independently. ID for these pairs implies ID of the sum.

Recall that E3 requires that Ψ1(ϕ) and Ψ2(ϕ) cross at (ϕE , cf ). However, Lemma 1 combined

with ID of v implies Ψi(ϕ) =∫

has increasing differences in ϕ and D. If x2 < x1, then Ψ(x∗1, D2) >

52

0 = Ψ(x∗1, D1), and increasing differences implies that the two functions never cross, generating a

contradiction.

Lemma 8. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: T is increasing in x∗.

Proof: Employing the decomposition of µ from equation (3.8):

T =λ∫

µ(ϕ)dϕ

=1∫ ∑∞

k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ

Fixing t,∫µt(ϕ)dϕ corresponds to the probability of surviving t periods conditional on entry, which

is trivially decreasing in x∗ (strictly for t ≥ 2).

Lemma 9. Under Assumptions 1 - 2: ϕ is increasing in x∗.

Proof: Using (3.8), ϕ can be rewritten:

(3.9) ϕ =

∫ϕ∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ∫ ∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ

Now,

(3.10)

∂ϕ

∂x∗=

∫ϕ∑∞k=1

∂∂x∗ µk(ϕ)dϕ ·

∫ ∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ−

∫ ∑∞k=1

∂∂x∗ µk(ϕ)dϕ ·

∫ϕ∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ

(∫

∂∂x∗

∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)dϕ)2

The denominator in (3.10) is trivially positive. In order to sign the numerator, one requires an

expression for the derivative of the sum over µk. To begin,

∂x∗µk(ϕ) = −f(ϕ|x∗)

∫ 1

x∗· · ·∫ 1

x∗f(x∗|ϕk−2) · · · f(ϕ2|ϕ1)f(ϕ1|ϕE)dϕk−2 · · · dϕ1

+

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|ϕk−1)

∂x∗

∫ 1

x∗· · ·∫ ∞x∗

f(ϕk−1|ϕk−2) · · · f(ϕ2|ϕ1)f(ϕ1|ϕE)dϕk−1 · · · dϕ1

= −f(ϕ|x∗)µk−1(x∗) +

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|ϕk−1)

∂x∗µk−1(ϕk−1)dϕk−1(3.11)

Summing over (3.11) and reorganizing yields:

53

∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ) = −f(ϕ|x∗)

∞∑k=2

µk−1(x∗) +

∞∑k=2

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|ϕk−1)

∂x∗µk−1(ϕk−1)dϕk−1

= −f(ϕ|x∗)∞∑k=1

µk(x∗) +

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|z) ∂

∂x∗

∞∑k=1

µk(z)dz(3.12)

Next, substitute in the left-hand side to solve the expression recursively.

(3.13)

∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ) = −

∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)

[f(ϕ|x∗) +

∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|z1)f(z1|x∗)dz1 + . . .

]

Define ξ(ϕ) ≡∑∞k=1 ξk(ϕ) and ξk(ϕ) ≡

∫ 1

x∗· · ·∫ 1

x∗f(ϕ|zk−1) · · · f(z2|z1)f(z1|x∗)dzk−1 · · · dz1

with ξ1(ϕ) = f(ϕ|x∗). Intuitively, ξk is the distribution of types for a firm that is observed k

periods after having type x∗. This notation affords the following simplification:

∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ) = −

∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)

∞∑k=1

ξk(ϕ)

= −∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)ξ(ϕ)(3.14)

Using (3.14) one can revisit the numerator in (3.10):

∫ϕ

∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ)dϕ ·

∫ ∞∑k=1

µk(ϕ)dϕ−∫ ∞∑

k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ)dϕ ·

∫ϕ

∞∑k=1

µk(ϕ)dϕ

=

∫ϕ

( ∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ϕ)

∫ ∞∑k=1

µk(ζ)dζ −∞∑k=1

µk(ϕ)

∫ ∞∑k=1

∂x∗µk(ζ)dζ

)dϕ

=

∫ϕ

(−∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)ξ(ϕ)

∫ ∞∑k=1

µk(ζ)dζ +

∞∑k=1

µk(ϕ)

∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)

∫ξ(ζ)dζ

)dϕ

=

[ ∞∑k=1

µk(x∗)

∫ ∞∑k=1

µk(ζ)dζ

∫ξ(ζ)dζ

]∫ϕ

( ∑∞k=1 µk(ϕ)∫ ∑∞k=1 µk(ζ)dζ

− ξ(ϕ)∫ξ(ζ)dζ

)dϕ(3.15)

The term in brackets is trivially positive. The difference integrated in the second term is positive

because the first distribution first-order stochastically dominates the second, as implied by Lemma

3.

54

0 1

y(f)

cf

fE

fx*

Figure 3.1: Industry in Equilibrium: Recall Ψ(ϕ) =∫v(ϕ′, µ;D)dF (ϕ′|ϕ) is the continuation value

for a firm of type ϕ today. Condition E2 requires that Ψ(ϕ) pass through the point (ϕE ,cF ), whilecondition E3 gives x∗ at the Y-intercept of the function.

55

0 1

y(f)

cf1

fE

fx1*

cf2

x2*

y1(f)

y2(f)

Figure 3.2: Decrease in Entry Costs: Let cf1 > cf2 . The reduction spurs entry, which drives profitsdown for all types. The new continuation value function Ψ2(ϕ) is smaller than Ψ1(ϕ), and valuedcf2 at ϕE . The exit threshold x∗ rises, spurring higher turnover and average type.

56

0 1

y(f)

cf

fE

fx1* x2*

y1(f)

y2(f)

Figure 3.3: Increase in Market Size: Let D1 < D2. The increase in demand raises profits, inparticular for higher types. The higher profits spur entry, in turn reducing profits, especially forlower types. Combined, these countervailing effects push Ψ2(ϕ) counterclockwise around the originalΨ1(ϕ), pivoting around (ϕE , cf ).

57

CHAPTER IV

An Estimable Demand System for a Large Auction PlatformMarket (with Gregory Lewis)

4.1 Introduction

Most goods and services are sold at fixed prices. Yet auctions are used as the allocation mech-

anism in a wide variety of contexts, including procurement and the granting of oil drilling and

spectrum rights. Online auction platforms, in particular, have grown substantially in recent years.

In retail eBay alone has revenues of $36 billion from its auctions business in 20071, while Google

realized $21 billion in revenue from its online advertising platform in 20082. More specialized auction

sites such as DoveBid and IronPlanet have sold billions of dollars of used aviation and construction

equipment respectively.

Given their importance in the modern economy, one would like to be able to estimate demand in

these platform markets. This would allow us to answer questions of broad economic interest, such

as how much welfare has been generated by these platforms; as well as narrower strategic questions,

such as how a firm with a fixed inventory should set reserves and time sales to dynamically maximize

its revenue. Demand estimation is often also a necessary first step for the evaluation of anti-trust

issues, such as the potential impact on the search-keyword advertising market of a merger between

Microsoft and Yahoo.

At first glance, auctions data is an extremely rich of information about demand. In auctions we

actually observe a continuous bid which directly reflects willingness to pay, relative to the discrete

choice we typically see in fixed price markets. Moreover, for any buyer we generally observe all the

auctions that they bid in, which provides valuable information about which items they view as close

substitutes. This is informative for demand, much in the same way that “second-choice” data is

useful in Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (2004). As the choice sets available to buyers vary we may

1Source: eBay Annual Report for 20072Source: Google Annual Report for 2008

58

observe differing participation, which is helpful for identifying substitution patterns.

Yet the strengths of auction market data also pose some difficulties. As Hendricks and Porter

(2007) note in their survey article, participants in auction markets are playing a complex dynamic

game, where they must continuously adapt to the changing set of available auctions, and learn about

rival’s valuations. Most of the existing tools of structural auction econometrics are focused on inde-

pendent auctions of homogenous objects, which limits their direct applicability to auction demand

estimation, where bidders repeatedly interact across auctions, and substitution across products is

important.

In this paper, we develop an estimable demand system for an auction platform market with a

large number of relatively short-lived, yet persistent, buyers. The first part of the paper outlines an

intuitive and empirically tractable equilibrium concept — competitive Markov equilibrium — and

characterizes the long-run distribution of bidders and their strategies. Next, we show that demand

is non-parametrically identified from panel data. In the last part, we develop a nonparametric and

a semiparametric estimation approach for backing out demand from bid data. We also show how

to estimate a characteristic-based model of demand. These approaches are tested by Monte Carlo

simulation and found to work well in moderately sized samples.

To begin, the theory section introduces a stylized model of an auction market, in which each

period a good is sold by second-price sealed bid auction. There are a finite number of different goods

that can be sold, and supply of these goods is exogenous. Bidders have multidimensional private

valuations over the different goods. These valuations may be correlated. They have unit demand,

and upon entry participate in every auction until they either win or randomly exit. The stage game

is played each period over an infinite horizon.

The environment is complicated, because for any bidder the set of rival types is unknown, and

Bayes-Nash equilibrium would imply that everyone simultaneously solves a filtration problem, using

the observed history — possibly private and arbitrarily long — to infer the distribution of types. We

simplify by developing an equilibrium concept in which bidders condition only on a coarser publicly

observable state vector in forming beliefs about rival types, and that they take the state evolution

as exogenous. We call this notion competitive Markov equilibrium, and argue that it is appropriate

for large anonymous markets.

Then, if bidders have unit demand, we have a simple way to deal with dynamic concerns. Partic-

ipation has an option value: the expected surplus from future auctions conditional on today’s state.

This option value is struck when a bidder wins an auction, so she shades her bids accordingly. The

challenge of estimating private values is then estimating the long-run option value. We show that

59

this is non-parametrically identified from observing both individual bidder time series and the full

bid distribution across states.

The final part of the paper is concerned with estimation. We offer two approaches. One follows

the nonparametric identification logic directly, showing that by looking at the time series of bidders

who are observed bidding in every state we can back out their individual valuations. As is common

with panel data, there are selection concerns. These bidders are a selected sample, and to get the

true distribution of valuations, it is necessary to re-weight the estimated density. We show how to

do this.

A disadvantage of the nonparametric method is that it is data intensive, since if the state space

is large, the set of bidders who bid in every state may be very small. By making a parametric

assumption on the type distribution, we can make use of the remaining data. We first show how to

estimate the bid function for any type directly from the data, and then argue that this allows us to

simulate moments given any parameter vector. We can thus apply simulated GMM to consistently

estimate the true parameter vector.

The paper is related to various strands of literature. Jofre-Benet and Pesendorfer (2003) was

the first paper to attack estimation in a dynamic auction game, though in a world where private

information was transient. Subsequent to this, a number of papers have looked at dynamics on

the eBay platform specifically. Budish (2012) examines the optimality of eBay’s market design

with respect to the sequencing of sales and information revelation. In Said (2012), the author

investigates efficiency and revenue maximization in a similar setup through the lens of dynamic

mechanism design. Zeithammer (2006) developed a model with forward-looking bidders, and showed

both theoretically and empirically that bidders shade down current bids in response to the presence

of upcoming auctions of similar objects. Ingster (2009) develops a dynamic model of auctions of

identical objects, and provides equilibrium characterization and identification results. Sailer (2012)

estimates participation costs for bidders facing an infinite sequence of identical auctions. Relative to

this literature, our main contribution is the focus on sequential auctions of heterogeneous objects,

where bidders have multidimensional persistent private valuations. In short, we are focused on

developing a demand system. A different approach has been taken in Adams (2012), who looks at

the problem of nonparametric identification when auctions are completely simultaneous.

