international tropical timber council in kuala …...role that interventions in the international...

36
Policy Issues and Options Concerning Linkages Between the Tropical Timber Trade and Sustainable Forest Management London Environmental Economics Centre International Institute for Environment and Development 3, Endsleigh St. , London WCIH ODD, UK Edward B. Barbier Paper prepared for the 1993 Market Discussion on the LEEC Report The Economic Linkages Benteen the Internoii0"o1 Trade in Tropicol Timber ond Ihe S"stdinoble Monogement of TropicolForesis, ITTO Activity (PCM(XI)/4), 14th Session of the International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala Lumpur, 12-13 May 1993.

Upload: others

Post on 09-Jun-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Policy Issues and Options Concerning Linkages Between the Tropical Timber Tradeand Sustainable Forest Management

London Environmental Economics Centre

International Institute for Environment and Development3, Endsleigh St. , London WCIH ODD, UK

Edward B. Barbier

Paper prepared for the 1993 Market Discussion on the LEEC Report The EconomicLinkages Benteen the Internoii0"o1 Trade in Tropicol Timber ond Ihe S"stdinobleMonogement of TropicolForesis, ITTO Activity (PCM(XI)/4), 14th Session of theInternational Tropical Timber Council in Kuala Lumpur, 12-13 May 1993.

Page 2: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Policy Issues and Options Concerning Linkages Between the Tropical Timber Tradeand Sustainable Forest Management

introduction

The following paper is based on the final report for the Activity (PCM(XI)/4) The EconomicLinkoges Benteen ihe International Trade in Tropical Timber ond Ihe S"sininobleMonogement of TropicolForesis (Barbier at o1. 1993). The report examines the extent towhich the tropical timber trade and policies, compared to other factors, affect tropicaldeforestation and timber-related forest degradation. The report also analyzes the potentialrole that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promotingefficient and sustainable resource use in the forestry sector. It is the latter findings that arethe subject of this briefing paper.

Evidence on the linkages between the tropical deforestation, timber production and the timbertrade suggests that the trade is not a major source of tropical deforestation. Not only is theconversion of forests to other uses such as agriculture a more significant factor, but anincreasing proportion of tropical timber harvested in producer countries is for domesticconsumption and does not enter international trade. For example, only 17% of total non-coniferous tropical roundwood production is used for industrial purposes. Of this, only 31%is exported in round or product form. Therefore, only 6% of total tropical non-coniferousroundwood production enters the international trade.

Thus the volume of tropical timber production that actually enters the trade is small anddeclining. As tropical timber resources are depleted and domestic consumption of timberproducts increases in producer countries, log prices are expected to rise and exports fall.However, increased exploitation of temperate timber resources, and possibly substitution byother wood and non-wood products, will keep the prices of tropical hardwood productsdown. Profit margins of tropical log processors will be squeezed, and export marketsdifficultto expand. Thus the main link between deforestation and the tropical timber trademay be the impact of increasing scarcity of tropical timber resources, and thus tropicalhardwood logs, on production and exports.

Nevertheless, there is genuine cause for concern over the excessive exploitation and rapiddepletion of tropical production forests in many regions, including the indirect impacts of'unsustainable' harvesting practices on the loss of non-timber forest values and the incentivesto convert forest land to other uses (e. g. agriculture, livestock ranching). However, a moresignificantimpact may be the role of 'unsustainable' timber production in opening up forestareas to subsequent agricultural encroachment and deforestation. These effects do notnecessarily in themselves support strong statements about the relationship between timberproduction for the trade and tropical deforestation. As rioted above, only a small proportionof tropical logs produced enters the trade directly, and in the future declining log exports areexpected to be only partially offset by increased product exports.

2

Page 3: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

On the other hand, the timber trade can lead to greater net returns for forestry investmentsand sustainable management of production forests, making this option more attractive thanalternative uses of forest land such as agriculture. Unfortunately, in many producer countriesthe widespread prevalence of market and policy failures have distorted the incentives forsustainable management. Failures in concession and pricing systems have produced counter-productive incentives that lead to the 'mining' of production forests. Domestic market andpolicy failures have also had a major influence on the conversion of forest land to agricultureand other uses.

Thus the key factor in reducing timber-related tropical deforestation is ensuring propereconomic inceniives for efficient and sustainable management of tropical production forests.Appropriate forest management policies and regulations within producer countries ought toprovide these incentives so that the long run income-generating potential of harvesting timberis maximized, and any significant external environmental costs associated with timberharvesting are 'internalized'. The 3rdrimg potnr/br In'0's Torgei 2000 is iher40re io rocklethe problem artts source by urging producer countries to improve forest seciorpolicies.

Current trade policy distortions in producer and consumer countries have, if anything,exacerbated the problems created by poor forestry policy and regulations in tropical forestcountries. Although log export restrictions in producer countries have stimulated growth andemployment in domestic processing, they have led to serious problems of processing over-capacity and inefficiency. To the extent that this is the case, log prices are artificiallydepressed and recovery rates fall, thus increasing pressure on timber resources. Althoughimport tariffs on tropical forest products are generally low and declining in major developedconsumer markets, non-tariffbarriers may be significant and increasing. Restrictions onimports depress the global demand for tropical timber products and can feed back to reducestumpage values in producer countries, thus discouraging the incentives for more efficientprocessing and better forest management. Moreover, producer countries will continue toargue that they need to compensate their domestic processing through subsidies and exportrestrictions.

In short, restrictions in trade are not helping to reduce timber-related deforestation indeveloping countries. In contrast, by adding value to forestry operations, the trade intropical timber products could act as an incentive to sustainable production forestmanagement - provided that the appropriate domestic forest management policies andregulations are also implemented by producer countries. Unfortunately, many proposed tradepolicy interventions to 'save the tropical forests' - such as bans, taxes and quantitativerestrictions - may actually work to resincithe trade in tropical timber products. Suchinterventions may reduce rather than increase the incentives for sustainable timbermanagement- and may actually increase overalltropical deforestation. A summary of timbertrade policy options, and their advantages and disadvantages in promoting sustainable tropicalforest management is provided in Table I.

3

Page 4: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table I Timber Trade Policy Options to Promote Sustainable Tropical Forest Management

POLICY OPTIONS

Trade Restraint: Import and export bans, quotas,tariffs and non-tariff barriers are used to restrict or

regulate trade in forest products. Policy options in-clude: export bans or preferential taxes to encouragevalue-added processing; selective import bans; punitivetariffs on "un-sustainably produced" timber; limits ontrade in endangered tree species; national import quo-tas based on estimates of sustainable timber yield.

Trade Stimulus: Tropical timber importers have re-duced tariffs under agreements to liberalize trade (eg.the GATT), but some quotas and non-tariff barriersremain. Producer countries callfor removal of importbarriers, especially on higher processed products.Others suggest selective trade liberalization or targetedsubsidies to promote trade in "sustainably produced"timber and/or to compensate producers for the highercosts of sustainable forest management.

ADVANTAGES

Revenue Mechanisms: International financial assis-

tance is required to support moves towards sustainablemanagement of tropical production forests. Proposalsinclude re-direction of existing trade revenues, eg. taxrelief in consumer countries linked to increased royal-ties in producer countries; incremental trade taxes tofinance forest management; and additional fundingfrom external sources (eg. development assistance,compensatory transfers, forest offsets).

. Relatively simple to administer and enforce (less sofor selective restraints).

. Tariffs and taxes can raise revenue for government.o Selective import restraints may encourage improvedforest management, by penalizing "unsustainablyproduced" products in export markets.. Selective export restraints may stimulate value-addedprocessing and boost employment in producer coun-tries.

Product Differentiation: Many trade policy optionsrequire a means to distinguish between "sustainably"and "unsustainably" produced timber. Proposalsinclude product labelling, in some cases combined withcertification of compliance with sustainability criteria.Certification may apply to forest compartments or toentire nations, or some intermediate level.

. Relatively simple to administer and enforce liess sofor selective stimulus).

. Consistent with the aims of global trade negotiations(eg. the GATT).. Increased export prices may enhance economicincentives to invest in production forest management.. Selective liberalization or subsidies for "sustainablyproduced" products may influence industry or govern-merits to adopt better management practices.

DISADVANTAGES

. Additional revenue may defray the costs of adoptingsustainable management or expanding set-asides.. Increased revenues may help to finance governmentforest service activities or technology transfer.. Increased royalties may reduce over-harvesting andimprove wood recovery rates in processing.

. May be considered discriminatory and protectionist.

. Potential trade diversion to export markets whichimpose fewer environmental or other restraints.. Limited impact due to small scale of internationaltrade in tropical timber.. Decrease in export prices may reduce economicreturns to timber production and thus undermine incen-tives for investment in forest management.. Inefficient wood recovery in protected processingindustry may imply increased log use and deforestion.

. Certification may identify forest operators, regions ornations adopting "sustainable" management practices,offering competitive advantage or ensuring eligibility forstatutory preferences.. Labelling may enable traders and consumers tochoose between more or less "sustainably" producedtimber products.

. May stimulate unsustainable logging if not supportedby appropriate domestic forestry policies (eg. royaltyand concession termsj.

. Liberalization may not effect prices due to coinpeti-tion from temperate timber and non-timber substitutes.. Subsidies for "sustainably produced" products maybe costly and ineffective if not strictly targeted.

. May be considered discriminatory and protectionist.

. Additional taxes may distort trade patterns.

. Consumer country governments may be reluctant torelinquish tax revenue raised on the trade or to provideadditional financial transfers to producers.. Administration and monitoring of funding mecha-nisms may be contentious.. International agreement to new financial transfermechanisms may be difficult to negotiate.

