natural resources, the environment and agriculture

57
Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture Chapter 10

Upload: duff

Post on 31-Jan-2016

29 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture. Chapter 10. Topics of Discussion. Agriculture and the environment Economics of the environment Economics of resources in agriculture Soil quality and quantity Economics of soil conservation - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Natural Resources,the Environmentand Agriculture

Chapter 10

Page 2: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Topics of Discussion

Agriculture and the environmentEconomics of the environmentEconomics of resources in agricultureSoil quality and quantityEconomics of soil conservationGovernment policies for agriculture,

natural resources, and the environment

2

Page 3: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Agriculture and the Environment

Water pollutionNon-point sourcePoint source

Air pollutionDispersed agricultural industry requiring

extension transportion system to get goods to market

Global climate changeImpact on rainfall totalsImpacts of temperature changes

Other environmental impacts Pages 171-176

3

Page 4: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Economics of the EnvironmentFrom Ch. 9 we saw that if an economy is

fully efficient then Private actions of consumers and producers

will maximize total surplus Referred to as being Pareto Efficient

Can the same be said for environmental impacts of economic activity? Is the efficient level of environmental

impacts being generated?

Pages 1774

Page 5: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Economics of the Environment

Does the environment have value? Example of the impacts of water pollution Users of waterway would be willing to pay

something to reduce (abate) the level of pollution

→Implicit demand for environmental improvements Similar to market commodities

Page 1775

Page 6: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Economics of the Environment

Are there costs associated with reducing the level of environmental pollution? Install scrubbers on power plant

smokestacks Use more expensive lower sulphur coal The above implies that there is a supply

curve (MC curve) for pollution abatement

What would be the socially optimal level of pollution abatement?

Page 1776

Page 7: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 177

WTP

MC

PollutionAbatement (Reduction)

$

P1

C1

A1 A3

At A1, ↑ abatement (↓pollution) would cost C1 but public would be willing to pay P1

If WTP>MC then society’s net benefit will be increased by increasing abatement

Economics of the Environment

Socially efficientabatement level

A2

C2

P2

C3

P3

A4

At A4 too much abatement, Why?

7

Page 8: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 177

Unlike typical market goods such as food, clothes, etc. We cannot use market information to determine

value of pollution abatement WTP is obtained using a variety of procedures

generally referred to as non-market valuation techniques

Will a market develop for environmental improvement and socially optimal outcome? Usually not because the characteristics of

efficient property rights are not satisfied for environmental goods

Economics of the Environment

8

Page 9: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Efficient Property RightsEfficient property rights are characteristics that

ensure a socially optimal provision of goods and services will be providedProperty rightsProperty rights: Privileges and limitations that are

associated with the ownership of a resourceEnforceabilityEnforceability: Can enforce individual property

rightsTransferabilityTransferability: One is able to transfer property

rights from one individual to anotherExclusivity: All associated benefits and costs are

received by only one individual at a time

Pages 178-1799

Page 10: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Efficient Property RightsEnforceability: security of individual rights

If not present then there is nothing to stop someone from taking the good from its owner

No one would produce the good as not assured will get paid

No one would purchase because they could take without paying

Pages 178-17910

Page 11: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Efficient Property RightsTransferability: Property can be

transferred from one individual to anotherExample is laws prohibiting the sale of certain

goodsNo markets will arise because sale is not

allowedEfficient transfer from one individual to

another cannot occur

Pages 178-17911

Page 12: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Efficient Property RightsExclusivity: All associated benefits and

costs are received by only one individual at a timeExample is some costs are not borne by the

producer of the good but by the public at largeExample of agricultural production

Farmer pays for labor, capital and material inputs Producer does not pay for the negative impacts

downstream when runoff causes a degradation in water quality such as reduced fishing quality

This downstream impact passed onto the public is referred to as an externality as the producer of the impact does not pay for its cost Pages 178-179

12

Page 13: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Concept of ExternalityExternality

There exists positive as well as negative externalities

Example of positive externality: Honey producer’s impact on neighbors' crop yield

Example of negative externality: Playing loud music in your apartment to the point that it wakes your neighbors

Pages 178-179

13

Page 14: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

D

C

B

A6

15

Pm

Qm

Below represents aggregate market demand and supply for good, Q

Sm=MCm

Dm

Producer surplus = BTotal willingness to

pay = A + B + C + DConsumer surplus = C

+ DTotal (societal) surplus

is B + C + D

14

Page 15: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of ExternalitySuppose the production of Q causes

pollution Assume this pollution imposes costs on

others due to degradation of water resources

Neither producers nor consumers of this good takes these costs into account i.e. are external to the market

