chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great...

34
>> Externalities Section 1: The Economics of Pollution chapter 19 Pollution is a bad thing. Yet most pollution is a side effect of activities that provide us with good things: our air is polluted by power plants generating the electricity that lights our cities, and our rivers are damaged by fertilizer runoff from farms that grow our food. Why don’t we accept a certain amount of pollution as the cost of a good life? Actually, we do. Even highly committed environmentalists don’t think that we can or should completely eliminate pollution—even an environmentally conscious socie- ty would accept some pollution as the cost of producing useful goods and services. What environmentalists argue is that unless there is a strong and effective environ- mental policy, our society will generate too much pollution—too much of a bad thing. And the great majority of economists agree. To see why, we need a framework that lets us think about how much pollution a society should have. We’ll then be able to see why a market economy, left to itself, will produce more pollution than it should. We’ll start by adopting the simplest framework to study the problem—assuming that the amount of pollution emitted by a polluter is directly observable and controllable.

Upload: others

Post on 06-Nov-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

>>Externalities

Section 1: The Economics of Pollution

chap

ter

19Pollution is a bad thing. Yet most pollution is a side effect of activities that provide uswith good things: our air is polluted by power plants generating the electricity thatlights our cities, and our rivers are damaged by fertilizer runoff from farms that growour food. Why don’t we accept a certain amount of pollution as the cost of a good life?

Actually, we do. Even highly committed environmentalists don’t think that we canor should completely eliminate pollution—even an environmentally conscious socie-ty would accept some pollution as the cost of producing useful goods and services.What environmentalists argue is that unless there is a strong and effective environ-mental policy, our society will generate too much pollution—too much of a bad thing.And the great majority of economists agree.

To see why, we need a framework that lets us think about how much pollution asociety should have. We’ll then be able to see why a market economy, left to itself, willproduce more pollution than it should. We’ll start by adopting the simplest frameworkto study the problem—assuming that the amount of pollution emitted by a polluter isdirectly observable and controllable.

Page 2: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Costs and Benefits of PollutionHow much pollution should society allow? We learned in Chapter 7 that “how much”decisions always involve comparing the marginal benefit from an additional unit ofsomething with the marginal cost of that additional unit. The same is true of pollution.

The marginal social cost of pollution is the additional cost imposed on societyas a whole by an additional unit of pollution. For example, acid rain damages fish-eries, crops, and forests, and each additional ton of sulfur dioxide released into theatmosphere increases the damage.

The marginal social benefit of pollution—the additional gain to society from anadditional unit of pollution—may seem like a confusing concept. What’s good aboutpollution? However, avoiding pollution requires using scarce resources that could havebeen used to produce other goods and services. For example, to reduce the quantity of

sulfur dioxide they emit, power companies must either buyexpensive low-sulfur coal or install special scrubbers to removesulfur from their emissions. The more sulfur dioxide they areallowed to emit, the lower these extra costs. Suppose that we cancalculate how much money the power industry would save if itwere allowed to emit an additional ton of sulfur dioxide. That sav-ing is the marginal benefit to society of emitting an extra ton ofsulfur dioxide.

Using hypothetical numbers, Figure 19-1 shows how we candetermine the socially optimal quantity of pollution—thequantity of pollution society would choose if all its costs andbenefits were fully accounted for. The upward-sloping marginalsocial cost curve, MSC, shows how the marginal cost to societyof an additional ton of pollution emissions varies with the quan-tity of emissions. (An upward slope is likely because nature canoften safely handle low levels of pollution but is increasingly

2 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

P I T F A L L S

so how do you measure the marginal social cost of pollution?It might be confusing to think of marginal social cost—after all, we have up to this point always defined margin-al cost as being incurred by an individual or a firm, notsociety as a whole. But it is easily understandable oncewe link it to the familiar concept of willingness to pay:the marginal social cost of a unit of pollution is equal tothe highest willingness to pay among all members of socie-ty to avoid that unit of pollution. But calculating the truecost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is adifficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the truemarginal social cost of pollution.

The marginal social cost of pollutionis the additional cost imposed onsociety as a whole by an additionalunit of pollution.The marginal social benefit of pollu-tion is the additional gain to societyas a whole from an additional unit ofpollution.The socially optimal quantity of pol-lution is the quantity of pollution thatsociety would choose if all the costsand benefits of pollution were fullyaccounted for.

Page 3: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

harmed as pollution reaches high levels.) The marginal social benefit curve, MSB, isdownward sloping because it is progressively harder, and therefore more expensive, toachieve a further reduction in pollution as the total amount of pollution falls—increas-ingly more expensive technology must be used. As a result, as pollution falls, the cost

3 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

Figure 19-1

Marginal socialcost, marginalsocial benefit

Quantity ofpollution

emissions (tons)

QOPT0

$200

Marginal socialcost, MSC,of pollution

Marginal socialbenefit, MSB,of pollution

O

Socially optimalquantity ofpollution

Socially optimalpoint

The Socially Optimal Quantity of Pollution

Pollution yields both costs and benefits. Herethe curve MSC shows how the marginal cost tosociety as a whole from emitting one more tonof pollution emissions depends on the quantityof emissions. The curve MSB shows how themarginal benefit to society as a whole of emit-ting an additional ton of pollution emissionsdepends on the quantity of pollution emissions.The socially optimal quantity of pollution isQOPT ; at that quantity, the marginal social bene-fit of pollution is equal to the marginal socialcost, corresponding to $200.

Page 4: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

savings to a polluter of being allowed to emit one more ton rises.The socially optimal quantity of pollution in this example isn’t zero. It’s QOPT , the

quantity corresponding to point O, where MSB crosses MSC. At QOPT , the marginalsocial benefit from an additional ton of emissions and its marginal social cost areequalized at $200.

But will a market economy, left to itself, arrive at the socially optimal quantity ofpollution? No, it won’t.

Pollution: An External CostPollution yields both benefits and costs to society. But in a market economy withoutgovernment intervention, those who benefit from pollution—like the owners of powercompanies—decide how much pollution occurs. They have no incentive to take intoaccount the costs of pollution that they impose on others.

To see why, remember the nature of the benefits and costs from pollution. For pol-luters, the benefits take the form of monetary savings: by emitting an extra ton of sul-fur dioxide, any given polluter saves the cost of buying expensive, low-sulfur coal orinstalling pollution-control equipment. So the benefits of pollution accrue directly tothe polluters.