. Certification may be costly, especially at a forestconcession or firm level.

. Competing labelling and certification schemes mayconfuse both producers and consumers,. Schemes may be resisted or ignored if they areconsidered intrusive, biased unreliable.or

Page 5: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

A more detailed assessment of trade policy options is summarized in the following sections.The policy options are grouped into three main categories: (i) do nothing; (ii) measures toalter the pattern of tropical timber trade; and, (111) measures to raise revenues for sustainableforest management.

Do Nothing

The option of 'doing nothing', i. e. allowing existing tropical timber trade policies to remainas they are today ond not implementing addition policy interventions to affect trade patternsand/or the incentives for sustainable forest management, should always be considered aserious policy choice. For example, 'doing nothing' would be the appropriate policy choiceif tropical deforestation was not perceived to be an economic problem. 'Doing nothing'would also be attractive if other policy options - i. e. 'doing something' - appear ineffectiveor undesirable, or if the costs of these options outweigh the benefits.

Another obvious attraction of the 'do nothing' option is that it does not present anyadministrative and institutional obstacles for consumer and producer countries, which wouldclearly not be the case for any new trade policy initiative. Similarly, no new supportmechanisms, such as certification, enforcement, side payments and sanctions, would have tobe devised.

However, given current trends in timber trade and tropical deforestation, and above all,given that sustainable management of production forests is still not widespread in tropicalforest countries, 'doing nothing' is not considered an attractive policy option. In particular,this option is unlikely to lead to greater trade-related incentives for sustainable managementof tropical production forests.

Measures to Alter the Pattern of Trade

Policy interventions that would alter the pattern of tropical timber trade significantly include:i) trade liberalization; ii) trade bans; in) quantitative restrictions; iv) trade taxes; and, v)trade subsidies. Each of these policy options are assessed briefly in turn.

Trade Liberalization

As export restrictions imposed recently by tropical timber producing countries have notreally been adopted to reduce timber-related deforestation, short-term impacts ondeforestation have been minimal. The expansion in processing capacity and the problemswith mefficiencies and over-capacity may have, if anything, exacerbated timber-relateddeforestation over the medium and long term. However, this does notimply that theremoval of these export restrictions will automatically lead to an increase in the incentivesfor sustainable forest management. The available evidence suggests that trade liberalization

4

Page 6: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

could in fact increose the pressure on the resource base, unless well-eat'orced SL, slotnobleforesJ monogemenipolicies ond reg"lotions ore o130 implemenied.

Existing import barriers to tropical timber products in developed market economies dodepress demand for these products somewhat. The main problem appears to be tariffescoloiion - the tendency for import tariffs to rise with the degree of processing of theproduct. Any tariffreduction by developed market economies would most likely lead tomore trade creoiion rather than trade diversion, with almost all new trade created fordeveloping countries involving markets in the EEC, Japan and the United States. However, itis also not clear that timber-producing countries would be the main beneficiaries from theadditional trade created. Newly industrializing countries (MCS) that have no or negligibleproduction forests, such as Taiwan, South Korea and Singapore, currently have a greatercomparative advantage in more advanced processed products, such as plywood and veneer.Thus current tariffbarriers may be discriminating more againstthe MCS rather than thetimber-producing countries.

Non-tariff barriers facing tropical timber products in developed market economies are muchmore significant than tariff barriers. However, it is very difficult to determine the effects ofnon-tariff barriers on the trade, and consequently, what impact their removal might have.Similarly, although the Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) may reduce tariffs fordeveloping countries, the tariff quota/ceiling system operated by the EEC and JapaneffectiveIy imposes quantitative restrictions on key imported tropical timber products, notablyplywood. Removal of this specific quota system, as proposed in the recent GATTnegotiations, would probably have more of an impact on the trade in tropical timber productsthan a general 'trade liberalization' through tariff reduction.

In addition, the tariff and other import barriers in developing countries for timber productsare generally much higher than those in developed market economies. For example, somemajor exporting regions (e. g. Indonesia and Peninsular Malaysia) completely ban the importof timber products. Complete liberalization of the trade would mean the removal of theseimport barriers as well, and by no means would it be certain that there would be a net gainfor these exporters. '

As part of the LEEC study, a trade liberalization policy simulation was conducted to examinethe implications of a 10% across the board reduction in 'transfer costs' i. e. the differencebetween export prices and import prices, as a proxy for the removal of both tariff and non-tariff barriers to tropical timber products. The simulation also included the complete

' Malaysia and Indonesia have been using their export and import restrictions as a means to increase theirmarket power, notably to capture larger shares of the international non-coniferous plywood market. Mostlikely, complete trade liberalization would undernitne this monopoly position.

5

Page 7: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

removal of log export bans from Malaysia West (includes Peninsular Malaysia), Indonesia,the Philippines, Papua New Guinea and West Africa. ' The main results indicate that:

. The reduction of tariffs and the elimination of bansincreases global demand fortropical hardwoods, with significant producer log price increases of about 20%.

. Consumer countries also benefit, arthe increased availability of tropical timber logsinternationally causes a significant decline in the prices of imported logs.

. However, asthe tropical timber producing countries have littlecomparative advantagein processing, they also lose some of their processing capacity to their majorimporters.

. As a result, there is a major shift in the pattern and distribution of tropical timberproduct exports from the major Asian exporting regions, i. e. more log and lessplywood exports. The exception is Malaysia West, which becomes a substantial logimporter in order to expand plywood exports. '

Thus the policy scenario suggests that trade liberalization would most likely producesignificant gains for importing countries, particularly those with log processing capacity.The impacts on tropical timber exporting countries are more mixed. In the policy scenario,the rise in producer log price increases could act as important incentives for sustainabletimber management- butthe scenario assumes that by the year 2005 policies promotingsustainable han, esilevels ore triploce in Indonesia and Malaysia. Without such policies,higher prices could conceivably lead to increased 'mining' of remaining commercial timberreserves in those countries.

However, general trade liberalization for tropical timber products may simply not bepolitically realistic in the current global trade climate. Getting exporting and importingcountries to agree to such wide-sweeping reductions in existing tropical timber traderestrictions would be a very tall order. For example, GATT negotiations for removing justone import restriction - the EEC plywood quota system - failed to obtain agreement onspecific actions. Exporting countries would also be extremely reluctantto remove exportrestrictions on logs, particularly if it would mean loss of processing capacity to importingcountries.

' The policy simulation was conducted using the the Center for International Trade of Forest Products(CINTRAFOR) Global Trade Model(CGTM) for forest products, which is included in minex K of Bathier atat. (1993).

' This reflects the jinimnent depletion of coriumercialinventory in the region, forcing Malaysia West toimport logs to supply its processing industry.

6

Page 8: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

In sum, complete removal of all export and import restrictions on the tropical timber trade issimply not feasible, and in any case, may not be environmentally desirable unlessaccompanied by improved forestry policies and regulations. For example, the extent of non-tariff barriers and their impacts on the trade is simply not well understood. However, eveneliminating the more 'visible' quantitative restrictions and tariffs across all countries isprobably not realistic either. Both importing and exporting countries will most likelycontinue to employ trade restrictions as part of their national strategies for forest-basedindustrialization and protection of domestic industries. Thus the 'political will' for a generalliberalization of the tropical timber trade may simply not be there.

A more realistic approach would be to promote selective 'trade liberalization' steps:

. Encouraging importing countries to revisepoliciesthatclearly discriminate againsttropical timber exporters, such as the tariff quota/ceiling system of EEC and Japan fornon-coniferous plywood exports. For example, exporting countries that showdemonstrable progress towards achieving Target 2000 of sustainable timbermanagement could be allowed exemption from the quota penalties of such systems.The same principle could be applied to other tariff and non-tariff barriers operated bydevdoped market economies on a case by case basis.

. Encouraging exporting countries to review the impacts of theirtraderestrictionpolicies on sustainable timber management, in particular the extent to which traderestrictions exacerbate problems caused by poor domestic forestry regulations andpolicies. Such trade restrictions should only be continued if: I) they do not appear tobe contributing to greater timber-related deforestation; and, 11) if the exportingcountry demonstrates progress towards achieving Target 2000 of sustainable timbermanagement, most notably by implementing well-enforced sustainable forestmanagement policies and regulations.

Tro ical Timber Trade Bans

Pressures from environmental groups and consumer-led boycotts in developed marketeconomies are leading to serious consideration of a complete ban on the import or antropicaltimber products, or at least a selective ban on those products that are not 'sustainablyproduced'. However, despite their popular appeal, the use of such bans would not beappropriate for encouraging sustainable management in tropical timber exporting countries.There are several reasons for this.

First, producer countries argue, with some justification, that a ban on tropical timberproducts is discriminoroiy; i. e. similar rules do not apply to the temperate timber trade. fitsunlikely that they would allow such a policy option to be sanctioned by any multilateralforum. As will be discussed below, withoutthe cooperation of producer countries, an importban would most likely be orbiiroiy and unworkoble.

7

Page 9: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

To extend the ban to include both tropical and temperate producttrade would be even moreunfeasible. Those developed market economies that produce temperate timber also tend to bethe most under pressure from environmental groups to instigate a tropical timber import ban.Given that the global temperate marketis much larger and highly competitive, thegovernments in these countries would probably resist hurting the prospects of their ownforest industries by extending the ban to cover antimber product trade.