For simplicity lets assume these external costs (Ex) are constant at $9/unit

The social marginal cost (MCS) per unit of production is: MCS = MCm + Ex15

Page 16: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

C

B

6

15

Pm

Qm

Ex = $9Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Dm

The social marginal cost (MCS) is: MCS = MCm + Ex

With Qm units produced there is additional cost

= Qm *Ex = area (B + C + E) below

E

16

D

A

Page 17: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

DE

C

B

A6

15

Pm

Qm

Ex = $9Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Dm

From the market equilibrium the social net benefits (SNB) = CS + PS – External CostsSNB = (B + C + D) – (B + C + E) = D – E

CS+PS External Costs

Page 18: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

DE

6

15

Qm

Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Dm

How can we increase the SNB = (CS + PS – Externality)?What happens if we increase production to Qm*?What happens if we decrease production to Qm**?

F

G

Qm*→ SNB* = D – E –F – G → SNB* < SNBQm** → SNB** = D → SNB** > SNBAt Qm and Qm* production is inefficiently high relative to socially optimal, Qm**

Qm*Qm**

From above:SNB = D - E

Page 19: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

Qm

Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Dm

We can also look at the above inefficiency relative the marginal (last) unit What are the marginal net benefits and marginal costs

of the last unit of Q purchased?

At the market level of production, Qm

Consumers willing to pay Pm

The cost to producers is Pm

→the SNB for the mth (last) unit purchased is 0

Pm

Page 20: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

Q

$

Qm

Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Dm

We can also look at the above inefficiency relative the marginal (last) unit What are the marginal net benefits and marginal costs

of the last unit of Q purchased?

There are additional social costs (area E)

→the marginal SNB for the last unit purchased is (WTP – MCm – Ex ) where we assumed Ex=$9 per unit of Q

Pm

E

Page 21: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Page 179

Concept of Externality

From the above we can conclude the following: In the presence of externalities the free market

will not reach socially optimal production level Referred to as an example of market failure

Although production of Q results in an externality this does not mean that production should be set to 0 Reducing production to 0 is socially inefficient At social optimal production level, SNB may be

positive even after subtracting external costs, Ex

Page 22: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

As noted above, an externality results in a market failure as too much production occurs If responsibility for damages could be

established and enforced then a market would arise

Lets look an example of a farmer and fisherman Coase market based approach to solving the

negative externality problem

Pages 180-183

Page 23: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental PoliciesLets look at farmer/fishing association example

Pages 180-183

Q

$

Qm

Sm=MCm

MCS=MCm+Ex

Qm*

Qm* is socially optimal pollution for farm

C is the externality (cost) of producing Qm

Fishing assoication offers a bribe of C+D

PS w/o payment = A + B + D w/payment = A+B+C+D

Social Net benefits Qm = A – CQ* = A

A

B

D

C

Page 24: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Coase’s approach has not been widely adopted due to the free-rider problem Suppose a fisherman’s association forms to pay

upstream polluters not to pollute Although only association members pay into the

fund, all fishermen whether a member of not benefits from cleaner water

→A strong incentive not to pay the cost of association membership while enjoying the benefits (i.e. to be a free-rider)

Pages 180-183

Page 25: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental PoliciesGiven the difficulty of obtaining an

economic efficient level of environmental resources there are a number of types of public policies used to move toward this targetCommand-and-Control policiesTaxes and subsidiesTransferable rights

Pages 180-183

Page 26: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental PoliciesCommand and Control: Environmental

policy consisting of regulations on technology or restrictions on practicesAll economic agents treated equally

All firms required to abate to the same level All must install same equipment

Problem is that it does not recognize the diversity in the economy and the differential impact of a regulation

Pages 180-183

Page 27: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental PoliciesExample: Two farmers and a requirement

to reduce non-point pollutionProducer John uses older technology →

reducing pollution could be costlyProducer Sue uses newer technology →

reducing pollution achieved relatively cheaplyIf they are neighbors

Same level of total environmental improvement achieved at a lower total societal cost if Producer Sue reduced more and Producer John reduces less

Pages 180-183

Page 28: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Pages 180-183

Fig. A & B represent the MC of abatement for Firms 1 and 2 MC ↑ with abatement level

Fig. C combines these two figures

$ $ $

A1 A2 A1

A2

MC1

MC2

MC2

MC1

5 10 5 10 5 10000

0510

A B C $

Page 29: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Pages 180-183

Movement to the right (left) would ↑ (↓) abatement for Firm 1 and ↓ (↑) that of Firm 2