A second related literature is on alternative equilibrium notions for dynamic games. In coarsening

the set of information bidders condition on, we are following the path of Krusell and Smith (1998).

Weintraub, Benkard, and Van Roy (2008) develops the related notion of oblivious equilibrium.

Fersthman and Pakes (2009) also emphasizes the importance of a finite state space. Finally, we

60

build on the literature for estimating demand systems in durable goods markets (e.g. Berry (1994),

Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes (1995), Gowrisankaran and Rysman (2009)).

The next section introduces the theoretical framework, while section 3 proves non-parametric

identification. Section 4 describes our two different estimation approaches, while section 5 gives

Monte Carlo simulations for those estimators. Section 6 concludes.

4.2 Model

Our aim in this section is to create an abstract model of a large auction market, and analyze it.

The space of such models is vast, and we narrow in a number of ways. We consider a market in which

similar products — such as iPods and Zunes — are sold by second-price sealed bid auctions. These

auctions are held in discrete time, with one good auctioned per period over an infinite horizon. Since

our focus is on demand, we assume for simplicity that supply is random and exogenous. Bidders are

persistent with unit demand, and enter the market with private (possibly correlated) valuations for

each of the objects. Winning bidders immediately exit, while losing bidders exit randomly. We aim

at characterizing the long-run behavior of this dynamic system.

We have chosen this set of assumptions to match some features of the environment on eBay, whose

platform design dominates online auctions. In any eBay category, there are many different products

sold by auction to a large number of anonymous buyers.3 Although these auctions typically last for

many days, and thus overlap — so that at any given point in time there are many auctions occurring

simultaneously — they finish at different ending times, in sequence. As Bajari and Hortacsu (2004)

and Hendricks and Porter (2007) have noted, this timing, combined with the way the proxy bidding

system works, imply that eBay is well approximated as sequence of second-price sealed bid auctions.

Yet our intent is not to model eBay per se — and indeed we ignore some important features of the

eBay environment — but rather to develop a reasonably motivated and rich abstract model and see

what we can learn from the exercise.

4.2.1 Environment

We formalize the above description of the environment in what follows:

Bidders and Payoffs: Bidders have unit demand for a good in the set J , where |J | = J .

Their demand is summarized by a privately known vector of valuations x = (x1, x2 · · ·xJ), their

type. They are risk neutral, and receive a payoff of xj − p for buying a single good j at price p, and

3eBay hides the identity of the bidders by replacing parts of the username with asterixes.

61

zero otherwise. Bidders are impatient, with a common discount rate δ.

Market: Time is discrete with infinite horizon, t = 1, 2 · · · . In each period t, the following stage

game is played. First, a sealed-bid second price auction is held for the current object jt, in which

all bidders present in the market may participate. Then entry and exit of bidders takes place, and

suppliers post new objects. These are described in more detail below.

Auctions: At time t, object jt ∈ J is auctioned. Bidders have the choice between not partici-

pating (action ϕ), and submitting a bid. The action space is thus A = ϕ ∪ R+, where A is totally

ordered under the usual ordering < with ϕ < 0. The highest bidder wins the auction and pays the

second highest bid, or zero if his is the only bid submitted. Ties are broken randomly. If no-one

participates, the item is not sold.

Entry and Exit: At the end of every period, the winner is assumed to exit with certainty.4

Losers exogenously exit the market with probability ρ ∈ (0, 1), receiving a payoff normalized to

zero on exit. Simultaneously, Et new bidders enter, where Et is random with a distribution that

depends on the total number of buyers in the previous period Nt−1. We assume that Et|Nt−1

has strictly positive support on the finite set of integers 0, 1, 2 · · ·N − Nt−1. This ensures that

the size of the market does not explode.5 Each entrant draws their valuation vector x identically

and independently from a distribution F with associated strictly positive density f , and support a

compact set X = [0, x]J .

Supply: Supply is essentially the rate at which different products appear on the auction market.

At the end of period t, suppliers list a new object to be auctioned in period t + 1 + kf , where kf

is the lead-time bidders have in observing future supply. The object to be auctioned is randomly

chosen according to a multinomial distribution over the set of products J .6

Information Sets and Bidding Strategies: New entrants are assumed to be able to view the

history of the game for the last kh periods.7 Incumbent bidders may have observed more: at time t,

a bidder i who entered the market time ti can observe a ”window” of past actions and current and

upcoming auctions, from ti−kh to t+kf . The cases kh = 0 and kf = 0 correspond to no observable

public history and no knowledge of future supply, respectively. So a generic information set consists

of a valuation x, the history hit and the list of current and upcoming objects jt = (jt · · · jt+kf ). A

(pure) bid strategy is a mapping βi : X ×Hit ×J kf+1 → A from any information set to the action

4Since they have unit demand, they are indifferent about exiting in any period following a win. But even an ε > 0participation cost would make exit optimal.

5With endogenous entry, one would expect a condition like this to hold: entry falls as the number of participantsin the market increases, and so surplus falls. With exogenous entry, we must impose it.

6It is easy to extend the model to allow for fluctuating total supply by letting the the object be multinomial overJ ∪ ∅, where ∅ is the event that nothing is listed.

7This mimics eBay, where the history of auctions held in the past 14+ days is public, though anonymized).

62

set.

4.2.2 Analysis

We analyze this environment in three parts. First, we motivate and define a new equilibrium

concept called a competitive Markov equilibrium (CME) that we think is appropriate for long-run

analysis of large markets. Under this equilibrium, we show that strategies take a simple and intuitive

form: bidders bid their valuation for the good under auction, less their continuation value. Second,

we characterize the long-run properties of the dynamic system for arbitrary strategies, showing that

a stationary distribution over types exists. Finally, we combine these two pieces — equilibrium

characterization and long-run dynamics — to show existence of a CME. We also argue that as the

market becomes large, while holding the ratio of buyers to sellers fixed, the CME tends towards the

anonymous equilibrium of the continuum game.

To motivate the concept, consider the decision problem of a bidder in this environment. He

knows the recent history of the market, current supply and his own valuation. What he doesn’t

know is who else is in the market (his rivals, their valuations and their history), nor how they

will bid. In addition, he must form expectations about future demand conditions, and should in

principle worry about “leakage”; his bid today might reveal valuable information to future rivals.

Addressing these issues with standard equilibrium concepts is problematic. Though Milgrom and

Weber (2000) were able to provide an elegant equilibrium characterization of sequential auctions

under certain information structures, their approach is essentially static and does not extend to

the infinite horizon case.8 In this environment, forming rational expectations about the play of

opponents requires some notion of the long-run stationary distribution of types, but without placing

some structure on the admissible strategies, the state space may grow without bound.

Technical objections aside, expecting this behavior from bidders in large markets seems unreal-

istic. Bidders on eBay don’t worry about leakage, because they don’t expect their individual bids

to be tracked by rivals. Rivals don’t track them because the market is large, turnover is rapid,

and there is little to be gained from the information. Basically, bidders expect that with this many

auctions, the probability of meeting the same opponents in the future is low.

To capture this intuition, we assume that bidders believe that now — and in the future —

they are to compete with a random draw from the long-run population of types. These beliefs

may be conditioned on some simple and publicly observable “state” variables, such as recent prices,

8They consider the problem of auctioning k identical objects to n bidders, where n > k, and the bidders all enterin the first period.

63

which may be informative as to whether demand is currently high or low. Bidders have rational

expectations, and their beliefs will be correct in equilibrium. Importantly, they will take the state

as given and its evolution as exogenous, though in fact since the market is finite, their actions may

have some impact on the state transitions.

This kind of assumption was introduced in the macroeconomics literature by Krusell and Smith

(1998) as a behavioral assumption, arguing that agents will make inferences based on simple func-

tionals of all the information available in the environment, at least when doing so loses little in-

formation. The special case where agents ignore all current information and the state is constant

or exogenously given has a complete information counterpart in the oblivious equilibrium concept

of Weintraub, Benkard, and Van Roy (2008). We also provide a “large-market” justification of the

assumption in the discussion below.

Formally, for any public history of actions ht = (at−1 · · ·at−kh), let hanont be the anonymized

history (i.e. where identifiers on bid identity are removed). The associated space of anonymized

histories is stationary, and denoted as Hanon ≡ Akh×N . Bidders also know the supply jt ∈ J kf+1,

implying the space of all anonymized public information is Hanon × J kf+1. Define a coarsening

function T as a (Borel) measurable function that finitely partitions the space into “states” s ∈ S,

where |S| = S. We require that T partitions different current objects into different states, so that

minimally the agent conditions on the object under auction — in math, jt 6= j′t ⇒ T (hanont , jt) 6=

T (hanon′

t , jt′).

This coarsening T defines the state space, and therefore what bidders pay attention to. Bidders

must also have a model of state transitions. Define Q as the transition matrix between states, with

typical element Qij = P(s′ = j|s = i), for s′ the state tomorrow. Our notion of equilibrium requires

that bidders correctly understand the distribution of competing types and the state transitions, and

optimize against this:

Definition 1 (Competitive Markov Equilibrium). A (symmetric) competitive Markov equilib-

rium (CME) with respect to a coarsening function T consists of:

(i) Correct beliefs about the ergodic distribution of opposing types conditional on any s ∈ S; and

about the state transition matrix Q

(ii) Symmetric Markovian strategies β(x, s) that maximize expected payoffs given beliefs.

Let us unpack this a bit. The CME is extremely similar to a Bayes-Nash equilibrium, requiring

that strategies are optimal given beliefs; and that beliefs are consistent with equilibrium play. The

64

key differences are that here bidders condition only on the state s in forming beliefs, even when this

is coarser than the public information available to them; and that they do not account for how their

actions may influence the state transitions Q. This is the is the “competitive” part of the name,

as it corresponds to the case in perfect competition where firms do not recognize that their joint

production decisions determine the price. Here, bidders behave as though they were small, and do

not endogenize the impact of their own actions on the future states. Another important difference

is that this is a long-run concept: bidders believe they face draws from the ergodic distribution of

types, which is a sensible belief only if the market does indeed converge to a long-run distribution

and has been in operation for a while. This formulation avoids the issue of a prior on the initial

type draw.

It turns out that under these assumptions, the equilibrium bidding strategy β(x, s) has a in-

tuitive and simple form. Temporarily putting aside questions of stationarity and existence, fix a

CME. Bidders have well-defined beliefs about the distribution of types in any state, and given the

equilibrium bid strategies, can also work out the distribution of highest opposing bids (i.e. the bid

they need to beat to win). They also have rational expectations about state transitions. This allows

us to define an (ex-post) value function for a type x in state s:

(4.1) v(x, s) = maxb∈A

G1(b|s)(xt − E[B1|B1 < b, s]

)+ (1−G1(b|s))δ(1− ρ)

S∑s′=1

v(x, s′)Qss′

where G1(·|s) is the distribution of the highest opposing bid today given the state; xt is the bidder’s

valuation of the object currently under auction, and Q is the equilibrium transition matrix. The first

term in the value function is the probability of winning — the probability that the highest opposing

bid is lower — times the surplus conditional on winning, equal to current valuation less expected

payment. The second term is the probability of losing times the continuation value in that event.

Non-participation (ϕ) implies certain loss, so G1(ϕ|s) = 0 ∀s.