More importantly, there is substantial evidence suggesting that an import ban on tropicaltimber products would be mateciive in reducing either tropical deforestation or the trade in'unsustainable' timber - and may be even counter:17rod"dive. Timber production is notthemajor cause of tropical deforestation. Not all(and a declining share) of the tropical timberproduced is for export and an increasing share of tropical timber exports is being absorbed inSouth-South trade. This would suggest that, in response to a tropical timber ban imposed bycurrent importers, major tropical timber exporters (e. g. in Southeast Asia) may be able todivert some timber supplies to domestic consumption, or to newly emerging export markets,fairly easily. For those tropical forest countries where timber exports are not significant, andare not a major factor in deforestation (e. g. Latin America), a ban may have little impact ontimber management or overall deforestation.

In fact, to the extent that a tropical timber import ban does affect the export of tropicaltimber products substantially, it would have little impact on the economic incentives forsustainable management at the concession level, and may actually encourage poormanagement practices. Domestic and market policy failures in tropical forest countries affectthe 'internalization' of the user and environmental costs of timber harvesting byconcessionaires. Major policy changes in the forestry sector will be required to address theseissues, yet by imposing trade bans importing countries may reduce theirpoli!ico/ leverage ininfluencing policy makers in producing nations.

Although in the short run a trade ban may reduce pressure on tropical forests through lowerproduction for the trade, in the medium and long run a ban is likely to have a detrimentalimpact. By eliminating the gains from trade, a ban on tropical timber imports woulddecrease the value derived from timber production and thus actually reduce the incentives fortropical forest countries to maintain permanent production forests. Faced by declining exportprospects and earnings from tropical timber products, developing countries may decide toconvert more forests to alternative uses, notably agriculture. Thus the effect of the ban maybe to reduce log production and exports, but may actually increase overalltropicaldeforestation in the medium and long term.

As part of the LEEC study the effects of a total import ban on a major tropical timberproducer, Indonesia, were simulated. ' According to the results of the analysis, an importban would have a devastating impact on Indonesia's forest industry in the short term (see

4 See minex I in Bathier at at. (1993).

8

Page 10: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 2). Although there would be significant diversion of plywood and sawnwood exportsto domestic consumption, this would be insufficient to compensate for the loss of exports.Net production in both processing industries would fall. Given its export orientation, theplywood industry would be particularly hurt- reducing its output by over 40%. Netproduction losses in the sawnwood industry would be closer to 10%. The overall effectis tolower domestic log demand in the shortterm by around 25-30%.

The policy scenario is of course assuming that the import ban is 100% effective. fitsunlikely that animporters of Indonesia's tropical timber products - many of which are alsonewly industrializing or producer countries with processing capacities - would go along witha Western-imposed ban. In any case, one would expectthat over the longer term therewould be some diversion of Indonesian plywood and sawnwood exports to either new importmarkets or existing markets that prove to be less stringentin applying the ban (e. g. otherdeveloping or newly industrializing countries).'

The long-term implications of an import ban on tropical deforestation are also notencouraging. Even if the ban is 100% effective in the short term, any reduction in tropicaldeforestation resulting from lower levels of timber harvesting is likely to be short-lived. Atotal import ban would cause a major diversion of Indonesian timber products to meetdomestic demand. Although in the shortterm net production of wood products, and thus logdemand, would fall, this situation would not necessarily be sustained over the long run.Even if this is not the case, the ban may be ineffective in permanently reducing tropicaldeforestation because: I) timber production is not the main source of deforestation inIndonesia; and, ii) as the value of holding on to the forest for timber production decreasesthe incentives to convert more of the resource to alternative uses such as agriculture willIncrease.

Many of the problems associated with a coinpleie import ban on tropical timber productswould also apply to a selective import ban on 'unsustainably' produced timber alone. Aselective import ban would also fail to provide the appropriate economic incentives forsustainable management at the forest level, and may also be counter-productive, for thesimilar reasons outlined above for a complete ban, namely:

. Diversion of trode to other inorkeis (domestic, export markets withoutbans, etc. ). Ifthese markets are for lower value products, producer countries may need to supplyhigher volumes of tropical timber to generate substantial earnings, thus leading tomore pressure on timber resources.

' These effects cannot be captured explictily in the model.

' For further discussion, see Barbier (1993), Constantin0 (1990), Vincent (1990) and minex I in Bathier atat. (1993).

9

Page 11: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 2. hidonesia - Timber Trade and Tropical Deforestation Simulation Model

Policy Scenario - import Ban and Revenue Raising Taxes (% Change over Base Case)

Key Variables

I. Prices (Rp/in3)

Log border-equivalent price (unit value)Sawnwood export price (unit value)Plywood export price (unit value)

2. Quantities ('000 in3)

Log productionLog domestic consumptionSawnwood productionSawnwood exportsSawnwood domestic consumptionPlywood productionPlywood exportsPlywood domestic consumption

3. Deforestation (kin2)

Total forest areaAnnual rate of deforestation

Total importBan at

I% Revenue

Raising importTax b/

Notes: at Large price changes were used deliberately to constrain sawnwood and plywood exports to zero inthis simulation and therefore are no longer endogenously generated by the model. Also, the functionalform of the deforestation equation and its estimation using regional panel data imply that the largechanges in log production associated with the import ban scenario cannot be used to predict reliableIthe effects on forest cover and deforestation. Thus both price and deforestation effects are elmxinatedfrom this policy scenario simulation.

b/ A total of Us$23. I million (1980 prices) in revenue would be raised, with Us $5.8 nitllion andUs$17.3 million from indonesian sauniwood and plywood exports respectively.

of A negligible increase over the base case forest cover of 53 sq kin.

d/ A total of Us $113.9 million (1980 prices) in revenue would be raised, with Us $28.5 nitllion andUs$85.4 lulllion from hidonesian sawnwood and plywood exports respectively.

Source: minex I in Barbier at at. (1993).

28.33%

27.37%

10.64%

- 100.00%

30.01%

43.84%

- 100.00%

214.51%

5% Revenue

Raising importTax d/

0.17%

0.11%

0.21%

0.04%

0.04%

0.03%

0.23%

0.06%0.04%0.10%0.23%

0.82%

0.54%1.03%

0.19%0.18%0.14%1.12%0.30%

0.22%

0.51%

1.12%

0.00% c/0.41%

0.01%0.72%

Page 12: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

. Lower political leveroge of importing countries to influence forestry policies inproducer countries.

. Linteposiiive reii!forcement of the inceniives/br s"sininoble monogemeni. Selectivebans would have an immediate impact on a country's ability to derive value fromtimber production, and would act as a disincentive in the medium and long term tomaintaining tropical forests for timber production, as opposed to conversion toagriculture and other uses.

. Generare incentives to circ"myenithe bon. Thereisgenerally high elasticity ofsubstitution for tropical timber products from different sources of origin, particularlyfor higher valued products such as plywood. ' Thus producer countries would gainsignificantly if they could 'pass off' their 'unsustainably' produced timber as'sustainably' produced.

Moreover, selective bans have the additional complication of the need for a non-orbirroni andworkoble international certification process to distinguish 'sustainably' versus 'unsustainably'produced tropical timber products. ' Given the lack of data on forest inventories and offtakelevels, such certification would be extremely difficult to establish in the near future withoutthe cooperation of producer countries. However, there is little incentive for producercountries to participate in this process if it leads to an import ban on their products. Withoutthis data, a selective ban could not possibly succeed. In addition, an effective monitoringand evaluation system would be required to enforce a selective import ban. No suchmechanism currently exists or is likely to be implemented in the next few years' Again,cooperation by producer countries, which would be fundamental to the success of theverification system, is unlikely to be forthcoming. Finally, a selective trade ban is unlikelyto be acceptable in the international political arena - particularly as producer countries willdismiss it as discriminoroiy.

uantitative Restrictions

To some extent quantitative restrictions are similar to trade bans, but usually take a lesssevere form. However, a 100% restriction on the quantity of trade is effectiveIy the same asa complete ban on allinternational trade in tropical timber. Thus, to a large extent, many ofthe problems associated with tropical timber trade bans also apply to quantitative restrictions.

Two quantitative restrictions are worth briefly examining: I) quotas targeted to specificproduct categories, such as timber products derived from endangered species; and, ii) quotasconditional on the level of sustainable offtake of specific species.

' Evidence on these elasticities is presented in Section 4 of Barbier at at. (1993).

' As a number of trade policy options require a sinxilar process in order to be effectiveIy implemented, wethe issue of certification is discussed separately below.

10

Page 13: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

At the 8th Conference of Parties to the Convention on International Trade in EndangeredSpecies (CITES), several tropical timber species were proposed for the Appendix I and finstof CITES (ITTC 1992b). Species given an Appendix Insting are effectiveIy banned fromcommercial trade, or only authorized "in exceptional circumstances". Species listed onAppendix 11 are subject to sinct regulation "in order to avoid utilization incompatible withtheir survival". Of the species proposed for listing at the meeting, mrsio .spp (meTabu),Gonyso^Jus boricon"s (rainin), Swieienio $pp (mahogany) and Pertcopsis eloio (aformosia) areinternationally traded in significant volumes, including by producer countries that aremembers of ITTO. Not surprisingIy, these proposals - which were put forward mainly byrepresentatives of developed market economies at the Conference - were strongly opposed bythe producer countries affected.

Studies of previous attempts by CITES to use quantitative restrictions and bans to regulatethe trade in endangered species suggest that this approach has not been an effective means ofcontrolto date (Barbier or o1. 1990; Burgess 1992). Problems of monitoring andenforcement are exacerbated when the producer countries affected either oppose thisapproach or do not receive adequate incentive (i. e. compensation) to participate. Forexample, at the 8th CITES Conference, Ghana and Cameroon opposed the proposedAppendix n listing of aformosia, and subsequently informed the Conference that the timbertrade was outside the scope of their countries' CITES managing authorities (ITTC 1992b).The lack of compliance by producer countries undermines the effectiveness of such policyoptions.