The costs of pollution, though, fall on people who have no say in the decisionabout how much pollution takes place: people who fish in northeastern lakes do notcontrol the decisions of power plants.

Figure 19-2 shows the result of this asymmetry between who reaps the benefits andwho pays the costs. In a market economy without government intervention to protectthe environment, only the benefits of pollution are taken into account in choosingthe quantity of pollution. So the quantity of emissions won’t be at the socially opti-mal quantity QOPT ; it will be QMKT , the quantity at which the marginal social benefitof an additional ton of pollution is zero, but the marginal social cost of that addi-tional ton is much larger—$400. The quantity of pollution in a market economy

4 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

P I T F A L L S

so how do you meas-ure the marginalsocial benefit of pol-lution?Similar to the problem of meas-uring the marginal social cost ofpollution, the concept of will-ingness to pay helps us under-stand the marginal social benefitof pollution in contrast to themarginal benefit to an individualor firm. The marginal social ben-efit of a unit of pollution is sim-ply equal to the highestwillingness to pay for the rightto emit that unit across all pol-luters. But unlike the marginalsocial cost of pollution, thevalue of the marginal social ben-efit of pollution is a numberlikely to be known—to polluters,that is.

Page 5: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

without government intervention will be higher than its socially optimal quantity.(The Pigouvian tax noted in Figure 19-2 will be explained shortly.)

The reason is that in the absence of government intervention, those who derive thebenefits from pollution—in this case, the owners of power plants—don’t have to com-pensate those who bear the costs. So the marginal cost of pollution to any given

5 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

Figure 19-2

Marginal socialcost, marginalsocial benefit

Quantity of pollutionemissions (tons)

QMKTQHQOPT0

$400

300

200

100

MSC of pollution

MSB of pollution

O

Marginalsocialcost at QMKT

OptimalPigouviantax onpollution

Socially optimalquantity of pollution

Marginalsocialbenefitat QMKT

Market-determinedquantity of pollution

The market outcome is inefficient: marginalsocial costof pollutionexceeds marginal social benefit.

Why a Market EconomyProduces Too Much Pollution

In the absence of governmentintervention, the quantity of pollu-tion will be QMKT, the level at whichthe marginal social benefit of pol-lution to polluters is zero. This isan inefficiently high quantity ofpollution: the marginal social cost,$400, greatly exceeds the marginalsocial benefit, $0. An optimalPigouvian tax of $200, the value ofthe marginal social cost of pollu-tion when it equals the marginalsocial benefit of pollution, canmove the market to the sociallyoptimal quantity of pollution, QOPT.>web...

Page 6: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

polluter is zero: polluters have no incentive to limit the amount of emissions. Forexample, before the Clean Air Act of 1970, midwestern power plants used the cheapest type of coal available, regardless of how much pollution it caused, and didnothing to scrub their emissions.

The environmental costs of pollution are the best-known and most importantexample of an external cost—an uncompensated cost that an individual or firmimposes on others. There are many other examples of external costs besides pollution.Another important, and certainly very familiar, external cost is traffic congestion—anindividual who chooses to drive during rush hour increases congestion and soincreases the travel time of other drivers.

We’ll see later in this chapter that there are also important examples of external benefits, benefits that individuals or firms confer on others without receiving compen-sation. External costs and benefits are jointly known as externalities, with external costscalled negative externalities and external benefits called positive externalities.

As we’ve already suggested, externalities can lead to individual decisions that arenot optimal for society as a whole. Let’s take a closer look at why, focusing on the caseof pollution.

The Inefficiency of Excess PollutionWe have just shown that in the absence of government action, the quantity of pollu-tion will be inefficient: polluters will pollute up to the point at which the marginal socialbenefit of pollution is zero, as shown by the pollution quantity QMKT in Figure 19-2.Recall that an outcome is inefficient if some people could be made better off withoutmaking others worse off. In Chapter 6 we showed why the market equilibrium quanti-ty in a perfectly competitive market is the efficient quantity of the good, the quantitythat maximizes total surplus. Here, we can use a variation of that analysis to show howthe presence of a negative externality upsets that result.

Because the marginal social benefit of pollution is zero at QMKT , reducing the quan-

6 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

An external cost is an uncompen-sated cost that an individual or firmimposes on others.

An external benefit is a benefit thatan individual or firm confers on oth-ers without receiving compensation.

External costs and benefits areknown as externalities; externalcosts are negative externalities,and external benefits are positiveexternalities.

Page 7: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

tity of pollution by one ton would subtract very little from the total social benefit frompollution. In other words, the benefit to polluters to that last unit of pollution is verylow—virtually zero. Meanwhile, the marginal social cost imposed on the rest of societyof that last ton of pollution at QMKT is quite high—$400. This means that by reducingthe quantity of pollution at QMKT by one ton, the total social cost of pollution falls by$400, while total social benefits fall by virtually zero. So total surplus rises by approxi-mately $400 if the quantity of pollution at QMKT is reduced by one ton.

If the quantity of pollution is reduced further, there will be more gains in total sur-plus, though they will be smaller. For example, if the quantity of pollution is QH inFigure 19-2, the marginal social benefit of a ton of pollution is $100, but the margin-al social cost is still $300. This means that reducing the quantity of pollution by oneton leads to a net gain in total surplus of approximately $300 − $100 = $200. This tellsus that QH is still an inefficiently high quantity of pollution. Only if the quantity ofpollution is reduced to QOPT , where the marginal social cost and the marginal socialbenefit of an additional ton of pollution are both $200, is the outcome efficient.

Private Solutions to ExternalitiesCan the private sector solve the problem of externalities without government inter-vention? Bear in mind that when an outcome is inefficient, there is potentially a dealthat makes people better off. Why don’t individuals find a way to make that deal?

In an influential 1960 article, the economist and Nobel laureate Ronald Coasepointed out that in an ideal world the private sector could indeed deal with all exter-nalities. According to the Coase theorem, even in the presence of externalities aneconomy can always reach an efficient solution provided that the costs of making adeal are sufficiently low. The costs of making a deal are known as transaction costs.

To get a sense of Coase’s argument, imagine two neighbors, Mick and Britney, whoboth like to barbecue in their backyards on summer afternoons. Mick likes to playgolden oldies on his boombox while barbecuing; but this annoys Britney, who can’t

7 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

According to the Coase theorem,even in the presence of externalitiesan economy can always reach anefficient solution as long as transac-tion costs—the costs to individualsof making a deal—are sufficientlylow.