Now let v(x, s) = δ(1 − ρ)∑Ss′=1 v(x, s′)Qss′ denote the discounted ex-ante value function (i.e.

before exit and state transitions are determined). Maximizing the value function above, we get the

optimal strategies:

Lemma 10 ( Equilibrium Strategies). In a symmetric CME, bidders bid their valuation less

65

their ex-ante continuation value if it is positive; otherwise they don’t participate:

(4.2) β(x, s) =

xt − v(x, s) , xt − v(x, s) ≥ 0

ϕ , otherwise

Think about this process as a single auction, where the winner gets the object, and the losers

are awarded a prize with value equal to the continuation value. Re-normalizing the prizes, it’s like

a standard second-price auction where the winner gets the object less continuation value, and losers

get nothing. Then the weakly dominant strategy is to bid the value of the prize, which is just the

value of the object less the continuation value.9 In the case where the “prize” has negative value,

there is no reason to participate.

The intuitive appeal of this characterization is that it reduces the bidder problem to forming

some expectation of their continuation value, which should be informed by the state of the market

(recent history and future supply). Under a CME, we require these expectations to be correct in

the sense of matching the long-run behavior of the system.

Our next step is to analyze these dynamics. Since bidders enter and exit every period over an

infinite horizon, if we kept track of specific identities the state-space would grow without bound. So

for the long-run analysis, we ignore identity, and keep track of an anonymous N -vector xt of types

currently in the market.10

We let the “true state” of the market ωt ∈ Ω ≡ XN × S be defined by the anonymized vector

of types xt and the state st. For any symmetric strategy β, the true state evolves as a first order

Markov process, with the type transitions governed by the entry and exit rules. The state transitions

are determined by the exogenous supply and the actions taken by the types in accordance with the

strategies. Denote by F the Borel σ-field over Ω.

Lemma 11 (Ergodic Distribution of True States). For any strategy β, there is a unique

invariant measure µβ on the measurable space (Ω,F), strongly converged to at uniform geometric

rate from any initial measure µ0. The conditional ergodic distribution of x−i given s exists and is

well-defined for any s ∈ S.

9As Budish (2012), Said (2012) and Zeithammer (2012) all note, this is not true in the full Bayes-Nash equilibrium,due to a winner’s curse effect: on winning, a bidder learns that the remaining types had lower valuations, and thereforeregrets winning now rather than later at a lower price. This effect is swept away in a CME, since bidders take thestate evolution as exogenous.

10We use 0 as a placeholder when there are fewer than N bidders in the market. Type transitions occur first byremoving exiting bidders and replacing them with the placeholder, and then adding entrants sequentially, startingfrom the first open placeholder. For example, suppose we have N = 3, and there are two bidders with (unidimensionalvaluations) 1 and 2 respectively. Then we have xt = (1, 2, 0); and if at the end of the period bidder 1 exits and twonew bidders with values 3 and 4 respectively enter, we will have xt+1 = (3, 2, 4).

66

This says that the market “settles down” to a steady-state, regardless of the initial conditions,

with a unique stationary distribution of types in each state. The intuition for this is that entry

and supply are exogenous, and only the exit of winning bidders is endogenously determined. This

has a limited influence on the long-run evolution of the market.11 An implication of this is that in

the long-run, given any strategies, agents have well-defined beliefs about the population of bidders

they face. We can now look for a fixed point: strategies that are optimal given long-run beliefs; and

beliefs that are consistent with the ergodic distributions induced by these strategies. We will call a

strategy β(x, s) monotone if in every state bids increase in the valuation of the good under auction,

and decrease in the valuations of other objects. We say it is strictly monotone if the monotonicity

is strict except for non-participating types.12

Theorem 1 (Existence). For any coarsening function T , there exists a CME in continuous strictly

monotone pure strategies. If there is only one product, the CME is unique.

The proof is non-trivial.13 One would like to exploit the characterization of the bidding strategies

in (4.2), and show existence of a fixed point of the best response operator Γ(β) = xt − vβ(x, s).

But as is often the case in auction theory, Γ does not map continuous functions into continuous

functions since if some types “play an atom” under β, then the continuation value vβ(x, s) may be

discontinuous at some points.

So instead we take a different and well-trodden approach, discretizing the action space, and then

applying the methodology of Reny (2008) based on contractible mappings to show a fixed point of

the finite action game. Since whether bids increase or decrease in the valuations depends on the

state, we cannot directly apply his results, and must modify some parts of the proof.14 A limiting

argument as in Athey (2001) yields an equilibrium for the continuous action game. In the case where

there is only one product, we can show that the Γ operator is a contraction mapping, implying a

unique CME.

Finally, to conclude this section, we wish to argue (informally) that for large markets, this concept

is a sensible approximation to a more standard equilibrium concept, anonymous equilibrium. One

way to do this is to show that as the markets become arbitrarily large, the set of equilibria coincide.

11The formal proof uses a renewal argument, based on the idea that the mean hitting time to the “null set” whereeveryone has exited the market is finite.

12That is, β(x, s) is strictly increasing in xt except possibly where β(x, s) = ϕ.13Duffie, Geanakoplos, Mas-Colell, and McLennan (1994) establish existence for a broad class of stochastic games,

but strategies may be mixed and a public coordination device is required.14Reny (2008) allows for arbitrary partial orders on both the type and action spaces, but requires that under those

orders, increasing types must take increasing actions. In our case, increasing types (e.g. a higher valuation for object1) take some higher actions (bid higher in states where 1 is auctioned) and lower actions (bid lower in states where 2is auctioned).

67

So consider a modification of this model in which instead of one auction being held in each period,

we instead had n auctions of the same good, and n times as many entrants. This implies that as

n→∞ the buyer to item ratio converges to a constant.15 As in the classic paper of Wolinsky (1988),

assume that bidders are randomly assigned to each of the n auctions.16

We must show that in any limiting CME, no bidder can improve their payoff by instead employing

an anonymous strategy. Notice that as as n→∞, by the usual abuse of the law of large numbers,

the distribution of types in every period will be exactly the stationary distribution. Then since

supply is exogenous, the CME assumption that individual bidders cannot affect the state transitions

becomes exact. It is then easy to show that optimal bidding strategies still take the form of valuation

less continuation value. Now any anonymous strategy cannot condition on identity, and so since

the stationary distribution is realized every period, there is no value to conditioning on the past.

This implies that both the limiting CME and anonymous strategies will not vary with past play.

Then provided the CME strategy does not coarsen away information about future auctions (i.e. T is

such that bidders use all the information available about future supply), the CME and anonymous

strategies will coincide. The limiting CME will be an equilibrium of the corresponding anonymous

discounted sequential game, in the language of Jovanovic and Rosenthal (1988).

So we learn that the fundamental simplification that we make — even in the limit — is that

bidders do not keep track of identity; for if they did, they could perhaps profitably condition on recent

history if they happened to be randomly matched with other incumbent bidders. Our intuition for

why anonymity is a reasonable assumption comes from large online markets, where bidders rarely

expect to meet the same opponents again, and even when they do, are typically not aware of it. If

you believe, as we do, that the anonymity assumption is reasonable in large markets, then the CME

concept is attractive because it preserves the limiting properties of other concepts while allowing

for strategies that respond to endogenous fluctuations in state. On the other hand, if bidders pay

attention to the specific actions of other bidders — as would be the case in a small or concentrated

market — it is less sensible.

Lemmas 10 and 11 provide the main take homes from this section. First, in equilibrium bidders

shade their bids down from their values, where the extent of shading depends on their continuation

value in the current state. Notice immediately that this is starkly different from the “usual” model of

second-price sealed bid auctions, where bids may be interpreted as valuations. Indeed, valuations are

strictly higher than bids, implying that nonparametric estimates of the value distribution obtained

15The steady state number of bidders is N∗ = nE[Et]− (1− ρ)n = n(E

[Et]− (1− ρ)). So N∗/n is constant.16The random assignment assumption is common in the theory literature: see also Satterthwaite and Shneyerov

(2007).

68

by treating auctions as independent will be systematically biased upward. Second, the stationary

distribution of types exists, but is different from the valuation distribution F , due to selection:

bidders with low valuations will persist in the market for longer. So again, treating the auction data

as a cross-section would be misleading. In the next section we develop nonparametric identification

results for large auction markets that addresses both of these issues.

4.3 Nonparametric Identification

Equilibrium play implies a precise data generating process, with bidders entering, making bids

and exiting according to the model. Suppose that one were to observe all the data produced in the

course of equilibrium play, essentially consisting of the object auctioned in each period, the bids

placed and the associated bidder identities. Could one then identify the underlying distribution of

valuations, and thus recover demand?

We give a nonparametric identification result in the spirit of Athey and Haile (2002).17 We think

this is useful because it makes explicit the assumptions that are needed to identify the primitives

of the dynamic game, as well as providing some guidance as to a sensible estimation strategy. For

intuition, we will first work through a simple two good example.

4.3.1 Example

Suppose there are two goods, so J = j1, j2. The exit probability ρ is constant across states.

Supply is binomial and independent of state, with q the probability of good 1. Bidders coarsen

the public information so that they condition only on the product identity in the current and next

auction, implying four states: 1 = 1, 1, 2 = 1, 2, 3 = 2, 1 and 4 = 2, 2. Recall that an

equilibrium bid strategy for a type x is a bid in each state, and let the equilibrium bids for a fixed

type be b1 · · · b4. Then the interim continuation value in state i, vi, is given by:

vi = G1(bi|i) (xi − E[B1|B1 < bi, i]) + δ(1− ρ)(1−G1(bi|i))4∑j=1

Qij vj

17Similar identification arguments were made in Jofre-Benet and Pesendorfer (2003) and Pesendorfer and Schmidt-Dengler (2003). Our identification problem differs substantively since there are persistent latent variables — thevaluations — whereas in their setup it is only the observable state variables that may persist.

69

where Q is the transition matrix between states. From the bidding function, we substitute out xi

as bi + vi, where vi is the ex-ante continuation value. Rearranging terms yields:

(4.3) vi − δ(1− ρ)

4∑j=1

Qij vj = G1(bi|i) (bi − E[B1|B1 < bi, i])

Let v = [v1, v2, v3, v4]T , and let u be given by:

u ≡

G1(b1|1) (b1 − E[B1|B1 < b1, 1])

G1(b2|2) (b2 − E[B1|B1 < b2, 2])

G1(b3|3) (b3 − E[B1|B1 < b3, 3])

G1(b4|4) (b4 − E[B1|B1 < b4, 4])

i.e. the expected difference between bid and payment in any one period. Then (4.3) can be repre-

sented as the linear system:

(I − δ(1− ρ)Q) v = u

where I is an S × S identity matrix. Next standard results imply that (I − δ(1− ρ)Q) is invertible,

and therefore the existence of a unique solution for v ?. Thus we have:

v = (I − δ(1− ρ)Q)−1u

Up to now, we have just been manipulating mathematical expressions. We now turn to the

question of identification. Suppose that the econometrician knows the coarsening function T (i.e.

the mapping from the public information, which is observed, to the state variables). Then each

of the auctions can be correctly classified into the four states. Now fix a particular bidder in the

dataset, who is observed participating in every state. For such a bidder, we can construct an S-length

bid vector b = b1 · · · b4 corresponding to their bid in each of the four states.18 We shall call such

bid vectors “complete”. Plugging this vector into the above expression for u, we can recover the

expected difference between payment and bid.

The transition matrix Q and exit probability ρ are identified directly from the data. So if the

econometrician also knows the discount factor ρ, then the interim continuation values v of any type

who bids b is identified. Now, we can move from v to the actual valuations x by again using the bid

18Of course, in the data they may have made many more than four bids; but as long as they have bid in every state,this construction is feasible.