Similar problems of incentives for management, enforcement and monitoring will exist forany import quotas based on the level of 'sustainable' offtake of specific species that areimposed withoutthe cooperation of tropical timber producing countries. For such a policy tobe workable from the outset, cooperation from producer countries in determining thescientific and trade data necessary for establishing quotas for sustainable offtake and exportswill be essential.

It might be possible to establish a more comprehensive trade mechanism that establishessustainable offtake export quotas for those species that are endangered, thus offering anincentive to both consumers and producers to accept a controlled legal trade and to enforceit. A properly constructed trade mechanism for each endangered species, using economicinstruments such taxes and subsidies to manage trade where appropriate, could be designed toenable sufficient profits from the trade to be channelled back into producer states toencourage management efforts, and to supportimproved monitoring of harvesting and exportactivities (Burgess 1992). However, full acceptance of and adherence to any suchmechanism by affected producer countries are essential to its success in terms of promotingcompliance with export regulations and on cooperation between exporters and regulatingagencies.

In sum, the use of quantitative restrictions to regulate the trade in tropical timber productscan suffer many of the same problems associated with complete and selective trade bans.

11

Page 14: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Although banning or controlling the trade in specific timber species may be a necessary shortterm response if the species are endangered, more effective and innovative long termssolution for management of the trade are required. A more comprehensive trade mechanismthat establishes sustainable offtake export quotas for endangered tropical timber specieswould offer a better incentive to both importers and exporters to accept a controlled legaltrade and to enforce it. '

Trade Taxes

An international trade tax would be a powerful means of increasing the costs associated withtrading tropical timber products. Such a tax could be implemented at either the exporting orthe importing end of the international tropical timber trade. In order for this tax to beeffective in achieving a reduction in the amount of tropical timber products traded, it wouldhave to be sufficiently high enough to stimulate producers and consumers to change theirpatterns of resource use. However, where the tax is implemented will effectthe extent towhich the costs of the tax is passed on to the producers or the consumers,

An international trade tax on tropical timber products suffers from the same sort of problemsof implementation and effectiveness as faced by trade bans and quantitative restrictions (seeabove).

First, it is unlikely that tropical timber exporting countries would endorse an international taxthat would discriminate againsttropicaltimber products. As noted, that these countries haveemployed their own export taxes on selective products (e. g. log exports, and more recentlysawnwood exports). However, the main purpose of such policies has not been to reduce rheoverallirode in tropical timber products, or for that matter timber-related tropicaldeforestation, but to change the potiern of their tropical timber exports to higher valuedproducts - thus stimulating wood-based processing industries.

Second, a tropical timber trade tax would in any case probably be inc:a"eciive in reducingtimber-related tropical deforestation - for the same reasons outlined above in the discussionof trade bans. In the short run, producer countries may increase their volumes of exports tomaintain their level of foreign eXchange earnings. Most likely, an overalltrade tax mightreduce Ihe incentives for sustainable timber management, as the tax would lower the netreturns from production and trade. As a result, the tax may actually prove to be counter-productive by encouraging the conversion of permanent production forests and any remaining'virgin' forest areas to alternative uses in the long run.

fits often argued that some of these problems associated with an indiscriminately applied taxon antropicaltimber products could be avoided by a tax imposed selectively on'unsustainably' produced tropical timber products. For example, selective import duties on

' As an encouraging sign, at the 8th Conference, the ITTO representative rioted and welcomed the call madeby several(government) Parties for increased cooperation between CITES and ITTO (ITTC 1992b).

12

Page 15: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

tropical timber products could be applied, but sustainably produced timber could be allowedin importing markets duty free. However, as argued in the case of selective bans andquantitative restrictions, there are obvious problems of certification, monitoring andenforcement that need to be sorted out - along with the political feasibility of such anapproach. The issue of certification is an important one, and is discussed in more detailbelow.

The economic impact of an import tax on tropical timber was analyzed in a policy simulationfor the LEEC study (see Annex K in Bathier et o1. 1993). The policy scenario simulates thetax by assuming a 10% increase in the 'transfer cost' of products reaching destinationcountries. The results suggest that:

. Some product exports are expected to be driven out by competition with domesticsupplies.

Log prices in consumer countries rise but fall in producer countries. As aconsequence, most consumer countries reduce their imports of tropical timber logs.

With such a large impact on log imports for their processing industries, consumingcountry demand for processed products results in a smallincrease in tropical plywoodexports, at leastinitially. However, as this import demand slackens and as logscarcity in producer countries becomes binding, tropical plywood exports fallsignificantly after 1995.

All tropical hardwood suppliers suffer a decline in production, at least initially.Indonesian production declines up to 2 inn in' compared to base case projections.However, the declines are not permanentin allregions. For example, Malaysia East(includes Sabah and Sarawak) experiences an initial decline of 4 inn in' but its logproduction generally exceeds the base case scenario after 1995.

The net effect of log production declines in producing countries, distortions in tradepatterns and falling producer prices for tropical timber harvesting will be lessmotivation to manage production forests sustainably, as wellreduced revenue tofinance these investments.

.

.

.

.

In sum, a trade tax on tropical timber products would not be an effective means ofencouraging sustainable production forest management, and may even be a disincentive forsustainable management.

Trade Subsidies

Unlike a tax, a trade subsidy essentially reduces the costs associated with the trade andencourages higher levels of trade in tropical timber products. It is argued that a subsidycould be used on differentiated products that are traded internationally to alter patterns of

13

Page 16: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

trade. For example, a subsidy could be levied on 'sustainably produced' tropical timber inorder to encourage the trade in products produced from this timber than from unsustainablymanaged tropical forests.

The rationale for a trade subsidy applied to sustainably managed timber usually rests on thearguments that:

. sustainable management of production forests will in most instances add to the cost oflogging; and,

. prices at the consumer end of the trade chain are not be high enough to create enoughvalue at the forest end of the chain to create the incentives for sustainablemanagement, or ifprices are high enough at the consumer end then the internationaldistribution system of the net returns leaves too little at the forest level to encouragesustainable forest management.

These issues were recently discussed at an ITTO workshop on trade-related incentives held inMelbourne (ITTC 1992d). The report of the Melbourne Workshop argued that only "ifthetrade is not and cannot be capable of financing sustainable management in both the revenuegeneration and distribution aspects should the matter of incentives based on subsidizationcome into the reckoning". However, the Workshop also concluded that there is currentlyvery little empirical verification that the above arguments are correct. The only indisputablefact is that "for industrial timber production to be sustainable, harvesting must have a verylow impact".

For the LEEC study, the implications of sustainable management restrictions were examined,using the policy simulation model of Indonesia (see Annex I in Barbier at o1. 1993). Asurprising result of the analysis is that, even if increases in logging costs of 25 and 50% areassumed, the resulting impacts on the rest of Indonesia's forestry sector, including itsprocessing industries and production, seem to be much less (see Table 3). In particular,Indonesia's sawnwood and plywood exports appear to be the least affected by the increasedharvest costs, which would suggest that external demand factors exert an important counter-acting influence. The impacts of the increased harvesting costs would presumably be lesssevere if sustainable management is 'phased in' over a number of years' In contrast, thereappears to be some direct reduction in timber-related deforestation, but even this may beoutweighed by the improvement in forest management and protection resulting fromqualitative changes in timber stand management practices and ownership. The Indonesianexample would suggest that the need for a trade subsidy is less serious than many believe.

A major problem is that a subsidy for 'sustainably' produced timber exports could easilybecome a disguised means of trade promotion. International competitors would insist onverification that this policy is subsidizing sustainably managed timber only and that theadditional costs of producing this timber justifies such a subsidy. This would again requirecareful and internationally agreed monitoring, enforcement and certification procedures. In

14

Page 17: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 3. Indonesia - Timber Trade and Tropical Deforestation Simulation Model

Policy Scenario - Sustainable Timber Management (% Change over Base Case)

Key Variables

I. Prices (Rp/in3)

Log border-equivalent price (unit value)Sawnwood export price (unit value)Plywood export price (unit value)

2. Quantities ('000 in3)

Log productionLog domestic consumptionSawnwood productionSawnwood exportsSawnwood domestic consumptionPlywood productionPlywood exportsPlywood domestic consumption

3. Deforestation (km2)

Total forest area

Annual rate of deforestation

25% Rise in

Harvest Costs

41.59%

4.04%

2.86%

50% Rise inHarvest Costs

Source: minex I in Bathier at at. (1993).

0.94%

1.37%

1.89%

1.03%2.28%0.87%0.38%3.12%

83.06%

8.09%

5.72%

1.87%

2.73%

3.77%

2.05%4.55%

1.73%0.75%6.24%

0.02%

2.28%0.04%

4.23%

Page 18: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

addition, as the Indonesian example illustrates, it is not anthat clear that increased harvestingcosts put exporting timber-processing industries at a competitive disadvantage. Thus simplybecause harvesting costs may increase as a result of sustainable management practices doesnot necessarily justify the use of trade subsidies for exported tropical timber products. Inaddition, trade subsidies may in fact encourage in<67cient resource use and have adetrimentalimpact on the forest base.

In sum, trade subsidies ought to be a last resort, and in any case, are "no substitute forforest-related incentives" (ITTC 1992d). If the problem is one of increasing the net returnsand incentives at the forest management level for sustainable production, then priority shouldbe given to correcting domestic market and policy failures in producer countries thatdiscriminate against such management practices. Existing trade policies in those countriesthat exacerbate 'unsustainable' and inefficient management should also be reviewed andcorrected. Progress toward sustainable management should come first before anyconsideration of trade or production subsidies be entertained.