Page 8: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

stand that kind of music.Who prevails? You might think that it depends on the legal rights involved in the

case: if the law says that Mick has the right to play whatever music he wants, Britneyjust has to suffer; if the law says that Mick needs Britney’s consent to play music inhis backyard, Mick has to live without his favorite music while barbecuing.

But as Coase pointed out, the outcome need not be determined by legal rights,because Britney and Mick can make a private deal. Even if Mick has the right to playhis music, Britney could pay him not to. Even if Mick can’t play the music withoutan OK from Britney, he can offer to pay her to give that OK. These payments allowthem to reach an efficient solution, regardless of who has the legal upper hand. Ifthe benefit of the music to Mick exceeds its cost to Britney, the music will go on; ifthe benefit to Mick is less than the cost to Britney, there will be silence.

The implication of Coase’s analysis is that externalities need not lead to ineffi-ciency because individuals have an incentive to make mutually beneficial deals—dealsthat lead them to take externalities into account when making decisions. When indi-viduals do take externalities into account when making decisions, economists say thatthey internalize the externality. If externalities are fully internalized, the outcomeis efficient even without government intervention.

Why can’t individuals always internalize externalities? Our barbecue example implici-ty assumes the transaction costs are low enough for Mick and Britney to be able to makea deal. In many situations involving externalities, however, transaction costs prevent indi-viduals from making efficient deals. Examples of transaction costs include the following:

■ The costs of communication among the interested parties—costs that may be veryhigh if many people are involved

■ The costs of making legally binding agreements—costs that may be high if theemployment of expensive lawyers is required

8 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

When individuals take external costsor benefits into account, they inter-nalize the externality.

Page 9: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

■ Costly delays involved in bargaining—even if there is a potentially beneficial deal,both sides may hold out in an effort to extract more favorable terms, leading toincreased effort and forgone utility

In some cases, people do find ways to reduce transaction costs, allowing them tointernalize externalities. For example, many people live in private communities thatset rules for home maintenance and behavior, making bargaining between neighborsunnecessary. But in many other cases, transaction costs are too high to make it pos-sible to deal with externalities through private action. For example, tens of millionsof people are adversely affected by acid rain. It would be prohibitively expensive to tryto make a deal among all those people and all those power companies.

When transaction costs prevent the private sector from dealing with externalities,it is time to look for government solutions. We turn to public policy in the nextsection. ■

9 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 1 : T H E E C O N O M I C S O F P O L L U T I O N

Page 10: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

>>Externalities

Section 2: Policies Toward Pollution

chap

ter

19Before 1970, there were no rules governing the amount of sulfur dioxide power plantsin the United States could emit—which is why acid rain got to be such a problem. After1970, the Clean Air Act set rules about sulfur dioxide emissions—and the acidity ofrainfall declined significantly. Economists argued, however, that a more flexible sys-tem of rules that exploited the effectiveness of markets could achieve lower pollutionat less cost. In 1990 this theory was put into effect with a modified version of theClean Air Act. And guess what? The economists were right!

In this section we’ll look at the policies governments use to deal with pollutionand at how economic analysis has been used to improve those policies.

Environmental StandardsThe most serious external costs in the modern world are surely those associated withactions that damage the environment—air pollution, water pollution, habitatdestruction, and so on. Protection of the environment has become a major role ofgovernment in all advanced nations. In the United States, the Environmental

Page 11: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Protection Agency is the principal enforcer of environmental policies at the nation-al level, supported by the actions of state and local governments.

How does a country protect its environment? At present the main policy tools areenvironmental standards, rules that protect the environment by specifying actionsby producers and consumers. A familiar example is the law that requires almost allvehicles to have catalytic converters, which reduce the emission of chemicals that cancause smog and lead to health problems. Other rules require communities to treattheir sewage, factories to avoid or limit certain kinds of pollution, and so on.

Environmental standards came into widespread use in the 1960s and 1970s, andthey have had considerable success in reducing pollution. For example, since theUnited States passed the Clean Air Act in 1970, overall emission of pollutants into theair has fallen by more than a third, even though the population has grown by a thirdand the size of the economy has more than doubled. Even in Los Angeles, still famousfor its smog, the air has improved dramatically: in 1988 ozone levels in the South CoastAir Basin exceeded federal standards on 178 days; in 2003, on only 68 days.

Despite these successes, economists believe that when regulators can control a pol-luter’s emissions directly, there are more efficient ways than environmental standardsto deal with pollution. By using methods grounded in economic analysis, society canachieve a cleaner environment at lower cost. Most current environmental standardsare inflexible and don’t allow reductions in pollution to be achieved at minimumcost. For example, Plant A and Plant B might be ordered to reduce pollution by thesame percentage, even if their costs of achieving that objective are very different.

How does economic theory suggest that pollution should be directly controlled?There are actually two approaches: taxes and tradable permits. As we’ll see, eitherapproach can achieve the efficient outcome at the minimum feasible cost.

2 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Environmental standards are rulesthat protect the environment byspecifying actions by producers andconsumers.

Page 12: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Emissions TaxesOne way to deal with pollution directly is to charge polluters an emissions tax.Emissions taxes are taxes that depend on the amount of pollution a firm produces. Forexample, power plants might be charged $200 for every ton of sulfur dioxide they emit.

Look again at Figure 19-2 in “Section 1: The Economics of Pollution,” which showsthat the socially optimal quantity of pollution is QOPT . At that quantity of pollution,the marginal social benefit and marginal social cost of an additional ton of emissionsare equal at $200. But in the absence of government intervention, power companieshave no incentive to limit pollution to the socially optimal quantity QOPT ; instead,they will push pollution up to the quantity QMKT , at which marginal social benefit iszero.

It’s now easy to see how an emissions tax can solve the problem. If power companiesare required to pay a tax of $200 per ton of emissions, they now face a marginal cost of$200 per ton and have an incentive to reduce emissions to QOPT, the socially optimalquantity. This illustrates a general result: an emissions tax equal to the marginal socialcost at the socially optimal quantity of pollution induces polluters to internalize theexternality—to take into account the true costs to society of their actions.