70

function expression:

x1 = b1 + δ(1− ρ) (qv1 + (1− q)v2) = b2 + δ(1− ρ) (qv3 + (1− q)v4)

x2 = b3 + δ(1− ρ) (qv1 + (1− q)v2) = b4 + δ(1− ρ) (qv3 + (1− q)v4)

where the expressions reflect the fact that good 1 is auctioned in states 1 and 2, while good 2 is

auctioned in states 3 and 4. Thus for any bid vector b, we have identified the underlying valuation

x = (x1, x2), which is unique. In fact you can see that in this case, where |J | < |S|, the valuations

are over-identified. This provides a potential test of the theory.

Given a random sample of complete bid-vectors, one could thus identify the valuation distribution

F . But in the actual data the set of complete bid vectors is a selected sample, as some types will

never participate in some states, and some types will persist longer, thus potentially being over-

sampled. Assume for simplicity that all types participate in all states. So the key is to address

the selection issue. As we show in the appendix, once the type x is identified for bid vector b, the

probability that the bid vector is complete can also be identified.19 Thus by inverting individual

complete bid vectors to valuation vectors, and then re-weighting the density of these valuations by

the inverse of the probability that they would be complete, we can identify the type density. This

gives us demand.

4.3.2 Formal Result

The formal result simply summarizes what we have learnt from the example. The only difference

is that we need to be a little careful about what we can identify for bidders who don’t participate.

Clearly, if a type never bids on product one, say, regardless of what the state is, then we cannot

identify their valuation for product one. Thus for each subset B of J , partition the type space X

into 2J − 1 sets of types who bid only on products in B, regardless of the state. Let XB be the |B|-

dimensional random variable defined by restricting valuations X to products in B, with distribution

function FB(xB) ≡ P (XB ≤ xB |X ∈ B). Then we have the following result:

Theorem 2 (Identification). If the discount rate δ and the coarsening function T are known, the

distribution FB is non-parametrically identified for all B ⊆ J . Moreover, the private valuation of

any bidder observed bidding in every state s ∈ S is identified.

The conditions for identification are slightly stronger than is usual in these dynamic settings.

19The idea is to recursively define the probability of being seen only in state 1, then in states 1 and 2....

71

Typically, it is necessary to know the discount rate.20 But here the econometrician must also know

the coarsening function. This is because the CME concept does not nail down bidder beliefs; it can

accommodate a variety of models about which variables bidders pay attention to. The downside with

this is that the econometrician must actually work out what those variables are in order to identify

demand. Given these assumptions, we get pointwise identification for complete observations, via the

same argument as in the example. We also get identification of the distribution of types who make

a positive bid on every object.

In fact, if bidders are sufficiently forward looking, all types will make positive bids on every

object in some state. To see this, notice that what causes a bidder to never bid on product j is the

lost future surplus from winning other objects in future auctions. But if product j is to be auctioned

every period for a long time — an event that will eventually happen — then the discounted future

surplus from other objects will be very small, implying that they will bid on product j. Intuitively,

variation in the set of upcoming auctions can be used to identify the valuations of bidders who may

generally not participate.

4.4 Estimation Strategy

Suppose that the conditions of the Theorem 2 are met, and the econometrician knows or can

determine the discount rate and coarsening function. He also has a panel dataset, consisting of

all the bids placed in each auction and bidder identify. Assume also for simplicity that all types

bid on every good.21 How should estimation proceed? We propose two different approaches. The

first approach is nonparametric, following the logic of the identification section by inverting from

observed bids to valuations. We look directly at the individual-level micro-data, treating the record

of all bids placed by a given bidder as an observation. The individual-level data may differ in its

dimensions: for some bidders, we may only see a single bid, while for others we may see many

bids. The structural model implies that at most we should see S distinct bids by any one bidder,

a different bid for every state. In the language of the section above, these S length bid vectors are

“complete observations”.

For complete observations, we can invert from the bid vector to a valuation vector via the first

order condition provided we have estimates of the transition matrix and the distribution of opposing

bids. This is very much like the approach of Guerre, Perrigne, and Vuong (2000). One important

20But as Ackerberg, Hirano, and Shahriar (2011) argue, if there are buy price auctions on the platform, it may bepossible to identify discount rates from the data.

21Where this fails, the estimation results presented here can be adapted with more work to account for non-participation; but it is important that non-participation is observable.

72

difference is that the set of complete observations is a selected sample of the bidders — bidders

with high valuations are more likely to win and exit quickly, and therefore less likely to be observed

bidding in every state. For this reason, it is necessary to re-weight the density of the estimated

valuations in order to get an estimate of the type density.

The nonparametric approach is very clean and makes no parametric assumptions, but requires a

fair number of complete observations. This may be impractical in markets with many states and high

turnover in participants. Many bidders on eBay, for example, participate in only one or two auc-

tions before either winning or giving up. We therefore also outline two additional approaches, where

we impose successively more stringent parametric assumptions. First, we outline a semiparametric

estimation approach based on simulated generalized method of moments, as is used elsewhere for

demand estimation in industrial organization and marketing. There we assume a parametric struc-

ture on the distribution of types, and then choose parameters to match moments implied by the

structural model with those observed in the data.

Even in that case, if there are a large number of products the model quickly becomes unwieldy.

So, following the literature (e.g. McFadden (1974)) we consider projecting product valuations onto

characteristics. Instead of types being valuations for products, types are now random coefficients

indicating the marginal value of product characteristics. In the standard specification we consider,

this implies a linear structure for valuations in characteristics. Under reasonable distributional

assumptions on the random coefficients, this linearity can be exploited and a very simple estimation

procedure can be used.

Regardless of the approach — nonparametric, semiparametric or characteristic-based — there is

a common first step in which a number of primitives are estimated.

4.4.1 Step 1: Estimate transitions, exit and payments

In the first step, we non-parametrically estimate the probability of winning with a bid of b

in state s, G1(b|s); the expected payment conditional on winning, E[B1|B1 < b, s]; the Markov

transition matrix Q; the invariant measure over states π; and the probability of exit conditional on

losing, ρ = [ρ1, ρ2 · · · ρS ]. This first step can be summarized as estimating elements of the per period

payoffs and the transition probabilities, and is similar to that of both Bajari, Benkard, and Levin

(2007) and Pakes, Ostrovsky, and Berry (2007) in their papers on dynamic games estimation.

All of these are conditional moments, and provided the conditioning variable is discrete — as the

state variable is — we can consistently estimate the conditional moment from the relevant empirical

73

analogue. So for example, to estimate an element of the transition matrix Qij , we have:

Qij =

∑Tt=1 1(st−1 = i)1(st = j)∑T

t=1 1(st−1 = i)

where t = 1 · · ·T indexes auctions and 1(·) is an indicator function. The only “difficult” object to

estimate is E[B1|B1 < b, s] because for fixed s the conditioning variable b is continuous. This can be

done state-by-state using any nonparametric approach, such as kernel density or sieve estimation.

4.4.2 Nonparametric Approach Step 2: Recover valuations

The key to the non-parametric approach is to treat the data as a sequence of (short) time series,

one for each bidder. We restrict attention to complete observations, a subset of our dataset consisting

of S-dimensional bid vectors bi = (bi1 . . . biS).

For each observation i, we can use the first-stage estimates to construct a vector ui = (ui1, ui2 . . . uiS),

where uis = bis − E[B1|B1 < bis, s]. Then the interim continuation value for bidder i, vi =

(vi1 . . . viS), is the solution to the linear system vi = (I − δ(1 − ρ)Q)−1ui. Moreover, we have

from (4.2) that given a J-length sub-vector bi of bi consisting of bids on different objects, an asso-

ciated sub-vector ρ of ρ, and an associated J × S submatrix Q of Q consisting of the transitions

associated with the bids in bi, we get xi = bi + δ(1 − ρ)Qvi. Substituting in our estimates on the

right hand side of this expression, we get an estimate xi of the valuation of each bidder.

The set of bidders with complete observations is a selected sample, and we need to correct for

this. In the appendix, we derive an expression for P (A, x), the probability that a type x is observed

bidding only in the set of states in A, for A ⊆ S. This expression is identified from previously

estimated objects. Now, the probability that a given type generates a complete observation is

P (S, x). We can thus correct for the selection bias by assigning a weight equal to 1/P (S, xi) to each

xi, and then use weighted kernel density estimation to back out the type density f(x).

We omit a formal analysis of the asymptotic properties of this estimator, both because it takes

us into the realm of non-parametric estimation with dependent data and because we suspect that

the semiparametric approach outlined below is more likely to be used in practice. Yet intuitively

Lemma 11 guarantees that the data generating process quickly converges to an ergodic distribution,

and so the asymptotics should be well-behaved. This is supported by the estimator’s performance

in our Monte Carlo experiments, below.

74

4.4.3 Semiparametric Approach Step 2a: Estimate bid function

The semiparametric approach goes in the opposite direction. Instead of inverting bids to valua-

tions we take draws from a parametrized type distribution, simulate bids, and match the moments

of the simulated bid distribution with those observed in the data. This places weaker demands on

the data, as we need not observe a large sample of complete bid vectors.

The first part of the second step is working out how to simulate bids for a given type. Our idea

is to solve for the optimal biding function in this environment. Bidders in this environment face a

Markov Decision Problem (MDP): they need to choose a bid in each state to maximize their payoff.

As is the case in other environments, policy iteration will suffice to find the optimal bid vector for

a type x.

To be more concrete, start with any initial strategy β0, such as bidding the object’s valuation

(β0(x, s) = xt). Then from (4.1), one can solve for the ex-ante continuation value given that strategy

by plugging in this bid into the probability of winning, expected payment on winning etc. From

this estimated continuation value v0(x, s), we can define a new strategy β1(x, s) = xt − v0(x, s) and

compute a new continuation value. Iterating in this way, we quickly converge to the optimal policy,

since the iteration process obeys a contraction mapping.22

4.4.4 Semiparametric Approach Step 2b: Match Moments

Once we have bidding strategies, we are close to being able to calculate moments of the bid

distribution in each state. Of course, we need to know not only how the types will bid, but also

the stationary distribution of types. To close the model then, we form a parametric model for the

type distribution Fθ ≡ F (X|θ), where θ is a finite dimensional parameter. Let F be the stationary

distribution of types. Fθ and Fθ will typically be quite different. Our aim is to identify the true

parameter vector θ0, as this identifies demand.

A generic estimation approach is to simulate data from the structural model under θ, and compare

the simulated and sample moments. Any minimum distance estimator that chooses θ to minimize

the distance between thoughtfully chosen functionals of the observed and actual bid distributions

will converge to the true θ0, provided it is identified. To take a specific example, consider comparing

a moment like E[b|S = 1] — the mean bid in state 1 — across the sample and the parametric model.

Dropping repeated bids in the same state by the same bidder, we can form the sample moment as a

simple average. On the model side, we need to calculate Eθ[β(X, 1)], where the expectation is over

22Here, for example, we see the benefit of assuming that bidders assume state transitions are exogenous. For if not,one would need a model of the counterfactual state transitions had another strategy been followed.

75

the stationary distribution of types who bid in state 1, which we can estimate for fixed θ. The easiest

way to do this is to simulate draws from Fθ, and compute the relevant bids using the estimated bid

function.

Yet as noted earlier, the stationary distribution of bids in state 1 is not the type distribution F .

So we need to re-weight the draws to consistently estimate Eθ[β(X, 1)]. As we show in the appendix,

one can use the first stage estimates to solve for the probability that in the stationary distribution

any type x will be observed bidding in any subset of states A ⊆ S. So the probability we see a bid

in state 1 is just the complement of the probability of seeing only bids in Ac, and we can use to

correctly re-weight and account for the selection issue.