However, to the extentthat additional revenue needs to gained from the tropical timber tradeor through non-trade related sources to improve the incentives for sustainable management ofproduction forests, then mechanisms to raise this revenue ought to be explored. This issue isdiscussed next, focussing on the extent to which each revenue-raising measure can be used tocomplement the forest-related incentives for sustainable management.

Measures to Raise Revenues for Sustainable Forest Management

The main rationale for providing financing for assisting tropical forest countries in movingtowards sustainable forest management is that there is an important principle of mrernoiionalcoinpensoiion at stake. There are essentially three reasons for this argument:

. It is often claimed that timber exporting countries receive an insufficientshare of thereturns from tropical timber product exports - at least to incur the additionalharvesting costs and other economic impacts of sustainable timber management.

. Implementation of the forestry policies and regulations required to ensure the properenforcement and monitoring of sustainable management of production forests willimpose substantial additional costs on producer countries that they will find difficult toafford.

. To the extent that all nations benefit from the global external benefits resulting fromsustainable management of large tracts of tropical forest lands, then the internationalcommunity should compensate producing nations for the loss of potential income thatthey would incur by reducing tropical deforestation, timber sales and conversion offorest land to other uses.

15

Page 19: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

As noted in the discussion of trade subsidies, the first pointis difficult to substantiate. Aswill be discussed further below, the issue may be less to do with whether the unequaldistribution of revenues along the chain of trade reduces Ihe incentives for sustainablemanagement of the forest level but whether any excess revenues along the chain can betapped for addiiionolji, rids to assist sustainable management of tropical production forests.

The second and third points are much more relevant to the argument for internationalcompensation. It is now generally accepted, as well as enshrined in the Forest Principles ofthe 1992 UNCED Conference, that coinpensoring tropical forest countries for their role inmaintaining a resource that has value on a global levelis a fundamental basis for multilateralpolicy action. However, the second and third points also suggest that compensation isneeded by tropical timber producing countries for the income they may forego in protectingtheir forests and for the additional costs incurred in implementing sustainable managementpractices for their production forests. This has to be demonstrated empiricalIy.

A policy simulation for the LEEC study was conducted to indicate the additional economicimpacts to tropical forest countries of 'setting aside' some of their forest resource base (seeAnnex K in Barbier at o1. 1993). Essentially, this was simulated by a reduced timber supplyscenario where the inventory of commercial tropical hardwood resources is reduced by 10%- which is equivalent to land being taken out of product forests and permanently protected.The result is that severe shortages in log production and higher sawlog prices are experiencedin tropical forest regions, notably in Malaysia and Indonesia. The modelindicates that suchreductions in supply would result in a loss of wealth for tropical timber producing countries.Over the long run, permanent set asides would mean that the remaining production forestinventory could not support as high a level of sustainable harvest as under base caseprojections.

There are also indications that the additional costs required to implement sustainable forestrymanagement policies and regulations are significant. Drawing on the work by Poore at o1.(1989), a rough assessment of the resources needed by producer countries to attainsustainability by the year 2000 was conducted on behalf of ITTO (Ferguson and Muiioz-Reyes Navarr0 1992). The estimates are shown in Table 4. Although preliminary and veryapproximate, they show that an additional Us$ 330.1 inn is required each year in order toassist producer countries of ITTO in attaining the Year 2000 Target. Moreover, at besttheestimates are an indication of only the minimum financing required.

Sizable though this figure may seem, it is less than the estimated amount required forsustainable management of alitropical forest resources. For example, Agenda 21 of the UNConference on Environment and Development(UNCED) has estimated that internationalfinancing of over Us$ 1.5 bn annually will be required by tropical forest countries to reduce

16

Page 20: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 4 Estimates of the Resources Needed by Producer Countries to AttainSustainability by the Year 2000

Policy Actions Needed

Securing the Penmanent Forest EstateMappingInventories

Production and consumptionLand use planningPolicy and legislation

implementing Sustainable Forest ManagementDemonstration forests

Implementation (mid-range)

improving Resource UtilizationTrials and missions

improving the Social and Pointical EnvironmentSocial sciences

Political and consumer awareness

Resources Needed (IIS$ Million/year)

Strategy Plans and Progress Reports

Existing *

Total

60.2

0.0

7.3

2. I

0.8

50.0

Notes:

Additional

191.3

6.0

28.2

5.0

19.3

132.8

Source:

84.0

4.0

80.0

* Existing resources are estimates of producer country expenditures basedon the current status of activities undertaken, including those using externalfunding.

Total

251.56.0

36.5

7. I

20.2

182.1

1.0

1.0

108.5

26.0

82.5

ITTC (1992) based on Ferguson and Mufioz-Reyes Navarr0 (1992).

0.0

0.0

0.0

13.0

13.0

192.5

30.0

162.5

4.0

149.2

8.1

4.4

3.7

14.0

14.0

9.2

330.1

8.1

4.4

3.7

13.2

479.3

Page 21: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

deforestation (ITTC 1992c)." Using these two estimates as the broad 'bounds' on the typeof financing required, we suggest that additional funds required by producer countries toimplement sustainable management of their tropical forest resource to be in the range of Us$0.3 to 1.5 bn onnuolly.

Although these figures would suggest the need for additional financial assistance for producercountries, the realissue is whether the financing ought to be raised from the tropical timbertrade or from other sources. There are essentially three policy options available: i) re-direction of existing revenue from the trade; it) appropriation of additional revenue from thetrade; and in) additional funding from sources external to the trade. Although these policyoptions are not necessarily mutually exclusive, they will be assessed in turn.

A To natin Existin Revenue from the Trade

A recent study for ITTO conducted by the Oxford Forestry Institute (OFl) has argued thecase for a fax iron. $fer of revenue from the trade between consumer and producer countries(OF1 1991). The main rationale behind the transfer is that:

. Revenues from stumpage (royalties) and other taxes accruing toproducer countrygovernments from tropical timber production and trade are often low in relation to theconsumer value of products; i. e. , producer country governments capture a lowproportion of the total economic rent earned through the trade.

. Revenues from taxes on imported tropical timber products accruing to consumergovernments, such as value-added tax (VAT), are relatively large.

. Consequently, a relatively modest reduction in the rate of taxation at the consumerend of the chain would allow a reasonably large increase in the stumpage value of theresource wirho"i affecting the end price of the resource.

Table 5 illustrates how the tax transfer might work. In the current scenario, producercountry governments are assumed to collect a royalty of Us$ 9 per in', and consumercountry governments impose a VAT on final products of 15%. However, in the tax transferscenario, VAT could be reduced to 7.5% and the royalty increased to Us$ 30 per in' - andthe final price would be left unchanged. Depending on the product, tax revenues of theconsumer country governments would fall by 13-18%. These losses are offset by importantincentives:

'' The proposed international financing is for, specifically, sustaining the multiple roles and functions of alltypes of forests, forest lands and woodlands (Us$ 860 Inn p. a. ) enhancement of the protection, sustainablemanagement and conservation of all forests, the greening of degraded areas through forest rehabilitation,afforestation, reforestation and other rehabilitation measures (Us$ 460 mm p. a. ); and promoting efficientutilization and assessment to recover the full valuation of the goods and services provided by forests, forestlands and woodlands (Us$ 230 mm p. a. ).

17

Page 22: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 5 Affects of a Tax Transfer on the Distribution of Value Added in the Timber Trade

LOG EXPORTS at

Producer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Consumer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Totals

SHARE OF TOTAL VALUE I%)

Current

TIMBER EXPORTS b/

9.2%

Producer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Consumer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Totals

90.8%

5.7%0.9%2.6%

100.0%

Tax transfer

40.1%26.2%24.5%

11.1%

100.0%

88.9%

Change relative tocurrent share I%)

21%5.8%1.1%4.2%

Current

10.5%

PRODUCT EXPORTS b/

Producer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Consumer countryoperating costprofitsgov't revenue

Totals

100.0%

41.3%27.5%20.1 %

100.0%

89.5%

7.5%1.0%2.0%

100.0%

Tax transfer

3%19%59%

-2%

40.4%24.1 %25.1%

12.6%

3%5%

-18%

100.0%

87.4%

Change relative tocurrent share I%)

19%7.7%1.2%3.6%

Current

35.3%

Notes:

100.0%

41.5%25.1 %20.8%

64.7%

20.1%8.4%6.9%

a/ Tropical logs exported by producer countries and all processingIn Consumer countries.

b/ Primary processing of timber in producer countries and secondary processing inconsumer countries.

of Export of final product with all processing done in the producer country.

Based on Figures 4.1, 4.2 and 4.3 in OF1(1991).

100.0%

Source:

Tax transfer

100.0%

3%20%82%

-2%

19.3%

22.2%23.2%

100.1 %

37.1 %

3%4%

-17%

62.9%

Change relative tocurrent share I%)

5%19.3%9.0%8.8%

100.0%

19.8%

22.8%20.2%

100.0%

-4%7%

29%-3%

2%

3%-13%

Page 23: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

. Due to the increased royalties, producer country government revenues risedramatically, by 29-82%, which would provide additional resources for sustainablemanagement expenditures (see Table 4).

The increased royalty would also raise the sale price of logs within producercountries, which could help to control over-exploitation of timber and inefficient useof logs in processing.

Despite the increase in the price of logs, within the forestry sector of producercountries profits would still rise modestly. A slight rise in profits from the tradewould also occur in the consumer countries.