Why is an emissions tax an efficient way (that is, a cost-minimizing way) to reducepollution but environmental standards are generally not? Because an emissions taxensures that the marginal benefit of pollution is equal for all sources of pollution butan environmental standard does not. Figure 19-3 shows a hypothetical industry con-sisting of only two plants, Plant A and Plant B. We’ll assume that Plant A uses newertechnology than plant B and so has a lower cost of reducing pollution. Reflecting thisdifference in costs, Plant A’s marginal benefit of pollution curve, MBA, lies below PlantB’s marginal benefit of pollution curve, MBB. Because it is more costly for Plant B toreduce its pollution at any output quantity, an additional ton of pollution is worthmore to Plant B than to Plant A.

3 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

An emissions tax is a tax thatdepends on the amount of pollution afirm produces.

Page 13: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Figure 19-3

Marginalbenefit toindividualpolluter

(b) Emissions Tax(a) Environmental Standards

0 600400200

$600

Emissionstax

200

B has a higher marginal benefit of pollution and reduces emissions by only 200 tons.

A has a lower marginal benefit of pollution and reduces emissions by 400 tons.

Marginalbenefit toindividualpolluter

Quantity ofpollution

emissions(tons)

Quantity ofpollution

emissions (tons)

0 600300

$600

150

300

Environmental standard forces both plants to cut emissions by half.

Without governmentaction, each plant emits 600 tons.

MBBMBB

MBA MBA

TA

SA

SB

TB

Environmental Standards versus Emissions Taxes

4 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Page 14: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

In the absence of government action, we know that polluters will pollute until themarginal social benefit of an additional unit of emissions is equal to zero. Recall thatthe marginal social benefit of pollution is the cost savings, at the margin, to pollutersof an additional unit of pollution. This means that without government interventioneach plant will pollute until its own marginal benefit of pollution is equal to zero. Thiscorresponds to an emissions quantity of 600 tons each for Plants A and B—the quan-tity of pollution at which MBA and MBB are each equal to zero. So although Plant Aand Plant B value a ton of emissions differently, without government action they willeach choose to emit the same amount of pollution.

Now suppose that the government decides that overall pollution from this indus-try should be cut in half, from 1,200 tons to 600 tons. Panel (a) of Figure 19-3 showshow this might be achieved with an environmental standard that requires each plantto cut its emissions in half, from 600 to 300 tons. The standard has the desired effectof reducing overall emissions from 1,200 to 600 tons but accomplishes it in an inef-ficient way. As you can see from panel (a), the environmental standard leads Plant Ato produce at point SA, where its marginal benefit of pollution is $150, but Plant Bproduces at point SB, where its marginal benefit of pollution is twice as high, $300.

Figure 19-3 Environmental Standards versus Emissions Taxes (continued)

In both panels, MBA shows the marginal benefit of pollu-tion to Plant A and MBB shows the marginal benefit of pol-lution to Plant B. In the absence of governmentintervention, each plant would emit 600 tons. However,the cost of reducing emissions is lower for Plant A, asshown by the fact that MBA lies below MBB. Panel (a)shows the result of an environmental standard that

requires both plants to cut emissions in half; this isinefficient, because it leaves the marginal benefit ofpollution higher for Plant B than for Plant A. Panel (b)shows that an emissions tax achieves the same quantityof overall pollution efficiently: faced with an emissionstax of $200 per ton, both plants reduce pollution tothe point where its marginal benefit is $200. >web...

5 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Page 15: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

This difference in marginal benefits between the two plants tells us that the samequantity of pollution can be achieved at lower total cost by allowing Plant B to pol-lute more than 300 tons but inducing Plant A to pollute less. In fact, the efficient wayto reduce pollution is to ensure that at the industry-wide outcome, the marginal ben-efit of pollution is the same for all plants. When each plant values a unit of pollutionequally, there is no way to re-arrange pollution reduction among the various plantsthat achieves the optimal quantity of pollution at a lower total cost.

We can see from panel (b) how an emissions tax achieves exactly that result.Suppose both Plant A and Plant B pay an emissions tax of $200 per ton, so that themarginal cost of an additional ton of emissions to each plant is now $200 rather thanzero. As a result, Plant A produces at TA and Plant B produces at TB. So Plant A reducesits pollution more than it would under an inflexible environmental standard, cuttingits emissions from 600 to 200 tons; meanwhile, Plant B reduces its pollution less,going from 600 to 400 tons. In the end, total pollution—600 tons—is the same asunder the environmental standard, but total surplus is higher. That’s because thereduction in pollution has been achieved efficiently, allocating most of the reductionto Plant A, the plant that can reduce emissions at lower cost.

The term emissions tax may convey the misleading impression that taxes are a solutionto only one kind of external cost, pollution. In fact, taxes can be used to discourage any activity that generates negative externalities, such as driving during rush hour oroperating a noisy bar in a residential area. In general, taxes designed to reduce externalcosts are known as Pigouvian taxes, after the economist A. C. Pigou, who emphasizedtheir usefulness in a classic 1920 book, The Economics of Welfare. In our example, theoptimal Pigouvian tax is $200; as you can see from Figure 19-2 in “Section 1: TheEconomics of Pollution,” this corresponds to the marginal social cost of pollution at theoptimal output quantity, QOPT.

Are there any problems with emissions taxes? The main concern is that in practicegovernment officials usually aren’t sure how high the tax should be set. If they set the

6 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Taxes designed to reduce externalcosts are known as Pigouviantaxes.

Page 16: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

tax too low, there will be too little improvement in the environment; if they set it toohigh, emissions will be reduced by more than is efficient. This uncertainty cannot beeliminated, but the nature of the risks can be changed by using an alternative strate-gy, issuing emissions permits.

Tradable Emissions PermitsTradable emissions permits are licenses to emit limited quantities of pollutantsthat can be bought and sold by polluters. They are usually issued to polluting firmsaccording to some formula reflecting their history. For example, each power plantmight be issued permits equal to 50 percent of its emissions before the systemwent into effect. The more important point, however, is that these permits aretradable. Firms with differing costs of reducing pollution can now engage in mutu-ally beneficial transactions: those that find it easier to reduce pollution will sellsome of their permits to those that find it more difficult. In other words, firms willuse transactions in permits to re-allocate pollution reduction among themselves,so that in the end those with the lowest cost will reduce their pollution the most,while those with the highest cost will reduce their pollution the least. Using ouroriginal example, this means that Plant A will find it profitable to sell 100 of its300 government-issued licenses to Plant B. The effect of a tradable permit systemis to create a market in rights to pollute.