Although any minimum distance estimator will do — and indeed in the Monte Carlo we use a

particularly simple approach based on comparing the mean and variance of bids in a state, and the

covariance across pairs of states — for the asymptotics it is easiest to appeal to standard results

from the literature on GMM. Treat the data as a time series of auction observations t = 1 · · ·T .

Then we can construct moment conditions based on the fact at the truth, sample and simulated

moments should coincide. The asymptotic theory of Hansen (1982) applies, showing that provided

the true parameter is identified and the environment is strictly stationary, the GMM estimation

approach will recover the truth asymptotically. Note that Lemma 11 proves the stationarity of the

environment, so that is satisfied. But we need also appeal to the results of Pakes and Pollard (1989)

to argue that the simulation error has no impact on the asymptotic distribution of the estimator

as the number of simulations grows large; and to either Andrews (1994) or Ai and Chen (2003) to

argue that the non-parametric first stage does not preclude√N consistency.

From a computational point of view, there are ways to speed up the estimation. One important

bottleneck is that for every new parameter update and sample of bidders, we must solve a dynamic

optimization problem for a large sample of simulated types. We can speed this up using an impor-

tance sampling approach.23 Instead of drawing the types anew on each iteration and solving out for

their bidding strategies, instead choose a set of R types initially to uniformly span some plausible

region of X and compute their optimal bids. The choice of initial region is up to the researcher:

one suggestion might be to regress prices on states, and then take the region of types spanned by

the coefficient estimate plus four standard deviations on either side. This need only be done once.

Then, to compute the simulated moments, we weight the types according to their relative likelihood

under θ and compute the simulated moments as weighted sums.

23This idea was also used in Ackerberg (2003). See Ackerberg (2009) for a thorough discussion of this technique.

76

4.4.5 Characteristic Space Approach

At the end of the day, we are trying to estimate the distribution of valuations over different

products. As in the more general demand literature, this can be overly demanding of the data if

the product space is large. Even after imposing a multivariate normal parametric structure, for

example, we need to estimate a variance covariance matrix with J(J + 1)/2 parameters. Given this,

we may want to project valuations down onto product characteristics.

To do this, we assume that valuations depend on the characteristics of the goods zt ∈ Rk, as well

as on tastes for the characteristics and an unobserved utility shock:

(4.4) xit = αizt + γi

where we index individuals by i and auctions by t as before. The pair (αi, γi) ∈ Rk+1 are the

individual’s type, reflecting tastes for the product characteristics and for buying a good relative to

the outside option. This is similar to the random coefficients demand specification familiar from

the discrete choice literature. The main differences are that γi replaces the totally idiosyncratic

shock εit; and that there is no unobserved heterogeneity term ξt. In an auction setup it makes

sense to think of agents varying in their willingness to pay in a way that does not depend on the

characteristics, and so we add γi; whereas in discrete choice this has no testable implications and so

is omitted. Including also an idiosyncratic shock εit in our specification would create few problems

for us. By contrast, unobserved heterogeneity presents more of a challenge, and we will not discuss

it here.24

It is not hard to see that provided there remains a finite number of products (i.e. characteristic

bundles), nothing from our previous semiparametric approach need change. Carrying out steps 1

and 2a, we can compute the bid strategy for any type, where a type is now a pair (α, γ). Then given

a parametric assumption on the joint distribution of (α, γ), we can simulate moments as before and

match them with sample moments.

Yet under stronger assumptions we can use a much simpler estimation procedure. Suppose

that agents condition only on the characteristics of the object under auction, so that z is the state

variable.25 Assume also that supply is exogenous and uncorrelated over time, by which we mean

that the characteristics zt of the goods to be auctioned are drawn independently each period from a

24But see Li and Vuong (1998) for a measurement error approach that would allow deconvolution of bids intocommon and idiosyncratic components if the unobserved heterogeneity ξt was iid over time and not known by theagents in advance of period t.

25Provided there are a finite number of products, and therefore characteristic bundles, the state space remainsfinite.

77

fixed distribution with discrete support. Then the states evolve as a random walk, and the bidding

function is:

β(α, γ, z) = x− v(x) = αz + γ − v(α, γ)

where the first equality follows because the ex-ante continuation value is independent of the state,

and the second follows by substituting in for the valuation.

Now, let the mean type be (µα, µγ) = (EF [α], EF [γ]). Then we can write bids as:

(4.5) bit = αizt + γi − v(α, γ) = µ0 + µαzt + εit

for µ0 = E[γ − v(α, γ)] and εit = zt(αi − µα) + γ − v(α, γ)− E[γ − v(α, γ)].

Now, since entry is exogenous and the type distribution F is independent of the current good

zt, the types of new bidders will be uncorrelated with zt. This implies the orthogonality condition

E[ztεit] = 0. So from (4.5) we can estimate the mean tastes for the characteristics µα by OLS

regression of bids on characteristics.26 This hedonic regression may be all that is needed in some

applications. It is worth noting though that the simple OLS approach requires that states evolve as

a random walk and that bidder entry into the market is independent of the products being offered.

One might wonder why such a simple approach is possible here and not elsewhere. The key is

that a characteristic-based model places strong and linear restrictions on the relationships between

the valuations. Whereas in the general product space model we had to look at joint bids on objects

A and B for inference, implying a need to understand the dynamic selection process driving bidders

into that pair of auctions, here we can just look at bids on A and infer the valuation for B from

their taste for the common characteristic z. This means that it suffices to look only at the initial

bids of new bidders — which is a sample of types directly from F — and completely abstract from

dynamic selection concerns.

4.5 Monte Carlo

We perform a simple Monte Carlo exercise to test both our nonparametric and parametric esti-

mation approaches in small samples. In the simple case there are two goods, and bidders condition

their bids only on the identity of the good and their private information, so there are two corre-

sponding public states. In each period, each of these goods is equally likely to be listed. The number

of entrants k is always 3 each period, but exit is random with losing bidders exiting with probability

26In practice, since we have conditional heteroscedasticity, using a feasible generalized least squares (FGLS) approachwill be more efficient than OLS. This may be important in small samples.

78

ρ = 0.25 and winning bidders exiting with certainty. The discount rate δ is set to 0.99. We con-

sider alternative parameterizations for k and ρ. Bidders’ private valuations are distributed bivariate

normal with mean µ and covariance matrix Σ, which we also allow to vary in different Monte Carlo

experiments.

Data is generated by first solving for the bidding function via policy iteration – though we have

only been able to prove this converges in general for |S| = 1 (see Theorem 1), it has converged in

all of our experiments to date. Then for each Monte Carlo iteration we simulate a dataset of 500

auctions, after discounting an initial 10,000 auctions as a ”burn in”. This amounts to, in expectation,

250 auctions per product, which seems like a moderate amount of data, especially given the volume

of transactions online.

We run both estimation routines assuming that the econometrician knows the entry process,

the discount rate δ and that the transitions between states are random rather than Markov. In

the common first stage, we estimate the probability of exit ρ, and the probability of good one

being listed, q. Then in the nonparametric second stage approach, we estimate the marginals of

the type density using a Gaussian kernel density estimation approach with automatic bandwidth

choice by cross-validation. In the parametric estimation, we (correctly) specify a multivariate normal

distribution for the types, and take a minimum distance (MD) approach by matching the mean and

variance of bids for each state in which a bidder may be observed, as well as the covariance between

bids in each state for bidders observed in both.

Our results for the simple case are presented in Table 1. Experiment A is a baseline case with

k = 3, ρ = 1/4, and symmetric µ and Σ. Experiment B slowed the rate of entry and random

exit, allowing for fewer, but longer-lived bidders. Experiments C and D add positive and negative

correlation between valuations, respectively, and finally experiment E adds positive correlation as

well as significant asymmetry in the means and variance terms. Estimates from the structural models

proposed in this paper appear in panel 1 for each experiment. Panel 2 presents, for comparison,

estimates from a naive approach that treats each observed bid as a draw from the distribution of

private valuations.

The supply parameter p and exit probability ρ are precisely estimated. Estimates of µ and Σ

come from the parametric approach, and are found to be accurate and encouragingly precise for all

parameterizations of the model. The naive approach gets both the means and the variances wrong

in a statistically significant way. This bias derives from three sources that we have dealt with in our

model: repeat bidding, selection by type, and bid shading according to the option value of losing.

In the far-right hand columns appear estimates of the mean integrated squared error (MISE),

79

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4

70 80 90 100 110 120

Estimated Density True Density

Figure 4.1: Monte Carlo Simulation: The figure shows the true and estimated marginal densityof valuations for product 1 for a randomly chosen Monte Carlo simulation of 500 auctions withspecification E.

which is a measure of goodness-of-fit for our nonparametric approach.27 We report MISE for the

marginal distributions of types in both dimensions. In comparing these numbers, note that MISE is

not a normalized measure, and is therefore not comparable across specifications. We can, however,

compare the MISE generated by the structural approach with the MISE generated by the naive

approach, and we see substantial improvement, with the structural model often doing a full order

of magnitude better. For a graphical intuition of the fit achieved, Figure 1 depicts the true and the

estimated marginal distribution of types for good 1 from experiment E of the simple model.

We also run a parallel set of Monte Carlo experiments for a forward-looking model, which is

based on the identification example presented earlier in the paper. Now bidders pay attention to the

good being auctioned in the next period, which means we now have four public states. Results are

presented in Table 2. While the more complicated structure of the model has a cost in precision,

both estimators continue to dramatically outperform the naive approach under all specifications.

Note that the cost in precision is much more severe for the nonparametric approach– this is because,

with four states instead of two, the sample of bidders for which we observe bids in every state is

much smaller.

Finally, we run the same set of experiments for a backwards-looking variation on the model.

In this version, the public state variable consists of the product being auctioned today as well as a

dummy for whether there were more than 9 bidders in the previous auction. This is meant to capture

inference regarding the level of demand. Results are presented in Table 3. It turns out that the level

27For a candidate distribution fn(x) and a true distribution f(x) this is calculated according to MISE =∫

(fn(x)−f(x))2dF (x)

80

of demand only affects the bidding strategies of a small fraction of types significantly. Estimation

performs roughly on par with that in the forward-looking model. As in that case, however, while

estimates of σ12 are within two standard deviations of the truth, when the truth is nonzero the

results consistently exhibit attenuation.

4.6 Conclusion

We have developed an estimable demand system for a large auction market. By defining and

focusing on competitive Markov equilibria, we got an intuitive and tractable characterization of

bidder strategies. We also showed existence of equilibrium, arguing that regardless of the initial

conditions of the market, there is strong convergence to a stationary type distribution. A key result

was that demand is identified from panel data, in which the same bidder is observed repeatedly

bidding in different states.

Turning to estimation, we outlined two different approaches for recovering the distribution of

types. These were tested by Monte Carlo simulation. From these exercises, we learned that ac-

counting for dynamics and allowing for multiple products is important. Naıve estimates based on

treating the data as a cross-section are systematically biased downwards, and are unable to account

for correlation in the valuations for different products.

Understanding these basic empirical problems will be helpful for future research. We hope also

that this is a first step towards obtaining satisfying models for other markets: those where bidders

have market power, or non-unit demand. In future work, we would like to take this model to data

and see how it performs.