.

.

In short, the main implications of a tax transfer would be to change significantly thedisiribi, nori of economic rents from the timber trade as an incentive for sustainablemanagement in producer countries. The main advantage would be that additional funds forthis purpose could be raised with nine or no effect on final product prices. As indicated inTable 6, just under Us$ 1.5 bn in additional funds could be raised by producer countriesthrough this means - closer to the 'upper bound' of the estimate financing for sustainablemanagement required by these countries.

However, consumer countries are likely to be concerned aboutthe fiscal and politicalimplications of a tax transfer scheme. First, as Table 6 shows, consumer countrygovernments would have to forego over Us$ 3.6 bn in tax revenues from the trade - morethan 2.5 times what producer country governments gain in increased revenues. This impliesa substantial netloss in revenue 'captured' from the trade. Second, exempting tropicaltimber products from VAT or other taxes could prove politically problematic in that it couldsetthe precedent for other goods being exempted from taxes on 'environmental' grounds.Forest industries in temperate forest countries and their governments could also press forsimilar treatment on the same grounds - the need for additional investment for sustainablemanagement or for compensation for pastinvestment.

Finally, consumer countries would insist on an internationally agreed monitoring andenforcement system that would ensure that: I) producer countries did respond by raisingroyalty fees; and 11) the additional revenue raised was spent on sustainable forest managementexpenditures. On the other hand, producer countries would consider too much externalsupervision to be 'interference' with their internal affairs and sovereign rights over theirresource base. Carefully negotiated bilateral and multilateral agreements would be necessarto avoid confrontations and to make the system workable.

One possible variant on the tax transfer scheme would be a revenue ironyer scheme. Ratherthan lower their VAT or other taxes on the tropical timber trade, consumer countrygovernments could instead transfer directly some proportion, or all, of the revenue raisedthrough these taxes to producer countries. Although the consumer country governmentswould still forego substantial revenues, they could ensure more direct control, and thus

18

Page 24: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Table 6 Revenue Transfers Available from Value Added in the Tropical Timber Trade, ,990IUS$ inn)

FOB Export Value atFinal End Use Value by

Tax Transfer Scenario of

Consumer CountryCurrent government revenuePost-transfer revenue

Revenue lost/transferred

Producer CountryCurrent government revenuePost-transfer revenue

Revenue gained/transferred

LogExports

Processed

Sawnwood Product

Exports Exports

2,28046,588

Notes:

2,15029,189

at Based on Bourke (1992).

by Based on ratios of FOB value to final product value in OF1(1991).of Based on Table 5

11,4149,3642,050

4,15012,858

Total

7,3266,0711,255

1,2111,957

745

8,58088,635

2,9832,597

386

584

1,051467

21,72418,033

3,691

887

1,132244

2,6824,1391,457

Page 25: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

leverage, over the allocation of funds to sustainable management. In addition, consumercountry governments would most likely have to forego less revenue ifit were directlytransferred to producer countries to help them meet their Us$ 0.3-1.5 bn target then underthe tax transfer scheme (see Table 6). As indicated in the table, due to 'leakages' to othersectors in the tropical timber trade, a tax transfer scheme would require consumer countrygovernments to forego around 2.5 times more tax revenue in order to allow producer countrygovernments to achieve their target.

However, a revenue transfer scheme would stillrequire an internationally agreed monitoringand enforcement system. Producer country governments would probably be more concernedaboutthe direct control and conditions that consumer country governments could assert overa revenue transfer scheme. Producers would insist on fullinvolvementin the establishment,implementation and monitoring of any such scheme.

In sum, both revenue and tax transfer schemes are similar means of appropriating existingfunds from the tropical timber trade for sustainable management. Both have the attractionthat they would allow substantial funds to be raised for producer country investments insustainable forest management withowl affecting product prices significantly. However,consumer countries are more likely to favour a revenue transfer scheme, whereas producersmay prefer the tax transfer scheme. Both would require international cooperation andagreement over monitoring and enforcement procedures.

A To natin Additional Revenue from the Trade

In recent years there has been renewed interest in the use of trade instruments inappropriating additional tax revenue from the trade for sustainable forest management. Onestudy by the Netherlands Economic Institute (NEl) has indicated that a I-3% surcharge onthe tropical timber imports of the EEC, Japan and USA would raise approximately IIS$ 31.4to 94.1 inn with little additional distortionary effects (NE1 1989). If endorsed by amultilateral forun such as the ITTO, the import surcharge would be within GATT rulesthrough sub-article XX(h). A differentiated surcharge could also be imposed so that importsof processed tropical hardwood products face less discrimination than logs, thus reducingexisting distortions from escalating tariffs. The funds raised would most likely be transferredto the ITTO for distribution, possibly through specific projects and programmes. Otherforms of collecting additional funds were found by the study to be less desirable.

For example, imposition of an exportlevy by producing countries themselves has theadvantage of directly addressing the forest management systems of those countries, butpresents obvious problems of monitoring and evaluating success in achieving sustainablemanagement. If the funds were transferred to ITTO, transaction costs could be high, thesame rate would need to be implemented in all producer countries simultaneously, and lessfunds would be raised than through an import surcharge. A parafiscaltax on antimber soldin consumer countries has the advantages of taxing all kinds of timber equally, includingnon-tropical products, and of generating large revenues at a low rate of taxation. However,

19

Page 26: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

such a tax has complications for external trade policies (e. g. temperate forest countries couldclaim unfair discrimination) and 'harmonization' of internal tax rates within trading blocs(e. g. the EEC's Internal Market Strategy). Finally, a voluntary surcharge collected by thetropical timber trade itself could raise funds transferTable to ITTO without requiringadditional national legislation. Unfortunately, compliance and effectiveness may bediminished because of the current overcapacity and low net profit margins faced by manyinternational traders and wood processing industries; the lack of effective control measures toensure collection with equal efficiency in all consumer countries; and, the possibility of entrand exit by traders in the industry to avoid payment (NE1 1989).

Buongiorno and Manjurung (1992) also examine the scope for a 5% revenue-raising importlevy on tropical timber by the Union pour to Commerce des Bois Tropicaux (UCBT) of theEEC. The results indicate that tropical timber exporters would lose around Us$ 44.8 inn intrade earnings, with Indonesia and Malaysia suffering the worst, but importing countrieswould earn Us$ 87.7 inn in additional revenues. Thus, if the funds raised by the tax wererebated to exporting countries, they could be made better off by over Us$ 40 inn.Moreover, a tax by UCBT countries would have little effect on total world trade of tropicaltimber products. The modelshows that tropical timber exporting countries wouldcompensate for any declines in imports by UCBT countries through increasing exports tonon-UCBT countries.

One of the major concerns of producer countries is that any revenue-raising importsurcharge, even at very low levels, would be distortionary. In particular, if the tax waslevied by animporters, then there could be a more significantimpact on total world trade oftropical timber products. Moreover, such a tax would provide unfair protection to temperateforest based industries of the developed market economies. For example, Buongiomo andManurung suggest that producer countries may prefer a tax on exports rather than an importsurcharge by UCBT countries. This would give producers more direct control over theproceeds of the tax. In addition, an export tax would affect animport market rather thanjust one, thus spreading the costs of sustainable management to all producers and consumers.

To examine the impacts of an import surcharge on the export markets of a producer country,the LEEC study conducted two policy scenarios involving a I and 5% surcharge respectivelyon Indonesia's timber trade (see Table 2, second and third columns). In the case of a I%surcharge, a total of Us$ 23.1 inn (1980 prices) in revenue would be raised, with Us$ 5.8inn and Us$ 17.3 inn from Indonesian sawnwood and plywood exports respectively. For the5% surcharge, a total of Us$ 113.9 inn (1980 prices) in revenue would be raised, with Us$28.5 inn and Us$ 85.4 inn from Indonesian sawnwood and plywood exports respectively.When compared to the revenue estimates from the NE1(1989) study, the above figuressuggest that, in the case of Indonesia, applying the import surcharge to plywood wouldsignificantly raise the total amount of financing appropriated.

The results from the policy simulation also confirm that a smallimport surcharge would havevery little distortionary effects on Indonesia's timber product flows and prices. There would

20

Page 27: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

also be a negligible directimpact on deforestation. However, around the 5% level, theimpacts of the surcharge on exports in particular would become more noticeable. Thus fromthe standpoint of minimizing additional distortionary effects, the policy scenario confirms thatan import surcharge of less than 5% would be optimal.

A more pertinentissue is whether it is worth imposing an import surcharge to raise revenuefor sustainable management of tropical forests. In the simulation model, the same result,and thus the same amount of revenue, could be achieved iflndonesia raised the money for itsown "sustainable management" initiatives by imposing a revenue-raising export surcharge of15%.

In sum, the imposition of an exportlevy by producing counties themselves has the advantageof directly addressing the forest management systems of these countries, as well as avoidingthe transaction costs involved in international transfers, but prevents obvious problems ofmonitoring and evaluating success in achieving sustainable management. The counter-argument is that an import surcharge not only has problems of transaction costs andadministration, but that it is also possibly discriminatory if it is limited only to the iropicoltimber trade. Moreover, the import surcharge-cum-international transfer mechanism wouldstill require the cooperation of producer countries, as well as raise similar problems ofmonitoring and evaluation of progress towards sustainable management and expenditures.

Finally, there is the issue of whether the amount of funds raised through any trade surchargewould be adequate for the task, and whether it would be more appropriate avenue for raisingadditional large-scale funding outside the timber trade altogether. The studies undertaken sofar suggest that the amount of mei funds raised from a trade surcharge of I-5% may fallshortof the approximate target of Us$ 0.3-1.5 bn required annually by producer countries asadditional resources for sustainable management of their forest resources.