Total abatement will always equal 10 units

$

A1

A2

MC2

MC1

5 100

0510

$

Page 30: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Pages 180-183

If each firm abates 5 units the total abatement cost (TAC) is:TAC = A + B + C

Firm 1’s last unit of abatement cost much higher than the last unit of Firm 2’s abatement Difference = MC1*- MC2*

→ that TAC could be reduced if Firm 2 abates more, Firm 1 less TAC is minimized when MC1 = MC2

The gov’t could make such an allocation but would have to know the MC curves

$

A1

A2

MC2

MC1

5 100

0510

A

B

C

Firm 1 Firm 2MC1*

MC2*

Page 31: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental PoliciesTaxes and Subsidies: An incentive-based

approach to environmental policySubsidy for abatementTax on pollution

Subsidy of S dollars onpollution abatement tominimize TAC

Firm 1 will abate 3 units,Firm 2 will abate 7 unitsA1<3→MC1 < S, A2>7→MC2 > SA1>3→MC1 > S, A2<7→MC2 < SA1 = 3 & A2=7 →MC1=MC2=S Pages 180-183

$

A1

A2

MC2

MC1

5 100

0510

3

S

7

Page 32: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

A tax on pollution would work just like a subsidy on pollution abatementA tax of $T per unit of pollution, for each

unit of abatement the firm saves $TThe firm will continue to abate as long as

the tax savings are greater than or equal the MC of abating

Pages 180-183

Page 33: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Advantage of tax/subsidy: Whatever level of abatement is achieved it will be done at the lowest total cost (across all agents)

Disadvantage of tax/subsidy: Unless MC curves known, the gov’t will not know with certainty the abatement level achievedT too low, too little abatementT too high, too much abatement

Pages 180-183

Page 34: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Transferable Rights: When applied to pollution known as transferable discharge permits (TDP)

Under a TDP program rights to pollute can be bought and sold by pollutersMoves the permits to those polluters with

relatively high abatement costsAs long as aggregate pollution level stays below

the target, the gov’t does not worry who is polluting

Pages 180-183

Page 35: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

TDP Example: Firm 1 and Firm 2 are required to do 5 units of abatement

MC1 > MC2 at this levelA trade could work out

where Firm 1 could pay Firm 2 for a permitFirm 1 ↑ pollutionFirm 2 ↓ pollution

Permits could continue until MC1 = MC2 Pages 180-183

$

A1

A2

MC2

MC1

5 100

0510

Page 36: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Environmental Policies

Advantage of a Transferable Rights program:Are cost effective given the least cost of TCP

could be achievedGov’t can control level of pollution and leave

the allocation up to the marketplace

Pages 180-183

Page 37: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Natural Resources and Agriculture

Distinction between environmental issues and natural resource issues: The extent to which externalities exist Environmental issues: Important

externalities present Natural Resource issues: Costs and Benefits

of natural resource use falls mainly on the user

Lets look at the example of soil quantity and quality

Pages 183-187

Page 38: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Economics of Soil UseFarmer undertakes efforts to prevent soil

erosion this protects its quality Soil quality a fundamental issue in agriculture An asset with potentially long productive

lifetime

Major source of decline in soil quality is soil erosion resulting from rain or wind Erosion can wash away productive soil Can also degrade features of the soil that are

essential for crop productivity Soil nutrients Pages 183-187

Page 39: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Economics of Soil UseSoil quality is a complex function of

physical (i.e., depth), chemical (i.e., acidity) and biological (i.e., microbial activity) What is the value of this resource? How much should be spent on preserving it?

A farmer values soil because it has the potential to generate a positive income stream over time Important question: What is the value of this

future income worth?Pages 183-187

Page 40: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Discounting and Present Value

Example of 5 years of $100/year income from an acre of land each year→total income of $500 Not accurate that this $500 of future income is

worth $500 today, need to wait to receive it Would you prefer to wait for 3 years for $100

or receive $75 today? General principle: The further in the future

income is generated, the less it is worth today

Pages 183-187

Page 41: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

To compare $ values over time economists use discounting to convert all $ to present values Present value: Amount of money an individual

could be given today that would make him/her indifferent to a greater amount of income in the future

What is the opportunity cost today of that future income

Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

Page 42: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Suppose you purchase a certificate of deposit today for $6 with an interest rate of 5% annually In 5 years that $6 would have grown due to

compound interest to $8.04 $8.04 = $6 x (1.05)5

You would be indifferent between $8.04 5-years from now and $6 today

The present value (PV) of $8.04 5-years from now given the 5% interest rate is $6.00 Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

Initial deposit Number of years

Interest rate

Page 43: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

What is the present value of $10 5-years from now with a 6% interest rate?