4.7 Appendix

Proof of Lemma 10: Conditional on a positive bid, the expected payoff function π(b, s) has the

form:

π(b, s) =

∫ b

0

(xt −B1)g(B1|s)dB1 +

(∫ ∞b

g(B1|s)dB1

)(1− ρ)δ

S∑s′=1

v(x, s′)Qss′

since we show in Corollary 1 below that the highest bid has a density on R+. Writing v(x, s) for

(1 − ρ)δ∑Ss′=1 v(x, s′)Qss′ , and taking an FOC in b, we get (xt − b)g(B1|s) − g(B1|s)v(x, s) = 0,

which has unique solution bt = xt−v(x, s). If this is negative, then the corner solution bt = 0 delivers

the highest payoff conditional on a positive bid; and it is easily shown that non-participation ϕ does

81

better still because the probability of winning with a bid of zero is positive (e.g. there may be no

other bidders in the market).

Proof of Lemma 11: By Theorem 11.12 in Stokey, Lucas, and Prescott (1989), uniform geometric

convergence in total variation norm will be achieved if their “condition M” holds: there exists ε > 0

and N ≥ 1 such that for all A ∈ F , either PN (ω,A) ≥ ε ω ∈ Ω or PN (ω,Ac) ≥ ε ∀ω ∈ Ω, for

PN the N -step transition probability. Let s0 = T (0,1) and ω0 = (0, s0) (i.e. ω0 is a superset of

the true state where there are no current participants, nor have been for the observable history;

and upcoming supply is entirely of object 1). Let p0 = P(Et = 0|Nt−1 = 0) > 0, by assumption;

let q0 = P(jt = 1); and let N0 = maxkf , kh + 1. Then PN0(ω, ω0) ≥ ρN (p0q0)N0 > 0 ∀ω ∈ Ω.

Choosing N = N0 and ε = ρN (p0q0)N0−1, condition M holds since either ω0 ∈ A or ω0 ∈ Ac.

Next, consider the marginal ergodic distribution on X N−1×S produced by integrating out the first

non-zero element of the type vector. Since S is finite, there is a well-defined conditional distribution

of x−i given s.

Proof of Theorem 1: Let the action space Ak be a finite grid ϕ, 0, xk ,2xk · · · x

S , with each

dimension totally ordered as written. Endow Ak with the Euclidean metric denoted d, where ϕ is

treated as having value −xk . Here, we define strategies as mappings from type to actions, β : X → Ak,

and write β(x) = (β1(x), β2(x) · · ·βS(x)). For each s, let λ(s) ∈ J be the object under auction in

state s; the mapping is well defined because of restriction (i) on the coarsening T. As in the text,

we call β monotone if βs(x) is increasing in xj if j = λ(s) and decreasing otherwise. Following Reny

(2008), let M denote the space of monotone functions from X to Ak, and define a metric δ on M

by:

δ(β, β′) =

∫Xd(β(x), β′(x))dµ(x)

As shown there, (M, δ) is a compact absolute retract. Define the payoff function u(a, t, β−i), equal

to the value of the game for type t when playing action vector a, everyone else follows strategy β−i,

and the invariant measure over true states is determined as though everyone plays β−i. As Reny

(2008) shows, the interim payoff function U(β, β−i) =∫X u(β(t), t, β−i)dµ(x) is continuous in both

arguments since the type distribution is atomless.

Let Γ(β−i) be the best response correspondence; by the theorem of the maximum it is non-empty

valued and upper-hemicontinuous. A fixed point of the correspondence, β∗, will be a CME, since

then strategies will be optimal given that the invariant measure over types is generated by play of

β∗. The existence of such a fixed point is guaranteed by the fixed point theorem due to Eilenberg

and Montgomery (1946) if we can show that Γ is contractible-valued and Γ(β−i) ∈ M whenever

82

β−i ∈M .

Fix β−i ∈ M and x ∈ X , and let v(x, s) still denote the ex-ante continuation value given

optimal actions. Then we can look at the optimal action state by state, and we have b∗s =

arg maxb∈Ak G1(b|s)(xλ(s) − E[B1|B1 ≤ b, s]) + (1 − G1(b|s))v(x, s). Define bls = maxbb : xλ(s) −

E[B1|B1 ≤ b, s] − v(x, s) > 0 and bus = minbb : xt − E[B1|B1 ≤ b, s] − v(x, s) < 0. Comparing

their payoffs directly, we see that bls yields higher payoff than bus ; this proves that these two bids

could not both be best responses. Next, at least one of these must be a best response — suppose

b < bls is optimal, then xt−E[B1|B1 ≤ b, s]− v(x, s) > 0; but since the payoff function is a weighted

sum of xt−E[B1|B1 ≤ b, s] and v(x, s), and G1(b|s) is (weakly) increasing in b for β−i ∈M , bls must

be weakly better still, and also a best response. The same argument holds on the other side. In

sum, either bls or bus (but not both) is part of the optimal strategy, and the best response is unique

unless G1(b|s) is constant over actions in some state (i.e. β−i assigns no mass to these actions).

Two results follow. First, since bls and bus are increasing in xλ(s) and decreasing in x−λ(s) —

since v increases in x−λ(s) — the best response to any β−i ∈ M is also in M . Second, given best

responses b and b′, the join b ∨ b′ is also a best response, since the probability of winning must be

constant over those actions, and so taking the coordinate-wise max doesn’t change payoffs at all. Γ

is thus join-closed and non-empty for β−i ∈M .

Finally, then, we need to construct a contraction on the best reply correspondence. We slightly

adapt Reny (2008) because actions are not increasing in type in all states. Fix β−i and (β, β0) ∈

Γ(β−i). Let Fi(x) be the marginal distribution of valuations for product i, and define functions

Φs(x) =Fλ(s)(x)−F−λ(s)(x)+1

2 , where F−λ(s)(x) is the average valuation quantile of objects not auc-

tioned at s. Then define

hs(τ, β)(x) =

βs(x), if Φs(x) ≤ |1− 2τ | and τ < 0.5

βs0(x), if Φs(x) ≤ |1− 2τ | and τ ≥ 0.5

βs0(x) ∨ βs(x), if Φs(x) > |1− 2τ |

Define h(τ, β)(x) = (h1(τ, β)(x), h2(τ, β)(x) · · ·hS(τ, β)(x)). It can be verified that h(τ, β) is mono-

tone, continuous and a best reply almost everywhere. This proves Γ contractible valued, and hence

it has a fixed point on M , showing existence for the finite action game.

To complete the proof, it suffices to show that there is a limiting set of strategies in which no

positive measure of types makes a bid b ∈ R+ in any state s (a positive measure of types bidding ϕ

presents no problems). But we showed earlier that for any grid fineness k, either bls or bus is played

83

by every type x against the equilibrium strategy β∗k ; taking a limit as k →∞, we get that strategy

β∞(x) = b for b solving xλ(s) − v(x, s) = 0 is played in some limit equilibrium for all x. Fix this

equilibrium, some state s and some bid b ∈ R+. Since β∞(x) is strictly increasing in xt, the set of

types bidding b must be of dimension J − 1 and thus Lebesgue-negligible. Finally, since the type

distribution is absolutely continuous with respect to Lebesgue measure, this implies the measure of

types bidding b is zero.

For the uniqueness claim, define an operator Γ(β)(x, s) = x− vβ(x, s) on the space of continuous

strictly increasing pure strategies under the sup norm. Showing Γ a contraction mapping suffices to

prove uniqueness:

‖Γ(β)− Γ(β)‖ = maxs∈S

supx∈X|vβ(x, s)− vβ(x, s)|

≤ maxs∈S

supx∈X|Gβ1 (β(x, s)) (x− E[B1|B1 ≤ β(x, s), s])

−Gβ1(β(x, s)

)(x− E[B1|B1 ≤ β(x, s), s]

)|

≤ maxs∈S

supx∈X

G1 (β(x, s))∣∣∣E[B1|B1 ≤ β(x, s), s]− E[B1|B1 ≤ β(x, s), s]

∣∣∣≤ ‖β − β‖

where in the third line we use the fact that Gβ1 (β(x, s)) = Gβ1

(β(x, s)

)for all x and s. This property

holds because under both strategies the same winner is chosen in each auction (types are totally

ordered for J = 1), and thus the transition functions and invariant measures over types are the same

in both cases; implying the distribution functions are equal if evaluated at the bids of a fixed type

x in any state s.

Corollary 1. In equilibrium the distribution G(b|b > 0, s) is absolutely continuous for all s.

Proof: Since the equilibrium bid function is strictly monotone on b ≥ 0, and the max operator

selecting the highest bid is continuous, it will suffice to show that the invariant measure on the type

space µx is absolutely continuous with respect to Lebesgue measure. So fix a Lebesgue-negligible set

A on X N , and let C = A×S. Following Meyn and Tweedie (2009), let L(x,C) = limN→∞ PN (x,C).

It suffices to show L(x,C) = 0. But to reach C, one must draw a sequence of types from A, and

since the distribution of entrants F is absolutely continuous with respect to Lebesgue measure, if A

is negligible, the probability of those draws is zero. Thus L(x, c) = 0, completing the proof.

Proof of Theorem 2: Following precisely the logic of the identification example, we can write the

vector of continuation values of a bidder who bids b as the solution to a linear system V = (I−δ(1−

84

ρ)Q)−1u, where Q is the transition matrix, ρ = ρ1, ρ2 · · · ρS is the vector of exit probabilities and

u = [u1, u2 · · ·uS ] is the S-length vector with terms of the form us = G1(bs|s)(bs−E[B1|B1 < bs, s]).

Notice that since bs = ϕ is possible, we may have us = 0 for some s. Q and ρ are identified from

the data, δ is assumed known and u is identified for any bidder observed bidding in every state.

Also (I − δQ)−1 exists for δ < 1. Given these objects, the ex-ante continuation value is identified

for all complete observations. Now fix any set B ⊂ J . Then to get the valuation vector restricted

to B, xB , we simply add the continuation value to the bid for each of |B| states where distinct

products in B are auctioned, where the bids are positive on B by assumption. Moreover, any type

in the interior of the support of FB has a positive probability of generating a complete observation.

So by re-weighting the density of valuations for complete observations, we recover FB . The correct

re-weighting factor is P (S, x), identified from the data and defined in (4.7) below.

Selection Correction Probabilities: Let A be a subset of S. We want to get the probability

that any type x ends up submitting bids in the states in A. Define p(x, s) = G1(β(x, s)|s) +

(1−G1(β(x, s)|s)) ρ(s), which is just the probability that a type x will exit the sample in state s,

whether by winning or losing. Also define P (B, x, s) to be the probability of a bidder x who enters

the sample in state s being observed bidding only in states B ⊆ S. We can express this recursively:

(4.6) P (B, x, s) = 1(s ∈ B)

[p(x, s) + (1− p(x, s))

∑s′∈B

Qss′P (B, x, s′)

]

Then the probability of observing a bidder x in group A can be defined implicitly as:

(4.7) P (A, x) =∑s∈A

π(s)P (A, x, s)−∑B⊂A

P (B, x)

where π is the invariant measure over states. The idea is simply that the probability of seeing bids

for every state s in A is equal to the probability that the bidder stays within A less the probability

that he stays in a strict subset of A.

85

Tab

le4.1

:M

onte

Carl

oR

esu

lts:

Sim

ple

Mod

el

µ1

µ2

σ2 1

σ2 2

σ12

MIS

E1

MIS

E2

Atr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

4983

30.

2523

499.9

402

100.0

09

100.0

492

98.6

958

-0.6

414

24.6

255e-

005

4.8

577e-

005

std

0.02

3662

0.00

7517

30.2

6534

0.2

6359

4.6

32

4.9

464

4.4

967

1.1

449e-

005

1.1

63e-

005

2es

t97.1

177

97.1

304

72.1

543

71.3

238

0.0

010196

0.0

01067

std

.34195

0.3

1483

4.1

01

4.1

475

0.0

0044665

0.0

0041746

Btr

ue

0.5

0.12

5100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

5022

50.