Additional Fundin Sources External to the Trade

There is also a strong rationale for additional funds to be made available to producercountries for sustainable forest management from sources outside of the tropical timber trade.Comprehensive international agreements, targeted financial aid flows and compensationmechanisms to deal with the overall problem of tropical deforestation may ultimatelyeliminate the need to consider intervention in the timber trade. Given that commerciallogging is not the primary cause of tropical deforestation, such approaches would avoidunnecessary, and possibly inappropriate, discrimination againstthe timber trade. On theother hand, a comprehensive tropical forest agreement seems much more difficult tonegotiate and raises its own problems of workability and effectiveness. "

'' See Barrett (1990) for a general discussion of the difficulties involved in securing internationalenvironmental agreements.

21

Page 28: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

fits unlikely in this economic climate that a concerted international effort to increasesubstantially bilateral or multilateral aid flows for sustainable production forest managementwould be successful, given the rapidly diminishing aid budgets of the developed economies.Nevertheless, there still remains the possibility of designing new sources of financialassistance that are separate from existing developing country aid budgets. The ForestryPrinciples are effectiveIy a stepping stone in that direction, and international commitmentsthrough the Tropical Forestry Action Plan (TFAP) and Global Environmental Facility (GEF)continue to reinforce the global interest in forestry and biodiversity protection. The casecould be made for more comprehensive international agreements to raise revenues forsustainable management of tropical forests, including production forests. The main focalpoints of such agreements should be the development of alternative revenue-raisingmechanisms other than trade interventions or reliance on existing aid budgets.

For example, Amelung (1991) argues the case for the establishment of an international rainforest fund, as proposed by UNEP, in order to avoid free-riding among non-tropicalcountries. Similar arguments are put forward by Sedjo, Bowes and Wiseman (1991),although their preference is for the establishment of a global system of marketable forestprotection and management obligations (FPMOs). Over the long term, internationalnegotiations leading towards an agreement for new revenue-raising mechanisms forsustainable management of tropical forests, including production forests, could be the mosteffective and equitable means for reducing global tropical deforestation. Although suchnegotiations are difficult and arduous, they may be the best hope of ensuring a globalcommitment to controltropical deforestation, as well as the sustainable management ofproduction forests.

Certification

Many of the trade policy options discussed above were concerned with using some form ofcertification as a means to distinguish between 'sustainably' and 'unsustainably' producedtropical timber products. A comprehensive and internationally agreed certification schemetherefore seems to be a necessoiy coinplemenito trade policy options for sustainable forestmanagement.

However, the term certjficoiion has been used variously to mean:

. Prod"cilobelling -labelling allproductsthatinclude tropical wood with a labelindicating whether or not it is sustainably produced.

. Concession cerr;ficoiion - certifying anthe timber produced by a specific concessionto be 'sustainably produced'. 12

'' A close alternative to concession certification would be company certification.

22

Page 29: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

. Cowniiy certification - certifying antimber products from a country that can prove ithas begun complying with ITTO's Year 2000 Target and its sustainable managementguidelines.

Mandatory productlabelling - even if it is internationally agreed - is the most difficult of thecertification procedures to implement and verify. Given the vast array of tropical timberproducts traded, and the degree of processing involved in producing final products, it will beextremely difficultto set up a workable productlabelling scheme that will be internationallyverifiable. fits made more problematic by the fact that the end uses of tropical timber areoften not discrete products, but components of products and composites, as well as basicstructures, fixtures and fittings. The real danger is that any such scheme of productlabellingwill essentially work as a powerful non-tariff barrier to discriminate against the import oftropical timber in general. This will particularly be the case if it is implemented unilateralIyor on a piecemeal basis, i. e. by individual importers or by selective trading blocs. Asargued above, further restrictions on the trade in tropical timber products will not beeffective in reducing tropical deforestation, and in fact may accelerate it.

Concession certification essentially involves: i) assessment of a forest concession in terms ofcompliance with sustainable management guidelines; it) monitoring of actual forestrypractices in the concession, including volumes sold and destination, up to the retaillevel;and, in) ensuring that each product produced with timber from that concession hasappropriate certification to verify its origin. In theory, the concession certification approachappears to offer the best means of guaranteeing that the tropical timber trade is committed tosecuring timber from only 'sustainably' managed sources. It has the possible attraction totraders and timber companies of earning 'brand recognition' for buying timber supplies fromsustainably managed concessions. Promotion of this fact could be an important 'sellingpoint' as part of the promotion of tropical timber products in consumer markets - much likecurrent campaigns to sell'organically grown' and 'environmentally friendly' products.These positive features of concession (or company) certification suggest that there areexcellent incentives for 'sustainably managed' concessions and companies to promote theirproducts through a voluntary labelling scheme. A group of countries, and even their hostproducer countries, may even develop a common 'voluntary' labelling scheme. Such effortsare essentially elements of a good marketing and export promotion strategy. However, incontrast, it will be difficultto make a comprehensive and internationally agreed concessioncertification scheme, that is inaridatorily imposed on all concessionaires of a producercountry, workable and effective.

First, there are extremely high costs of monitoring, enforcement and verification. Such ascheme would therefore require substantial funding on an international level. Moreimportantly, concession certification would add substantially to the additional financingalready required to implement sustainable forest management. As discussed above, thequestions of who pays these additional costs, how the money ought to be raised, and how toimplement such a mechanism are not easy to resolve - especially when not all concessionairesin producer countries may be willing to accept a mandatory scheme.

23

Page 30: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Second, producer countries and companies may object to detailed monitoring of all aspects oftheir forest industry production, from harvesting to processing to trade. It is unlikely that ateam of visiting international inspectors would be able to monitor the 'wood chain' starting atthe concession levelin all producer countries on their own. In-country inspectors (such as inthe CITES system) would probably be also required, but there will inevitably be conflictsover their level and source of funding and over their degree of autonomy.

Third, concession or company certification in itself does not involve support for forestmanagement administration and services of producer countries. If anything, a comprehensivemandatory scheme may impose additional costs on forest departments. Unless adequatecompensation is provided, the incentives to support or enforce the scheme by forestpersonnel may be lacking.

Fourth, concession-level monitoring also requires close monitoring of products at the retailend of the trade. For consumer products made solely from one type of wood from a singlesource, verification would be fairly straightforward. However, for composite products,products containing one or more differenttropicaltimber components, or for tropical timberused as part of basic structures, fixtures and fittings, the process will be more difficult. Theadditional costs incurred in acquiring tropical timber with the appropriate certification maymake discourage its use compared to alternative materials in end use markets. Again, it ispossible that such a certification scheme will: i) act as a restriction on trade and use oftropical timber for many final end uses; and ii) increase the incentives to find 'loopholes' orcheatthe scheme (e. g. obtaining similar timber from 'unverified' sources in the samecountry; concessions 're-selling' timber from other sources; forging of certificates).

Given the difficulties with product labelling and concession certification, the most appropriatescheme at leastinitially would be cownriy cert;iicorion. The main point of such a schemewould be to ensure that a producer country is implementing policies, reg"joltons dadmonogemeniplons rhor ensure subsioniiolprogress rowords the Yeor 2000 ranger. In return,the tropical timber products of that country will be certified as coming from a 'Target 2000'country, which should give them easier access to import markets in developed economies(GHK/HDH/VDH 1992).

There are several reasons why country certification may be more effective and workable:

. Certification at the country levelwillbe less costly and more easy to implementcompared to other certification schemes. Periodic inspection tours by aninternationally certified teams, monitoring at custom ports, reviews of forest policyand management plans would probably be sufficient for such a scheme to be effective.

. Producer countries would find country certification more politically acceptable,provided that:

24

Page 31: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

i) under international auspices producer countries could helpdeterminethecertification scheme as well as any verification process;

ii) the certificate of origin could then be issued by the exporting country, orcompanies authorized by that country;

in) as it is effectiveIy a notional sustainable management plan that is beingcertified, it would be up to the producer country to address adequately theproblems posed by production from conversion forests, plantations, re-afforestation and so forth, but once this plan is internationally verified, o11timber products from o11types of forests in the country would be certified;

Iv) development of a nationalsustainable management forest policy and land useplan would in turn support efforts by companies and concessionaires todevelop more sustainable forest management practices, which they may thenchose to promote voluntarily through productlabelling;

v) it would be up to producer country to ensure compliance with the sustainablemanagement plan, and in cooperation with 'independentinspection' therelevant forest authorities would have primary responsibility for monitoringoperations at the concession and industry level; and,

vi) in eXchange for adopting the scheme and being certified, an exporting countrywould hope to receive improved access to international markets for their'sustainably managed' products, and hopefully, international financialassistance to implement their sustainable management plans. This wouldprovide an incentive for producer countries to adopt this policy approach.

Consumer countries may also find country certification more feasible to implement as:

i) under international auspices, such aslTTO, consumer countries could helpdetermine the certification scheme as well as any verification process;

ii) individual timber trade products would not have to be certified - antradeproducts from a certified country could be safely imported, and any inspectioncould be conducted as routine port of entry (i. e. customs) procedures;

in) consumer countries would be assured that country certification would require apolicy commitment by producer country governments to manage theirproduction forests sustainably under the ITTO guidelines and Target 2000,viable national plans to implement this policy, and a mandate to correctdomestic market and policy failures that encourage timber-relateddeforestation; and,

.

