economic anthropology all societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic...

78
Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and ways to distribute goods and services

Upload: easter-french

Post on 26-Dec-2015

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Economic anthropology All societies have systems to

allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and ways to distribute goods and services

Page 2: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Kinds of economies Reciprocity, redistribution, and

market exchange Market exchange is eventually

based on all-purpose money. Hunter-gatherers, pastoralists,

horticulturalists, agriculturalists … and industrial food production.

Page 3: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Hunter-gatherers Subsistence technology, including

implements for hunting and fishing Paleolithic technology, small groups,

patrilineal and patrilocal

Page 4: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Reciprocity Generalized reciprocity:

under conditions of low technology and unpredictability without scarcity.

Balanced reciprocity: short term and explicit, including “silent

trade” Andaman Islands, Australian

Aborigines, !Kung San, Semang of Malysia, Pygmies of central Africa, Inuit, Hadza

Page 5: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

• from Raymond Hames’ work on the Yanomamo of Brazil (figure 6 at

http://www.unl.edu/rhames/aaa96/egalexch.htm

Page 6: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Pastoralists This is a special adaptation to areas

that don’t support agriculture but that do support extensive grasses Dry climate Steep hills Poor soils

Page 7: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Where are the pastoralists? East Africa (cattle) Maasai and Fulani North Africa (camels) Bedouins SW Asia (sheep, goats) Kurds Central Asia (yaks) Kazhaks Subarctic (caribou and reindeer) Lapps Material goods are limited by migration Little craft specialization, but some regional

trade agreements with agricultural villages

Page 8: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Transhumant and nomadic pastoralism

East Africa Men and boys move livestock; women

may remain in permanent villages. Nomadic pastoralists move the whole

village.

Page 9: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Nama of South Africa Clan organization rather than tribal or

national The Nama pastoralists migrated

constantly and lived on meat and milk from cattle, sheep, and goats, with hunted meat and gathered vegetables.

Oxen made it easier for them to pack and cover large areas.

Page 10: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 11: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Pastoralists today Being settled by governments Range being taken by agriculture But for some countries (Ethiopia and

Afghanistan, for example), restoring pastoralism would improve people’s lives: especially if they are integrated into

international markets for animal products

Page 12: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Horticulturalists Hills of India, Pacific islands, Amazon forest

– Yanomamo, for example Slash and burn (swidden) agriculture plus

hunting Warm forest regions of the world Textiles and pottery are rudimentary 5-25 families in impermanent villages Village autonomy and little tribal level

organization Some intervillage trade, but very limited

Page 13: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Agriculturalists These are advanced cultivators: SW

Pacific, agricultural regions of sub-Saharan Africa

Permanent settlements Crop rotation and fallow practices Often combined with stock raising and

little hunting Tribal government well developed

Page 14: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Dahomey In Dahomey (Benin), a city of over

100,000 developed from 1650-1894 Very high level of specialization Capital city of Agbome was a

centralized state based on a monarchy Independence in 1960

Page 15: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Highland cultivators of NW Aztecs, Incas and prior civilizations in those regions Maize, potatoes, beans, roots, squash, chili peppers Irrigated dry lands and terraced fields on hilly slopes Permanently cleared land Organized towns and states Hand cultivation (only the llama in Peru for wool and pack,

but no wheel) Well-established trade system and great specialization and

achievement in government, with rods and temples and houses; complex superstructure, including religion and arts and crafts

Page 16: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 17: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Asian agrarian civilizations India, Burma, Cambodia, China, Japan – before

industrialization Irrigated rice cultivation and some millet, fruit

trees, spices, vegetables, oil-producing seeds, fibrous plants, and fish

Plow cultivation Elaborate arts, crafts, and religion Highly developed government, including states Very dense population: up to 1500/sq mi Permanent villages with either a feudal or

peasant society

Page 18: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Industrial economies Europe, brazil, Argentina, the U.S., South Africa,

Australia, New Zealand, Japan, S. Korea, Taiwan, Malaysia – many in transition today

Irrigated and non-irrigated plow cultivation, with mechanization and large-scale domestication of animals

Industry and exploitation of oil, cola, gas, timber, minerals, and water

Highest level of specialization with large urban centers and small proportion of rural food producers

Page 19: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Reciprocity: Karl Polanyi’s categories

Generalized reciprocity under conditions of low technology and

unpredictability without scarcity: !Kung, parents and children

Balanced reciprocity: short term and explicit, including “silent trade” – Mbuti

Negative reciprocity We continue to have elements of,

generalized, balanced, and negative reciprocity in our economic system.