1262

6100.0

734

99.9

833

99.5

718

100.3

942

-0.6

444

69.6

628e-

005

9.5

621e-

005

std

0.02

4032

0.00

5375

90.3

3802

0.3

1305

8.3

594

7.7

141

5.9

52

1.5

998e-

005

1.4

511e-

005

2es

t94.8

977

94.9

262

59.9

129

59.9

75

0.0

029342

0.0

029148

std

0.4

2577

0.4

2052

4.9

428

4.1

342

0.0

004266

0.0

0034493

Ctr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

50

1es

t0.

4993

60.

2513

3100.0

668

99.9

853

100.1

644

101.7

52

50.7

979

7.9

872e-

005

8.1

255e-

005

std

0.02

0988

0.00

6379

80.2

3694

0.2

5533

3.9

595

4.2

876

4.3

402

1.5

956e-

005

1.4

507e-

005

2es

t96.5

085

96.4

077

65.0

887

66.7

31

0.0

01157

0.0

012266

std

0.3

2974

0.3

1951

3.3

594

3.3

033

0.0

0044747

0.0

003483

Dtr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

-50

1es

t0.

4991

20.

2512

100.0

154

99.9

708

99.6

918

100.9

662

-49.2

951

3.4

979e-

005

3.5

023e-

005

std

0.02

4874

0.00

7295

70.3

6192

0.3

2671

5.4

416

5.4

446

5.0

245

1.3

121e-

005

9.4

455e-

006

2es

t97.8

661

97.8

516

74.9

175.1

188

0.0

0096236

0.0

0097535

std

0.4

2579

0.4

0438

3.8

811

3.9

719

0.0

0041383

0.0

0039483

Etr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

150

100

400

100

1es

t0.

5019

10.

2522

599.9

653

149.9

225

98.8

567

398.8

675

99.1

276

0.0

0010318

1.6

378e-

005

std

0.02

1896

0.00

7705

0.2

3589

0.4

9806

4.7

741

16.1

838

9.5

806

2.0

12e-

005

3.1

715e-

006

2es

t95.7

595

143.7

828

61.4

454

278.0

839

0.0

011407

0.0

0026994

std

0.3

3151

0.7

2523

3.4

637

13.7

853

0.0

0052147

0.0

0011414

For

each

exp

erim

ent

A-E

,p

an

el1

dep

icts

stru

ctu

ral

esti

mate

san

dp

an

el2

the

naiv

ees

tim

ate

s.E

xp

erim

ent

A:

base

lin

eca

se,

wit

hk

=3,ρ

=1/

4,

an

dsy

mm

etri

an

.E

xp

erim

ent

B:

lon

ger

-liv

edb

idd

ers,

wit

hk

=2

an

=1/

8.

Exp

erim

ent

C:

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=50.

Exp

erim

ent

D:

neg

ati

veco

rrel

ati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=−

50.

Exp

erim

ent

E:

Asy

mm

etri

an

,as

wel

las

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s.

86

Tab

le4.2

:M

onte

Carl

oR

esu

lts:

Forw

ard

-Lookin

gM

od

el

µ1

µ2

σ2 1

σ2 2

σ12

MIS

E1

MIS

E2

Atr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

4998

70.

2490

199.9

341

99.8

08

94.8

547

94.8

593

-1.4

892

0.0

0022831

0.0

0022285

std

0.02

1162

0.00

6513

10.2

871

0.2

9919

6.4

142

6.3

335

4.9

616

5.5

919e-

005

4.6

794e-

005

2es

t97.1

755

97.0

25

71.8

718

72.8

582

0.0

0068577

0.0

0063888

std

0.3

3698

0.3

3314

3.4

844

3.7

971

0.0

0034674

0.0

0033673

Btr

ue

0.5

0.12

5100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

4976

80.

1248

799.9

521

100.0

425

97.5

813

97.3

092

-2.9

59

0.0

0042409

0.0

0041063

std

0.02

3491

0.00

5788

50.3

9795

0.4

0503

7.9

82

9.1

703

6.1

737

8.0

64e-

005

7.7

461e-

005

2es

t94.9

433

95.0

142

59.7

917

59.2

406

0.0

019602

0.0

019706

std

0.4

0746

0.4

0215

4.5

596

4.3

055

0.0

0032758

0.0

0026379

Ctr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

50

1es

t0.

4941

0.25

058

99.8

19

99.8

049

91.8

484

92.6

894

42.9

742

0.0

003049

0.0

003044

std

0.02

6691

0.00

6902

40.3

072

0.2

8907

5.9

086

5.3

654

5.2

429

7.1

99e-

005

5.8

35e-

005

2es

t96.4

719

96.4

774

65.7

957

65.7

867

0.0

0083543

0.0

0081302

std

0.3

0472

0.3

4834

3.3

865

3.3

406

0.0

0034527

0.0

0035448

Dtr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

-50

1es

t0.

5036

90.

2507

999.9

49

100.0

644

96.3

282

97.4

392

-44.4

073

0.0

0023373

0.0

0023328

std

0.02

3882

0.00

6943

40.3

2751

0.3

21

8.1

597

8.5

975

5.6

176

5.9

192e-

005

6.2

75e-

005

2es

t97.7

889

97.9

007

75.2

727

75.6

323

0.0

0057612

0.0

0052678

std

0.3

6284

0.3

7382

4.0

511

4.6

602

0.0

0029306

0.0

0032672

Etr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

150

100

400

100

1es

t0.

5050

30.

2505

299.7

609

149.6

732

92.5

428

369.8

52

87.3

218

0.0

0035134

6.9

119e-

005

std

0.02

2175

0.00

6473

50.3

2631

0.5

5967

6.1

947

25.9

437

11.3

395

5.9

314e-

005

1.4

589e-

005

2es

t95.7

264

143.7

643

62.4

126

277.3

82

0.0

0082781

0.0

0019845

std

0.3

5323

0.6

1251

3.5

549

14.2

732

0.0

0041283

8.2

194e-

005

For

each

exp

erim

ent

A-E

,p

an

el1

dep

icts

stru

ctu

ral

esti

mate

san

dp

an

el2

the

naiv

ees

tim

ate

s.E

xp

erim

ent

A:

base

lin

eca

se,

wit

hk

=3,ρ

=1/

4,

an

dsy

mm

etri

an

.E

xp

erim

ent

B:

lon

ger

-liv

edb

idd

ers,

wit

hk

=2

an

=1/

8.

Exp

erim

ent

C:

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=50.

Exp

erim

ent

D:

neg

ati

veco

rrel

ati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=−

50.

Exp

erim

ent

E:

Asy

mm

etri

an

,as

wel

las

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s.

87

Tab

le4.3

:M

onte

Carl

oR

esu

lts:

Back

ward

-Lookin

gM

od

el

µ1

µ2

σ2 1

σ2 2

σ12

MIS

E1

MIS

E2

Atr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

5022

50.

2490

399.5

455

99.4

76

90.5

713

90.0

723

0.8

1214

0.0

0030105

0.0

0032009

std

0.02

2929

0.00

6675

70.2

83

0.2

9668

7.5

447

7.9

162

4.8

788

9.6

654e-

005

0.0

0010594

2es

t97.0

564

97.0

128

66.3

069

66.7

998

0.0

011306

0.0

01079

std

0.3

4049

0.3

4873

3.3

928

3.9

655

0.0

0039424

0.0

0047592

Btr

ue

0.5

0.12

5100

100

100

100

0

1es

t0.

5054

30.

126

99.4

281

99.2

61

94.1

747

93.1

985

-0.9

9954

0.0

0057706

0.0

0060249

std

0.01

8153

0.00

5335

10.3

7785

0.3

5817

9.5

136

10.7

578

6.7

87

0.0

0015555

0.0

0015446

2es

t94.8

876

94.8

948

56.1

622

55.3

11

0.0

030883

0.0

031265

std

0.3

7063

0.3

8293

4.6

828

4.2

582

0.0

0045435

0.0

0048513

Ctr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

50

1es

t0.

5014

0.24

894

99.4

041

99.3

418

89.3

272

89.2

724

41.2

166

0.0

0035513

0.0

0037807

std

0.02

1388

0.00

6063

80.2

7722

0.2

6244

7.4

923

7.6

598

5.9

907

9.6

62e-

005

9.3

648e-

005

2es

t96.3

922

96.3

618

61.9

956

61.7

951

0.0

013294

0.0

013081

std

0.3

4935

0.2

6843

3.4

279

3.4

378

0.0

0033777

0.0

0045434

Dtr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

100

100

100

-50

1es

t0.

5013

10.

2489

899.7

147

99.5

963

92.1

85

90.9

354

-40.2

983

0.0

0031033

0.0

0033724

std

0.02

4505

0.00

6184

30.3

2289

0.3

0584

8.3

661

7.6

269

5.7

865

0.0

0010573

9.9

659e-

005

2es

t97.8

232

97.7

51

68.4

931

68.5

974

0.0

011092

0.0

0095543

std

0.3

5707

0.3

6555

3.4

815

4.2

274

0.0

0030701

0.0

0044662

Etr

ue

0.5

0.25

100

150

100

400

100

1es

t0.

5011

50.

2501

499.2

897

148.9

155

88.1

829

363.6

608

83.7

978

0.0

0040269

8.7

667e-

005

std

0.02

2705

0.00

6559

70.2

8836

0.5

3591

8.3

556

27.3

134

11.0

149

9.2

293e-

005

2.3

743e-

005

2es

t95.9

237

143.5

118

59.2

387

258.8

469

0.0

012831

0.0

0028309

std

0.3

2372

0.6

5581

3.7

201

13.1

16

0.0

0040399

0.0

001278

For

each

exp

erim

ent

A-E

,p

an

el1

dep

icts

stru

ctu

ral

esti

mate

san

dp

an

el2

the

naiv

ees

tim

ate

s.E

xp

erim

ent

A:

base

lin

eca

se,

wit

hk

=3,ρ

=1/

4,

an

dsy

mm

etri

an

.E

xp

erim

ent

B:

lon

ger

-liv

edb

idd

ers,

wit

hk

=2

an

=1/

8.

Exp

erim

ent

C:

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=50.

Exp

erim

ent

D:

neg

ati

veco

rrel

ati

on

inva

luati

on

s,w

ithσ

12

=−

50.

Exp

erim

ent

E:

Asy

mm

etri

an

,as

wel

las

posi

tive

corr

elati

on

inva

luati

on

s.

88

CHAPTER V

Conclusion

The three chapters of this dissertation have endeavored to show the importance and the flexibility

of dynamic modeling of economic behavior, both for empirical and analytic work.

Chapter 1 demonstrated that a dynamic model of firm selection is empirically separable from the

familiar notion of X-inefficiency, and developed methods with an application to Ready-Mix Concrete

data from the US Census of Manufactures. X-inefficiency was vindicated as the primary explanation

for the stylized fact that productivity and competition are correlated.

Chapter 2 demonstrated that comparative statics can be derived from general industry dynamics

models without the imposition of parametric form. Results were obtained for firm turnover rates

and average type with respect to changes in fixed costs of entry and market size.

Finally, Chapter 3 posited a dynamic model of an auction marketplace, meant to represent the

eBay platform, and demonstrated both the viability and, in monte carlo simulations, the importance

of incorporating dynamic considerations in demand estimation for this environment.

It is the hope of the author that these contributions will spur future innovation in general,

dynamic analysis.