Just like emissions taxes, tradable permits provide polluters with an incentive to takethe marginal social cost of pollution into account. To see why, suppose that the mar-ket price of a permit to emit one ton of sulfur dioxide is $200. Then every plant has anincentive to limit its emissions of sulfur dioxide to the point where the marginal ben-efit of emissions is $200. This is obvious for plants that buy rights to pollute: if a plantmust pay $200 for the right to emit an additional ton of sulfur dioxide, it faces thesame incentives as a plant facing an emissions tax of $200 per ton. But it’s equally true

7 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Tradable emissions permits arelicenses to emit limited quantities ofpollutants that can be bought andsold by polluters.

Page 17: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

for plants that have more permits than they plan to use: by not emitting a ton of sul-fur dioxide, a plant frees up a permit that it can sell for $200, so the opportunity costof a ton of emissions to the plant’s owner is $200.

In short, tradable emissions permits have the same cost-minimizing advantage asemissions taxes over environmental standards: either system ensures that those whocan reduce pollution most cheaply are the ones who do so. The socially optimal quan-tity of pollution shown in Figure 19-2 in “Section 1: The Economics of Pollution” couldbe efficiently achieved either way: by imposing an emissions tax of $200 per ton ofpollution or by issuing tradable permits to emit QOPT tons of pollution. If regulatorschoose to issue QOPT permits, where one permit allows the release of one ton of emis-sions, then the equilibrium market price of a permit among polluters will indeed be$200. Why? You can see from Figure 19-2 that at QOPT, only polluters with a margin-al benefit of pollution of $200 or more will buy a permit. And the last polluter whobuys—who has a marginal benefit of exactly $200—sets the market price.

It’s important to realize that emissions taxes and tradable permits do more thaninduce polluting industries to reduce their output. They also provide incentives to createand use less-polluting technology. In fact, the main effect of the permit system for sul-fur dioxide has been to change how electricity is produced rather than to reduce thenation’s electricity output. For example, power companies have shifted to the use of alter-native fuels such as low-sulfur coal and natural gas; they have also installed scrubbersthat take much of the sulfur dioxide out of a power plant’s emissions.

The main problem with tradable emissions permits is the flip-side of the problem withemissions taxes: because it is difficult to determine the optimal quantity of pollution,governments can find themselves either issuing too many permits—that is, they don’treduce pollution enough, or issuing too few—that is, they reduce pollution too much.

In practice, after first relying on rigid environmental standards, the U.S. govern-ment has turned to a system of tradable emissions permits to control acid rain, andcurrent proposals would extend that system to other major sources of pollution. TheEconomics in Action that follows describes how the system has worked in practice. ■

8 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 2 : P O L I C I E S T O W A R D P O L L U T I O N

Page 18: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

>>Externalities

Section 3: Production, Consumption, and Externalities

chap

ter

19Nobody imposes external costs like pollution out of malice. Pollution, traffic con-gestion, and other harmful externalities are side effects of activities, like electricitygeneration or driving, that are otherwise desirable. We’ve just learned how govern-ment regulators can move the market to the socially optimal quantity when the sideeffect can be directly controlled. But as we cautioned earlier, in some cases it’s notpossible to directly control the side effect; only the original activity can be influ-enced. As we’ll see shortly, government policies in these situations must instead begeared to changing the quantity of the original activity, which in turn changes thequantity of the side effect produced.

This approach, although slightly more complicated, has several advantages. First, itgives us a clear understanding of how the quantity of the original, desirable activity isaltered by policies designed to manage its side effects (which will, in fact, typically occurboth when the side effect can be directly controlled and when it can’t). Second, it lets usevaluate arguments against environmental policy—arguments that arise from the factthat desirable activities are unavoidably impeded by policies intended to control their

Page 19: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

negative side effects. Finally, it helps us think about a phenomenon that is different butrelated to the problem of external costs: what should be done when an activity generatesexternal benefits.

Private versus Social CostsGiven current technology, there is no affordable way to breed and raise livestock on acommercial scale without hurting the environment. Whatever it is—cows, pigs, chicken,sheep, or salmon—livestock farming produces prodigious amounts of what iseuphemistically known as “muck.” But that’s not all: scientists estimate that the amountof methane gas produced by livestock (the same gas produced when a person—heavenforbid!—belches) currently rivals the pollution caused by the burning of fossil fuels in thecreation of greenhouses gases. From the point of view of society as a whole, then, the costof livestock farming includes both direct production costs to the farmer (payments forfactors of production and inputs such as animal feed) and the external environmentalcosts imposed as a by-product. In the absence of government intervention, however, live-stock farmers have no incentive to take into account the environmental costs of theirproduction decisions. As a result, in the absence of government intervention, livestockfarmers will produce too much output.

Panel (a) of Figure 19-4 illustrates this point. The market demand curve for live-stock by consumers is represented by the curve D; the market, or industry, supplycurve is given by the curve S. In the absence of government intervention, market equi-librium will be at point EMKT , yielding the amount produced and consumed QMKT andthe market price PMKT . At that point, the marginal benefit to society of another unitof livestock (measured by the market price) is equal to the marginal cost incurred bythe industry for producing that unit.

Let’s look a little more closely at the supply curve. Assuming that the livestockindustry is competitive, we know from Chapter 9 that the industry supply curvecorresponds to the horizontal sum of all the individual supply curves of producers

2 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 20: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Figure 19-4

MSC oflivestock

S

D

(a) Negative ExternalityPrice,

cost oflivestock

OptimalPigouviantax

Quantityof livestock

QOPT

POPT

PMSC

PMKT

QMKT

Marginalexternal cost

S

D

(b) Optimal Pigouvian TaxPrice,

cost of livestock

Quantityof livestock

QOPT QMKT

Price toconsumersafter tax

Price toproducersafter tax

EMKT EMKT

O O

Negative Externalities and Production

Livestock production generates external costs, so themarginal social cost curve of livestock, MSC, correspondsto the supply curve, S, shifted upward by the marginalexternal cost. Panel (a) shows that without governmentaction, the market produces the amount QMKT. It is greaterthan the socially optimal quantity of livestock produc-tion, QOPT, the quantity at which MSC crosses the demand

curve, D. At QMKT, the market price, PMKT, is less than PMSC,the true marginal cost to society of livestock production.Panel (b) shows how an optimal Pigouvian tax on livestockproduction, equal to its marginal external cost, moves theproduction to QOPT, resulting in lower output and a higherprice to consumers. >web...