From the above we know that:$10=$X x (1.06)5

→ $X = $10 ÷ [(1.06)5] = $7.47 →$7.47 is the PV of $10 5-years from now and

given a 6% interest rate Present value should always be < future value with a

positive interest rate →Opportunity cost of $10 5 years from now is

$7.47 given the above interest rate Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

Page 44: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Returning to our farm example:You have an acre of land that generates a

stream of income over time The PV of this stream would be the amount

of money the farmer would have to be paid now that would be equivalent to this stream of future income

The total PV of the stream would equal the sum of the PV’s of the individual elements of this future stream

Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

Page 45: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Lets represent some unknown interest rate by the symbol ρ

If we have a level of income in year t represented by Yt, the PV of the stream of income (V) is:

Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

31 2

1 2 3

YY YV

1 ρ 1 ρ 1 ρ

PV of yr 1income PV of yr 2

income

PV of yr 3income

Page 46: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Given the above assume: The farmer receives the same level of income

each year (Y*) This income is generated for a very large

number of years There is a mathematical result that the PV of

this sum over a large number of years (V*) will be approximately equal to:

V* is referred to as the capitalized value of the constant income stream, $Y* given interest rate ρ

Pages 183-187

Discounting and Present Value

** YV

ρ

Page 47: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Going back to our soil example Y* earned each year from an acre of land Capitalized value of this stream of income

needs to be shared with all inputs used to generate this income Fertilizer, seed, tractor time, management, etc.

How can we determine the marginal value of the soil? What is the value of the last unit of soil added to the

generation of the above income? Page 186 in the text shows how to undertake such

an evaluation

Pages 183-187

Economics of Soil Use

Page 48: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Going back to our soil example Suppose the yearly profits is $10/year/acre and

ρ = 5% Capitalized Value = $10/(5/100)=$200 What is the marginal value of his soil given

other inputs used?

The next year, there was a change in tillage practices that resulted in unanticipated and significant erosion events → loss of $1/acre in return

Pages 183-187

Economics of Soil Use

Page 49: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

The capitilized value of the now $9/acre return is 9/(5/100)=$180 →The value of soil conservation efforts is $20

($200 - $180) How does this value compare to conservation

effort costs?

Pages 183-187

Economics of Soil Use

Page 50: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

A characteristic of surface water (i.e., lakes, rivers) are that they are typically renewed over time via rainfall and runoff

Important question for economists: How are these water resources to be allocated among competing uses? i.e., agricultural irrigation, residential use,

industrial use, recreation, etc.

Pages 187-189

Water as an Asset

Page 51: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Water as an AssetWe have two farmers who are competing

for the use of a river’s water for irrigation Assume that a total of 100 acre-feet are allowed

to be extracted Applying irrigation water

increases crop yield The marginal revenue of water

and marginal cost of pumping aresuch that both farmers would like to use 80 acre ft of water

Pages 187-189

Page 52: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Water as an AssetOne farmer is upstream of the other

Will use 80 acre-ft of water Leave only 20 acre-ft for downstream farmer

Pages 187-189

Irrigation Marginal Revenue and Marginal Cost

Both farmers havethe same revenueand cost curve

Upstream farmer

Downstream farmer

Page 53: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Water as an AssetThe 80/20 allocation is

economically inefficient Marginal Value of water = 0

for upstream farmer as MR=MC

Marginal Value of water for downstream farmer > 0 = a – c

→Total net benefits could be ↑ by allocating water from upstream to downstream farmer

Pages 187-189

Page 54: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Water as an AssetIf the water rights are transferable

Downstream farmer would be willing to pay more for an additional unit of water than upstream farmer values the marginal unit of water

→ A deal could be made such that both are better off

Ideally, the farmers would bargain back and forth until each had 50 acre-ft of waterPurely the result of assumed cost and revenue

structures

Pages 187-189

Page 55: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Water as an AssetGiven the assumption of equal cost and

revenue structures for both farmersTotal net benefits would be maximized

where the net benefits of an additional water unit would be the same for both farmers

→A system in which upstream users have preference over downstream users can result in an inefficient water allocation

Pages 187-189

Page 56: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

SummaryEconomists play a role in designing policies

that affect the environment and natural resources

Incentives matter when designing policies to achieve desired objectives

For agricultural production, water and soil are assets that have value and net benefits associated with their use

Page 57: Natural Resources, the Environment and Agriculture

Chapter 11 is used to discuss forms of governmental intervention, including price and income supports that impact agricultural markets…