89

BIBLIOGRAPHY

90

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Ackerberg, D. (2003): “Advertising, Learning, and Consumer Choice in Experience Good Markets: AnEmpirical Examination,” International Economic Review, 44(3), 1007–1040.

(2009): “Quantitative Marketing and Economics,” A New Use of Importance Sampling to ReduceComputational Burden in Simulation Estimation, 7(4), 343–376.

Ackerberg, D., K. Caves, and G. Frazer (2006): “Structural Identification of Production Functions,”Working Paper.

Ackerberg, D., K. Hirano, and Q. Shahriar (2011): “Identification of Time and Risk Preferencesin Buy Price Auctions,” Working Paper.

Adams, C. (2012): “Identifying Demand from Online Auction Data,” Working Paper.

Ai, C., and X. Chen (2003): “Efficient Estimation of Models with Conditional Moment RestrictionsContaining Unknown Functions,” Econometrica, 71(6), 1795–1843.

Alchian, A. A. (1950): “Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy,58(3), 211–221.

Andrews, D. (1994): “Asymptotics for Semiparametric Econometric Models Via Stochastic Equiconti-nuity,” Econometrica, 62(1), 43–72.

Asplund, M., and V. Nocke (2006): “Firm Turnover in Imperfectly Competitive Markets,” Review ofEconomic Studies, 73(2), 295–327.

Athey, S. (2000): “Characterizing Properties of Schochastic Objective Functions,” Working Paper.

(2001): “Single Crossing Properties and the Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria in Games ofIncomplete Information,” Econometrica, 69(4), 861–889.

Athey, S., and P. Haile (2002): “Identification of Standard Auction Models,” Econometrica, 70(6),2107–2140.

Backus, M. R. (2011): “Why is Productivity Correlated with Competition?,” Working Paper.

Bajari, P., L. Benkard, and J. Levin (2007): “Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competi-tion,” Econometrica, 75(5), 1331–1370.

Bajari, P., and A. Hortacsu (2004): “Economic Insights from Internet Auctions,” Econometrica,42(2), 457–486.

Berger, A. N., and T. H. Hannan (1998): “The Efficiency Cost of Market Power in the BankingIndustry: A Test of the ”Quiet Life” and Related Hypotheses,” The Review of Economics andStatistics, 80(3), 454–465.

Berry, S. (1994): “Estimating Discrete Choice Models of Product Differentiation,” RAND Journal ofEconomics, 25, 242–262.

91

Berry, S., J. Levinsohn, and A. Pakes (1995): “Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium,” Econo-metrica, 63(4), 841–890.

(2004): “Differentiated Products Demand Systems from a Combination of Micro and MacroData: The New Car Market,” The Journal of Political Economy, pp. 68–105.

Bond, S., and M. Sderbom (2005): “Adjustment Costs and the Identification of Cobb Douglas Pro-duction Functions,” Working Paper.

Boone, J. (2008): “Competition: Theoretical Parameterization and Empirical Measures,” Journal ofInstitutional and Theoretical Economics, 164, 587–611.

Budish, E. (2012): “Sequencing and Information Revelation in Auctions for Imperfect Substitutes: Un-derstanding eBay’s Market Design,” Working Paper.

Caves, R., and D. Barton (1990): Efficiency in US Manufacturing Industries. MIT Press.

Chen, X. (2007): Handbook of Econometricsvol. 6, chap. Large Sample Sieve Estimation of Semi-Nonparametric Models. Elsevier, 1 edn.

Collard-Wexler, A. (2011): “Productivity Dispersion and Plant Selection in the Ready-Mix ConcreteIndustry,” CES Working Paper 11-25.

Combes, P., G. Duranton, L. Gobillon, D. Puga, and S. Roux (2010): “The Productivity Ad-vantages of Large Cities: Distinguishing Agglomeration from Firm Selection,” Working Paper.

Doraszelski, U., and M. Satterthwaite (2010): “Computable Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics,”RAND Journal of Economics, 41(2), 215–243.

Duffie, D., J. Geanakoplos, A. Mas-Colell, and A. McLennan (1994): “Stationary MarkovEquilibria,” Econometrica, 62(4), 745–781.

Dunne, T., S. Klimek, and J. Schmitz (2010): “Competition and Productivity: Evidence from thePost-WWII US Cement Industry,” CES Working Paper 10-23.

Eilenberg, S., and D. Montgomery (1946): “Fixed Point Theorems for Multi-Valued Transforma-tions,” American Journal of Mathematics, 68, 214–222.

Ericson, R., and A. Pakes (1995): “Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics: A Framework for EmpiricalWork,” The Review of Economic Studies, 62(1), 53–82.

Fersthman, C., and A. Pakes (2009): “Finite State Dynamic Games with Asymmetric Information:A Framework for Applied Work,” Working Paper.

Foster, L., J. Haltiwanger, and C. Syverson (2008): “Reallocation, Firm Turnover, and Efficiency:Selection on Productivity or Profitability?,” American Economic Review, 98(1), 394–425.

Gowrisankaran, G., and M. Rysman (2009): “Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New DurableGoods,” Working Paper.

Green, A., and D. Mayes (1991): “Technical Inefficiency in Manufacturing Industries,” The EconomicJournal, 101(406), 523–538.

Guerre, E., I. Perrigne, and Q. Vuong (2000): “Optimal Nonparametric Estimation of First-PriceAuctions,” Econometrica, 68(3), 525–574.

Hansen, L. P. (1982): “Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators,” Econo-metrica, 50, 1029–1054.

Harberger, A. C. (1954): “Monopoly and Resource Allocation,” American Economic Review, 44(2),77–87.

92

Hay, D. A., and G. S. Liu (1997): “The Efficiency of Firms: What Difference Does Competition Make?,”The Economic Journal, 107(442), 597–617.

Heckman, J. J. (1979): “Sample Selection Bias as Specification Error,” Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

Hendricks, K., and R. Porter (2007): “A Survey of Empirical Work in Auctions,” in Handbook ofIndustrial Organization, ed. by M. Armstrong, and R. Porter, vol. III. North-Holland.

Hopenhayn, H. (1992a): “Entry, Exit, and Firm Dynamics in Long Run Equilibrium,” Econometrica,60(5), 1127–1150.

(1992b): “Exit, Selection, and the Value of Firms,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,16, 621–653.

Ingster, A. (2009): “A Structural Study of a Dynamic Auction Market,” Working Paper.

Jofre-Benet, M., and M. Pesendorfer (2003): “Econometrica,” Estimation of a Dynamic AuctionGame, 71(1), 1443–1489.

Johnson, K., and J. Kort (2004): “2004 Redefinition of the BEA Economic Areas,” Survey of CurrentBusiness, 84(11).

Jovanovic, B., and R. Rosenthal (1988): “Anonymous Sequential Games,” Journal of MathematicalEconomics, 17(1), 77–87.

Krusell, P., and A. A. Smith (1998): “Income and Wealth Heterogeneity in the Macroeconomy,” TheJournal of Political Economy, 106(5), 867–896.

Leibenstein, H. (1966): “Allocative Efficiency vs. ”X-Efficiency”,” American Economic Review, 56(3),392–425.

(1978): “X-Inefficiency Xists: Reply to an Xorcist,” The American Economic Review, 68(1),203–211.

Li, T., and Q. Vuong (1998): “Nonparametric Estimation of the Measurement Error Model UsingMultiple Indicators,” Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 65, 135–165.

Lippman, S., and R. Rumelt (1982): “Uncertain Imitability: An Analysis of Interfirm Differences inEfficiency under Competition,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 418–438.

McFadden, D. (1974): “Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior,” in Frontiers inEconometrics, ed. by P. Zarembka, pp. 105–142. Academic Press.

Melitz, M. (2003): “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate IndustryProductivity,” Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725.

Melitz, M., and G. Ottaviano (2008): “Market Size, Trade, and Productivity,” Review of EconomicStudies, 75, 295–316.

Meyn, S., and R. Tweedie (2009): Markov Chains and Stochastic Stability. Cambridge UniversityPress.

Milgrom, P., and R. Weber (2000): “A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding II,” in TheEconomic Theory of Auctions, ed. by P. Klemperer. Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.

Mookherjee, D. (1983): “Optimal Incentive Schemes with Many Agents,” The Review of EconomicStudies, 51(3), 433–446.

Nalebuff, B., and J. Stiglitz (1983): “Prizes and Incentives: Towards a General Theory of Compen-sation and Competition,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 21–43.

93

Nickell, S. J. (1996): “Competition and Corporate Performance,” Journal of Political Economy, 104(4),724–746.

Olley, S., and A. Pakes (1996): “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telcommunications EquipmentIndustry,” Econometrica, 64(6), 1263–1297.

Pakes, A., M. Ostrovsky, and S. Berry (2007): “RAND Journal of Economics,” Simple Estimatorsfor the Parameters of Discrete Dynamic Games, with Entry/Exit Examples, 38(2), 373–399.

Pakes, A., and D. Pollard (1989): “Simulation and the Asymptotics of Optimization Estimators,”Econometrica, 57(5), 1027–1057.

Pavcnik, N. (2002): “Trade Liberalization, Exit, and Productivity Improvements: Evidence from ChileanPlants,” Review of Economic Studies, 69(1), 245–276.

Pesendorfer, M., and P. Schmidt-Dengler (2003): “Identification and Estimation of DynamicGames,” Working Paper.

Raith, M. (2003): “Competition, Risk, and Managerial Incentives,” The American Economic Review,93(4), 1425–1436.

Reny, P. (2008): “On the Existence of Monotone Equilibria in Bayesian Games,” Working Paper.

Said, M. (2012): “Auctions with Dynamic Populations: Efficiency and Revenue Maximization,” WorkingPaper.

Sailer, K. (2012): “Searching the eBay Marketplace,” Working Paper.

Satterthwaite, M., and A. Shneyerov (2007): “Dynamic Matching, Two-Sided Incomplete Informa-tion and Participation Costs: Existence and Convergence to Perfect Competition,” Econometrica,75(1), 155–200.

Schmidt, K. M. (1997): “Managerial Incentives and Product Market Competition,” The Review ofEconomic Studies, 64(2), 191–213.

Schmitz, J. A. (2005): “What Determines Productivity? Lessons from the Dramatic Recovery of theUS and Canadian Iron Ore Industries Following Their Early 1980s Crisis,” Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 113(3), 582–625.

Stigler, G. (1976): “The Xistence of X-Efficiency,” The American Economic Review, 66(1), 213–216.

Stokey, N., R. Lucas, and E. Prescott (1989): Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. HarvardUniversity Press.

Sutton, J. (1991): Sunk Costs and Market Structure. MIT Press.

Syverson, C. (2004): “Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example,” Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 112(6), 1181–1222.

(2008): “Markets: Ready-Mix Concrete,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(1), 217–233.

Vives, X. (2009): “Strategic Complementarity in Multi-Stage Games,” Economic Theory, 40(1), 151–171.

Weintraub, G., L. Benkard, and B. Van Roy (2008): “Markov Perfect Industry Dynamics withMany Firms,” Econometrica, 76(6), 1375–1411.

Williamson, O. (1968): “Economics as an Antitrust Defense: The Welfare Tradeoffs,” American Eco-nomic Review, 58(1), 18–36.

Wolinsky, A. (1988): “Dynamic Markets with Competitive Bidding,” The Review of Economic Studies,55(1), 71–84.

94

Zeithammer, R. (2006): “Forward-Looking Bidding in Online Auctions,” Journal of Marketing Research,43(3), 462–476.

(2012): “Sequential Auctions with Information About Future Goods,” Working Paper.

95