3 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 21: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

in the industry. In addition, we know that each individual producer’s supply curvecorresponds to its marginal cost curve. These two facts taken together imply that the industry supply curve is the horizontal sum of the individual producers’marginal cost curves: a given point on S corresponds to the total industry-widemarginal cost at the corresponding output level. But we also know from our earlierdiscussion that this estimation of marginal cost does not include the external costthat production imposes on others. In other words, when external costs are present,the industry supply curve does not reflect the true cost to society of production ofthe good.

In order to account for the true cost to society of an additional unit of the good,we must define the marginal social cost of a good or activity, which is equal tothe marginal cost of production plus the marginal external cost generated by anadditional unit of the good or activity. It captures the increase in production cost tothe industry and the increase in external cost to the rest of society caused by pro-ducing one more unit. Panel (a) of Figure 19-4 shows the marginal social cost oflivestock curve, MSC; it corresponds to the industry supply curve shifted upward bythe amount of the marginal external cost. With the marginal social cost curve andthe demand curve, we can find the socially optimal quantity of a good or activity thatcreates external costs: it is the quantity QOPT, the quantity corresponding to O, thepoint at which MSC and D cross. Reflecting the proper accounting for external cost,QOPT is less than QMKT. So left to its own, a market will result in too much of a goodthat carries external costs being produced and consumed. Correspondingly, withoutgovernment action, the price to consumers of such a good is too low: at the outputlevel QMKT , the unregulated market price PMKT is lower than PMSC, the true marginalcost to society of a unit of livestock.

4 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

The marginal social cost of a goodor activity is equal to the marginalcost of production plus its marginalexternal cost.

Page 22: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Environmental Policy, RevisitedWe have already seen two efficient methods for controlling pollution when govern-ment regulators can control it directly: an emissions tax and a system of tradableemissions permits. Are there similar methods that lead to an efficient quantity of pol-lution when regulators can target only the original activity or good, such as livestockproduction? Yes, there are—although they will take the form of a tax on livestock salesor a license to produce a unit of livestock rather than on the pollution created. Thesemethods will move the market to the efficient quantity by compelling producers tointernalize the externality caused by livestock production in their decisions.

Consider first the case of a Pigouvian tax on livestock transactions. Once such atax is in effect, the cost to a livestock farmer of producing an additional unit of live-stock includes both the marginal cost of production and the tax. If the tax is set atthe right amount, it is exactly equal to the marginal external cost. As shown in panel(b) of Figure 19-4, the optimal Pigouvian tax will move the market outcome to theoptimal point O.

A system of tradable production permits that restricts the industry-wide quantityof livestock produced to the optimal level has the same effect. Suppose that in orderto produce an additional unit of livestock, a farmer must purchase a permit. The costof this permit behaves like a Pigouvian tax, and once again external costs are com-pletely internalized in the private decisions of producers. Even if the farmer alreadypossesses the permit, its opportunity cost—the price it could command in the marketfor permits—acts like a Pigouvian tax.

So QOPT , the efficient quantity of livestock produced and consumed, correspondsto the efficient quantity of pollution generated by livestock production. You might askyourself at this point how this analysis, in terms of the optimal amount of a good oractivity that gives rise to an external cost, relates to our earlier analysis of the optimalamount of pollution. Except for the effect that emissions taxes and tradable emissionspermits have on the creation and adoption of less-polluting production methods, the

5 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 23: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

two approaches are equivalent: the difference between the two comes down to a mat-ter of units. The first analysis was carried out in units of pollution and the second inunits of a good or activity that yields pollution. But regardless of the framework weuse, the underlying method is the same: to find the level at which society’s marginalbenefit from another unit equals society’s marginal cost.

But our second analysis does create additional insights: we see how consumptionchoices are affected by policies designed to counteract external costs. Note that inpanel (b) of Figure 19-4, consumers consume less livestock (in the form of meat pur-chased at supermarkets and restaurants) and pay a higher market price at the sociallyoptimal quantity. (We know from Chapter 5 that exactly how the burden of the tax isallocated between producers and consumers depends on the price elasticities ofdemand and supply.) Moreover, this shows us that criticisms of environmental poli-cies made exclusively on the basis that they “hurt consumers” are misguided.

Finally, you might ask which method a regulator would choose if a choice existedbetween policies that target pollution directly and policies that target production ofthe original good or activity. Generally, whenever feasible it is a good idea to targetthe pollution directly. The main reason, as we mentioned earlier, is that it gives incen-tives for the creation and adoption of less-polluting production methods. This, inturn, lessens the disincentive to produce the good (something, after all, that peoplewant) when the good is targeted rather than when pollution is targeted.

As this book goes to press, an example of this phenomenon is being reported. AFlorida-based company, Agcert, has developed technology whereby methane frompig-waste tanks can be drawn off and either burnt or used as “biofuel” to generateelectricity. The company claims that this technology can achieve an average emis-sions reduction of one ton of methane gas per pig per year, a sizable savings in anindustry where farms can have as many as 10,000 animals. Farmers could then begranted “credits” for their emissions reductions, which they could sell to producersin other industries who want to purchase a license to pollute. Such credits could be

6 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 24: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

a lucrative source of income for farmers, given that the current market price for aone-ton credit for emissions is about $7 to $8. Agcert is currently valued at around$128 million. As some have commented, this invention has given new life to an oldsaying among plumbers and sewer workers: “Where there’s muck, there’s gold.”

Private versus Social BenefitsNot all externalities are negative. In some important cases, an economic activity cre-ates external benefits—that is, individual actions provide benefits to other people forwhich the producers are not compensated.

The most important source of external benefits in the modern economy probablyinvolves creation of knowledge. In high-tech industries like semiconductors, innova-tions by one firm are quickly emulated and improved upon both by rival firms in thesame industry and by firms in other industries. Such spreading of knowledge amongindividuals and firms is known as a technology spillover. Such spillovers often takeplace through face-to-face contact. Bars and restaurants in California’s Silicon Valleyare famed for their technical gossip, and the need to keep tabs on the latest innova-tions is a major reason so many high-tech firms are clustered near each other.

In Chapter 22 we’ll discuss the economics of goods whose value lies principally inthe knowledge or information they embody. For now, let’s just look at the implica-tions of external benefits in general for economic efficiency and economic policy.Suppose that the production of some good—say, semiconductor chips—yields positiveexternalities. How does this affect our analysis of the chip market, and does it createa justification for government intervention?