25

Page 32: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

in) it would be easier to target bilateral and multilateral financial assistance forsustainable forest management - i. e. such flows could now be conditional onproducer countries complying with the certification scheme.

In sum, an internationally agreed certification scheme ought to be used as a means tofacilitate trade in sustainably produced tropical timber - not as a means to restrict trade.Mandatory productlabelling and concession certification are too cumbersome and restrictiveto assist trade-related incentives for sustainable management, and may also fail to gainadequate producer country cooperation. On the other hand, country certification wouldrequire the active participation and verification of producer countries. Moreover, a countrycertification scheme may also support efforts by companies and concessionaires to developmore sustainable forest management practices, which they may then chose to promotevoluntarily through productlabelling. In eXchange, producer countries could qualify foradditional financial assistance to implement sustainable management plans, as well as beassured of better market access for their exports.

Conclusions

This paper has provided a brief assessment of the various trade policy options analyzed in theLEEC study (Barbier at o1. 1993). A summary of the timber trade policy options, and theiradvantages and disadvantages in promoting sustainable tropical forest management, isprovided in Table I.

The general conclusion is that additional tropical timber trade policies do have a role infostering Irode-reinied incentives for sustainable management. Trade policies will be themost effective if:

. they are employed in conjunction with and complement improved domestic policiesand regulations for sustainable forest management within producer countries;

they improve rather than restrict access to import markets for tropical timber productsso as to ensure maximum value added for sustainably produced tropical timberexports; and,

.

. they assist producer countries in obtaining the additional financial resources requiredto implement comprehensive national plans for sustainable management of tropicalproduction forests.

More specifically, the main conclusions of the assessment of trade policy options are:

. There is very little evidence to suggest that the option of 'doing nothing' willencourage greater trade-related incentives for sustainable management of tropical

26

Page 33: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

production forests, or is the appropriate response given current trends in tropicaldeforestation and trade.

. The problem with restrictive trade policy interventions, such as bans, taxes andquantitative restrictions, is that if they are applied indiscriminately across all tropicaltimber products, they will reduce rather than increase the incentives for sustainabletimber management- and may prove actually to increase overalltropicaldeforestation. 'Selective' interventions, such as those that distinguish between'sustainably' and 'unsustainably' produced timber, would also work to restrict tradeand thus should also be avoided.

. Banning or controlling the trade in specific timber species may be a necessary shortterm response if the species are endangered, but more effective and innovative longterms solution for management of the trade are required. A more comprehensivetrade mechanism that establishes sustainable offtake export quotas for endangeredtropical timber species would offer a better incentive to both importers and exportersto accept a controlled legal trade and to enforce it.

Trade subsidies to support sustainable management goals would also probably bedistortionary and could lead to problems of disguised protectionism and encourageinefficiency in the forest sector. Progress toward sustainable management in producercountries should come first before any consideration of trade or production subsidies.

General liberalization of the trade in tropical timber products is probabl not feasible.However, producer countries that show demonstrable progress towards achievingTarget 2000 could be allowed better access to importing markets through the removalof specific tariff and non-tariffbarriers on a case-by-case basis. Similarl , indemonstrating compliance with Target 2000, producer countries should be asked toreview the implications of their own tropical timber export policies and restrictionsfor both timber-related tropical deforestation and international markets.

However, there is evidence that producer countries will require additional financing ofaround Us$ 0.3 to 1.5 bn annually to implement sustainable management plans fortheir tropical forests, including production forests. Moreover, the Internationalcommunity led by the developed market economies ought to provide this assistance,given the global values attributed to tropical forests. In the current economic andpolitical climate, new forms of assistance other than traditional bilateral andmultilateral aid flows will probably be required.

A revenue-raising surchorge could be levied at either the exporting or importing endof the trade. Trade distortions would be minimized ifthe surcharge was ke ttounder 5% of the value of the trade. Unfortunately, the net funds raised ina be wellbelow the annual target of Us$ 0.3-1.5 bn. However, the trade should not be

.

.

.

.

27

Page 34: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

expected to pick up the total tab for financing sustainable management of tropicalforests, but rather make a contribution towards it.

. If additional revenue were to be raised from the trade, the distribution of existingfunds appropriated by consumer country governments, either through a tax or revenuetransfer, would be feasible. Consumer countries would probably prefer the latter, andproducer countries the former.

. In the medium and long term, more comprehensive mechanisms and internationalagreements for raising revenue erremolto the trade to combatthe overo11problem oftropical deforestation will have to be examined. Possible mechanisms include theestablishment of a tropical forest fund or a global system of marketable forestprotection and management obligations.

Finally, any promotion of trade-related incentives for sustainable management willhave to consider an appropriate cert!iicoiion scheme. Product labelling and concessionor company certification are too cumbersome and restrictive to assist trade-relatedincentives for sustainable management, and may also fail to gain adequate producercountry cooperation. On the other hand, country certification would require theactive participation and verification of producer countries and satisfy consumerdemand for a sustainably managed supply of timber products. In eXchange, producercountries could qualify for additional financial assistance to implement sustainablemanagement plans, as well as be assured of better market access for their exports.

.

28

Page 35: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

References

Amelung, T. 1991. "Tropical Deforestation as an International Economic Problem " Paper presented at theEgon-Sohmen Foundation Conference on Econonitc Evolution and Environmental Concerns, Linz, Austria, 30-31 August.

Bathier, E. B. 1993. "Econonxic Aspects of Tropical Deforestation in South East Asia " Forthconitn inGlobalEcology dad Biogeographic@! Letters, 3.

Barbier, E. B. , Burgess, I. C. , Bishop, I. T. , Aylward, B. A. , and Bami, C. 1993. file Economic LinkagesBetween the International Trade in Tropical Timber dad ihe Sustainable Management of Tropical Forests. FinalReport: ITTO Activity PCM(XD/4. Yokohonm: International Tropical Timber Organization.

Bathier, E. B. , Burgess, I. C. , Swanson, T. M. and Pearce, D. W. 1990. Elephants, Economics and IvoLondon: Earthscan Publications.

Bartert, S. 1990. "The Problem of Global Environmental Protection. " 0. :;ford Review of Economic Policy6(I):6879.

Buongiomo, I. and Manurung, T. 1992. "Predicted Effects of an Import Tax in the European Coriumunit onthe International Trade of Tropical Timbers. " mimeo. Madison, Wisconsin: Department of Forestr , Universitof Wisconsin.

Burgess, I. C. 1992. file Impact of Wildlife Trade on Endangered Spedes. LEEC Discussion Paper 92-02.London: London Environmental Econonxics Centre.

Constantino, L. F. 1990. On the I^@'icie"cy of Indonesia's Sawmilli"g and Plymi!ling Industries. Jakarta: D. G.of Forest Utilization, Ministry of Forestry, Government of hidonesia and FAO.

Ferguson, I'S. and Muiioz-Reyes Navarr0, I. 1992. "Working Document for ITTO Expert Panel on ResourcesNeeded by Producer Countries to Achieve Sustainable Management by the Year 2000 " Yokohoma: ITTO.

Gewerkschaft Holz und Kunststoff(GHK), Central Federation of German Timber and Plastics Processingindustries (HDH) and German Timber Importers Federation (VDH) 1992. Joint Dederntion on the Protection ofTropical Forests. Bonn: GHK/HDH/VDH.

International Tropical Timber Council(ITTC) 1992a. Report From the Experi Panel on Estimation ofResources Needed by Producer Countries to Attain Sustainabiltty^ by ihe year 2000. ITTC(XII)/7 Rev. I, 10thSession, Yaound6, Cameroon, 6-14 May.

international Tropical Timber Council(ITTC) 1992b. Repor! on the Eigrh Committee of Parties to theConvention on International Trade in Endangered Sipecies, Kyoto, I-13 March 1992. PCM(X)/7, 10th Session,Yaound6, Cameroon, 6-14 May.

International Tropical Timber Council(ITTC) 1992c. Report on Preparationsfor the 1992 United NationsContere"ce on Environment dadDevelopme"t. ITTC(XII)/8, 10th Session, Yaound6, Cameroon, 6-14 May.

international Tropical Timber Council(ITTC) 1992d. Report Submitted to the International Tropical TimberCouncil on the "Workshop on Issues Related to Incen!ives to Promoie Sustainable Development of TropicalForests through Trade. " PCM(X)/4, 10th Session, Yaound6, Cameroon, 6-14 May.

29

Page 36: International Tropical Timber Council in Kuala …...role that interventions in the international tropical timber trade may have in promoting efficient and sustainable resource use

Netherlands Econonxic institute (NE1) 1989. An Import Surcharge on the Impori of Tropical Timber in theEuropean Community. . An Evaluation . Rotterdam: NEl.

Oxford Forestry Institute (OFl) in association with the Timber Research and Development Association(TRADA) 1991. Incentives in Producer and Consumer Countries to Promote Sustainable Development ofTropical Forests. ITTO Pre-Project Report, PCM, PCF, PCI(IV)/11Rev. 3. Oxford: OFl.

Poore, D. , Burgess, P. , Palmer, I. , Riotbergen, S. , and Synnott, T. 1989. NO Timber Without Trees. .Sustain"bino, in Ihe Tropical Forest. London: Earthscan Publications.

Sedjo, R. A. , Bowes, M. and Wiseman, C. 1991. Toward a Worldwide System of Tradedble Forest Protectiondad Management Obligoiio"s. Discussion Paper ENR 91-16. Washington DC: Energy and Natural ResourcesDivision, Resources for the Future.

Vincent, I. R. 1990. "Don't Boycott Tropical Timber. " Journal of Forestry 88(4):56.

30