Just as external costs cause the marginal social cost of producing a good to exceedthe industry’s marginal cost, when there are external benefits from a good, the mar-ginal social benefit exceeds consumers’ marginal benefit. This is illustrated in panel (a)of Figure 19-5, which shows the market for semiconductor chips. Since there are no

7 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

A technology spillover is an exter-nal benefit that results when knowl-edge spreads among individuals and firms.

Page 25: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Figure 19-5

S

D

MSB ofchips

O

Marginalexternal benefit

(a) Positive ExternalityPrice,cost

of chips

OptimalPigouviansubsidy

Quantityof chips

Price,cost

of chips

QOPT

POPT

PMSB

PMKT

QMKT

S

D

O

Quantityof chips

QOPTQMKT

(b) Optimal Pigouvian Subsidy

Price toconsumersaftersubsidy

Price toproducersaftersubsidy

EMKTEMKT

Positive Externalities and Production

Semiconductor chip production generates external benefits, sothe marginal social benefit curve of chips, MSB, correspondsto the demand curve, D, shifted upward by the marginalexternal benefit. Panel (a) shows that without governmentaction, the market produces QMKT. It is lower than the sociallyoptimal quantity of production, QOPT, the quantity at which

MSB crosses the supply curve, S. At QMKT, the market price,PMKT, is less than PMSB, the true marginal benefit to society ofsemiconductor chip production. Panel (b) shows how an opti-mal Pigouvian subsidy to chip producers, equal to its marginalexternal benefit, moves the production to QOPT, resulting inhigher output and a higher price to producers. >web...

8 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 26: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

external costs in this case, the industry supply curve, S, represents the true marginalsocial cost to society of production. The demand curve, D, represents the marginal benefit that accrues to consumers of the good: each point on the demand curve corre-sponds to the willingness to pay of the last consumer to purchase the good at the corresponding price. But it does not incorporate the benefits to society as a whole fromproduction of the good—the technological spillover an additional unit provides to theeconomy as a whole.

To explore this phenomenon we need a new concept, the marginal social bene-fit of a good or activity—the marginal benefit that accrues to consumers from anadditional unit of the good or activity, plus the marginal external benefit to societyfrom an additional unit. As you can see from panel (a) of Figure 19-5, the marginalsocial benefit curve, MSB, corresponds to the demand curve D shifted upward by theamount of the marginal external benefit.

The analysis in this case is very similar to that of external costs. Left to itself, themarket will reach an equilibrium at EMKT, the point at which the demand curve Dcrosses the supply curve S at a market price PMKT. But the quantity of output at thisequilibrium, QMKT, is inefficiently low: at that output level, the marginal social bene-fit of an additional unit, PMSB, exceeds the industry’s marginal cost of producing thatunit, PMKT. The optimal quantity of production and consumption is QOPT, the quan-tity at which marginal cost is equal to marginal social benefit.

How can the economy be induced to produce QOPT chips? The answer is aPigouvian subsidy: a payment designed to encourage activities that yield externalbenefits. The optimal Pigouvian subsidy, shown in panel (b) of Figure 19-5, is equalto the marginal external benefit of producing an additional unit. Producers receivethe price paid by consumers plus the per-unit subsidy, inducing them to producemore output. Such a subsidy is an example of an industrial policy, a general termfor a policy of supporting industries believed to yield positive externalities.

9 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

The marginal social benefit of agood or activity is equal to the mar-ginal benefit that accrues to con-sumers plus its marginal externalbenefit.

A Pigouvian subsidy is a paymentdesigned to encourage activitiesthat yield external benefits.

An industrial policy is a policy thatsupports industries believed to yieldpositive externalities.

Page 27: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

Although the strict economic logic supporting such efforts is impeccable, econo-mists are generally less enthusiastic about industrial policies to promote positiveexternalities than they are about fees and permit schemes to discourage negativeexternalities. This lack of enthusiasm reflects a mixture of practical and politicaljudgments. First, positive externalities—which most often involve the creation ofknowledge and new technologies—are typically much harder to identify and measurethan negative externalities. (A simple sensor can keep track of how many tons of sul-fur dioxide come out of a smokestack. But how do you tell whether and when a newproduct embodies a technology that will benefit other producers and consumers?) Inaddition, producers gain monetarily from subsidies: they receive a higher price thanthey otherwise would. So many economists also fear, with some historical justifica-tion, that a program intended to promote industries that yield positive externalitieswill degenerate into a program that promotes industries with political pull.

However, there is one activity that is widely believed to generate positive external-ities and is provided with considerable subsidies: education! ■

10 C H A P T E R 1 9 S E C T I O N 3 : P R O D U C T I O N, C O N S U M P T I O N, A N D E X T E R N A L I T I E S

Page 28: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

>>Externalities

chap

ter

191. What type of externality (positive or negative) is described in each of the following exam-

ples? Is the marginal social benefit of the activity greater than or equal to the marginal ben-efit to the individual? Is the marginal social cost of the activity greater than or equal to themarginal cost to the individual? Consequently, without intervention, will there be too lit-tle or too much (relative to what would be socially optimal) of this activity?

a. Mrs. Chau plants lots of colorful flowers in her front yard.

b. Anna Crombie and Fritz, a popular clothing store, opens in a mall, attracting more shop-pers who also visit other stores.

c. The fraternity next to your dorm plays loud music, keeping you from studying.

d. Maija, who lives next to an apple orchard, decides to keep bees to produce honey.

e. Justine buys a large SUV that consumes a lot of gasoline.

2. The loud music coming from the sorority next to your dorm is a negative externality that canbe directly quantified. The table below shows the marginal social benefit and the marginalsocial cost per decibel (dB, a measure of volume) of music.

P R O B L E M S

Page 29: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

a. Draw the marginal social benefit curve and the marginal social cost curve. Use yourdiagram to determine the socially optimal volume of music.

b. Only the members of the sorority benefit from the music and they bear none of the cost.Which volume of music will they choose?

c. The college imposes a Pigouvian tax of $3 per decibel of music played. From your dia-gram, determine the volume of music the sorority will now choose.

3. Many dairy farmers in California are adopting a new technology that allows them to pro-duce their own electricity from methane gas captured from animal wastes. (One cow canproduce up to 2 kilowatts a day.) This practice reduces the amount of methane gasreleased into the atmosphere. In addition to reducing their own utility bills, the farmersare allowed to sell any electricity they produce at favorable rates.

2 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Volume of Marginal social Marginal social music (dB) benefit of dB cost of dB

90

91

92

93

94

95

96

97

$36

30

24

18

12

6

0

$0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Page 30: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

a. Explain how the ability to earn money from capturing and transforming methane gasbehaves like a Pigouvian tax on methane gas pollution and can lead dairy farmers toemit the efficient amount of methane gas pollution.

b. Suppose some dairy farmers have lower costs of transforming methane into electricitythan others. Explain how this system leads to an efficient allocation of emissionsreduction among farmers.

4. The accompanying table shows the total social benefit from steel production and the totalcost to steel producers of producing steel. Producing a ton of steel imposes a marginal exter-nal cost of $60 per ton.

a. Calculate the marginal social benefit per ton of steel and the marginal cost per ton ofsteel to steel producers. Then calculate the marginal social cost per ton of steel.

b. What is the market equilibrium quantity of steel production?

c. What is the socially optimal quantity of steel production?

d. If you wanted to impose a Pigouvian tax to remedy the problem created by the negativeexternality, how high would the Pigouvian tax have to be per ton of steel?

3 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Quantity of Total social Total coststeel (tons) benefit to producers

1 $115 $10

2 210 30

3 285 60

4 340 100

5 375 150

Page 31: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

5. Education is an example of a positive externality: acquiring more education benefits the indi-vidual student and having a more highly educated work force is good for the economy as awhole. The accompanying table illustrates the marginal benefit to Sian per year of educationand the marginal cost per year of education. Each year of education has a marginal externalbenefit to society equal to $8,000. Assume that the marginal social cost is the same as the mar-ginal cost paid by an individual student.

4 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Quantity of Sian’s marginal Sian’seducation benefit marginal cost

(years) per year per year

9$20,000 $15,000

1019,000 16,000

1118,000 17,000

1217,000 18,000

1316,000 19,000

1415,000 20,000

1514,000 21,000

1613,000 22,000

17

Page 32: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

a. Find Sian’s market equilibrium number of years of education.

b. Calculate the marginal social benefit schedule. What is the socially optimal number ofyears of education?

c. You are in charge of education funding. Would you use a Pigouvian tax or a Pigouviansubsidy to induce Sian to choose the socially optimal amount of education? How highwould you set this tax or subsidy per year of education?

6. Getting a flu shot reduces not only your chance of getting the flu but also the chance thatyou will pass it on to someone else.

a. Draw a diagram showing the supply and demand curves of inoculating different propor-tions of the population. Assume that the marginal cost of each flu shot is constant andis equal to the marginal social cost, and that the demand curve is downward sloping.

b. Will the marginal social benefit curve be higher, lower, or the same as the demandcurve? Why? Draw the marginal social benefit curve into your diagram.

c. In your diagram, show the market equilibrium quantity and the socially optimal quan-tity of flu shots. Is the market equilibrium quantity of flu shots socially efficient? Whyor why not?

d. Many university health centers offer free flu shots to students and employees. Doesthis solution necessarily achieve efficiency? Explain, using your diagram.

7. Draw a diagram of the supply and demand curves for telephone service. The marginal cost ofconnecting another household to the telephone network is increasing, as it is more costly toconnect another household as the size of the network grows larger. Assume that the demandcurve is downward sloping.

a. Label the market equilibrium in your diagram EMKT.

Telephone service is a positive externality (sometimes called a “network externality”). Thereis a marginal external benefit to connecting one more household to the telephone network,the benefit to everybody else of being able to call the newly connected household.

5 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Page 33: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

b. Draw the marginal social benefit curve into your diagram, find the socially optimalpoint, and label it O.

c. Explain why the market equilibrium EMKT is inefficient.

d. Governments subsidize phone service for rural households. Describe how such aPigouvian subsidy eliminates the inefficiency.

8. According to a report from the U.S. Census “the average [lifetime] earnings of a full-time, yearround worker with a high school education are about $1.2 million compared with $2.1 mil-lion for a college graduate.” This indicates that there is a considerable benefit to a graduatefrom investing in his or her own education. Tuition at most state universities covers onlyabout two-thirds to three-quarters of the cost, so the state applies a Pigouvian subsidy to col-lege education.

If a Pigouvian subsidy is appropriate, is the externality created by a college education apositive or a negative externality? What does this imply about the differences between thecosts and benefits to students compared to social costs and benefits? What are some rea-sons for the differences?

9. Fishing for sablefish has been so intensive that sablefish were threatened with extinction.After several years of banning such fishing, the government is now proposing to introducetradable vouchers, each of which entitles its holder to a catch of a certain size. Explain howfishing is a negative externality and how the voucher scheme may overcome the inefficien-cy created by this externality.

10. The two dry-cleaning companies in Collegetown, College Cleaners and Big Green Cleaners, area major source of air pollution. Together they currently produce 350 units of air pollution,which the town wants to reduce to 200 units. The accompanying table shows the current pol-lution level produced by each company and each company’s marginal cost of reducing its pol-lution. The marginal cost is constant.

6 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Page 34: chaptercost to society of pollution—marginal or average—is a difficult matter, requiring a great deal of scientific knowl-edge. As a result, society often underestimates the true

a. Suppose that Collegetown were to pass an environmental standards law that limitseach company to 100 units of pollution. What would be the total cost to the two com-panies of each reducing its pollution emissions to 100 units?

Suppose instead that Collegetown issues 100 pollution vouchers to each company, eachentitling the company to one unit of pollution, and that these vouchers can be traded.

b. How much is each pollution voucher worth to College Cleaners? to Big GreenCleaners? (That is, how much would each company, at most, be willing to pay for onemore voucher?)

c. Who will sell vouchers and who will buy them? How many vouchers will be traded?

d. What is the total cost to the two companies of the pollution controls under this vouch-er system?

11. Ronald owns a cattle farm at the source of a long river. His cattle’s waste flows into the river,and down many miles to where Carla lives. Carla gets her drinking water from the river. Byallowing his cattle’s waste to flow into the river, Ronald imposes a negative externality on Carla.In each of the two following cases, do you think that through negotiation, Ronald and Carla canfind an efficient solution? What might this solution look like?a. There are no telephones, and for Carla to talk to Ronald, she has to travel for two days

on a rocky road.

b. Carla and Ronald both have e-mail access, making it costless for them to communicate. �

7 C H A P T E R 1 9 P R O B L E M S

Marginal cost of Initial pollution reducing pollution

Companies level (units) (per unit)

College Cleaners 230 $5

Big Green Cleaners 120 $2