Page 20: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Kula Ring Bronislaw Malinowski described this system in

the Trobriand Islands Advanced cultivators, boat builders and

fishermen Produced a lot of surplus using Neolithic tools. Strong specialization in foods and crafts. Ritual

exchange as part of the system of trade The Mwali are the white shell armbands and

move counter-clockwise; the Soulava are red shell necklaces and move clockwise

Page 21: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 22: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 23: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Potlatch of the NW Coast

Northwest Coast of North America: Haida of Queen Charlotte Islands of British Columbia, Kwakiutl, Tlingit, Nootka

Totem poles, old and modern Mild climate, heavy rainfall. Rich forests and

marine fauna. Hunting, fishing and gathering. Stratified society and highly developed craft specialization, WITHOUT agriculture

Elaborately carved boats, paddles, boxes and other artifacts

Page 24: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 25: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 26: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Potlatch Potlatching is tied to rank and status in a

highly stratified society like the Haida Moiety social organization: each person

belongs to the moiety of his or her mother, and must take a spouse from the opposite moiety

Each moiety may have up to 20 clans, each with many households, and up to 30 people in a household

Page 27: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Clans control hunting territories, including salmon streams and sea mammal grounds.

Clans also own names and titles to boats, songs, dances, ceremonies, and carvings

People accumulate foods, oils, furs, blankets, slaves, and copper shields, but this was traditionally for potlatching, not for trade

Page 28: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Traditional potlatches Surplus is distributed through

potlatches Funeral potlatch – ascension to a

title after the death of a relative Face-saving potlatch – to establish

place after being humiliated Vengeance potlatch – to destroy an

enemy

Page 29: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Redistribution mechanisms The potlatch, the New Guinea pig feasts,

and the Mexican cargo system distribute surplus, but not the means of production. Thus, they are not wealth leveling mechanisms.

Roy Rappaport’ study of New Guinea pig feasts: Pigs for the Ancestors (1984)

Frank Cancian’s study of the Mexican cargo system: Economics and Prestige in a Maya Community (1992)

Page 30: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Tsembaga say that the pig feast is part of the cycle of war and peace and that the spirits of the ancestors would be upset if the Tsembaga failed to sacrifice the pigs.

Rappaport showed both the cycle of war and the pig sacrifices were part of a single process that maintained meat protein – up to a point.

Page 31: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Money True money has portability,

durability, homogeneity, and divisibility

Examples include: Diawara shells in New Britain, Melanesia; Wampum in Nieuw Amsterdam; Kwakiutl copper shields; Sudanese cowries; and Yap money wheels

Page 32: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Diawara shells Diawara shells in New Britain, Melanesia

were efficient. Standard unit of one fathom string of

shells One string bought 60-80 taro roots, but a

chicken was one quarter of a unit Stored in large coils in money houses and

accumulated as capital, with bankers lending at interest the money given to them by wealthy men

Page 33: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

 

Chumash bead money from olivella (purple olive) shells on the Channel Islands.

Page 34: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

                                               

Like wampum, the value of Chumash money depended on the labor required to make it. Beads made from the opening of the shell were more valuable because. As with other shell money systems around the world, Chumash money was measured by the length of the string.

Page 35: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Wampum Also fathom length string, but used as

measures of wealth, as ornaments, and as means of recording important events, in addition to trade.

Given as tokens of friendship and as a pledge of honor in treaties

Value of wampum was determined by the number of beads and the color: purple and white had different values

Page 36: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 37: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Porcelain wampum It took skill and time to make

wampum and there was hardly any inflation until the 19th century, when fur traders brought in porcelain beads.

The Dutch law of 1650: good quality = 6 white and 3 purple per

stiver poor quality = 8 and 4

Page 38: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Yap money wheels: Rai Caroline Islands, Micronesia – the

Yap trading empire The wheels were from 1-12 feet in

diameter. This meant that some wheels never moved, but changed hands (one remained in the lagoon).

The wheels are not portable or divisible, but they are very durable.

Page 39: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 40: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The cost of manufacture The wheels were made from

argonite that was quarried on Palau and Guam.

Guam is 550 miles from Yap; Palau is 300 miles.

Open ocean expeditions required provisions to crews on the islands during the quarrying.

Page 41: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

O’Keefe money A 12-14” stone of good quality was

worth 50 baskets of taro, yams, or bananas; or 1 pig of 80-100 pounds.

Large wheels could be traded for land – even whole plantations.

“O’Keefe money” (David Dean O’Keefe) was discounted because of the difference in labor and risk.

Page 42: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Optimal foraging theory From Eric Smith at the University of

Washington: The decision rule in OFT is:

add prey types to the set taken, in descending rank order, until reach the jth prey type where Vj/Hj < Vi /

(Ts + Hi)

[Note: V = value (e.g., calories) for each prey type; Ts

= total search time; = "sum of"; H = average handling time for prey items of each prey type]

Page 43: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

OFT "Add prey types until the return rate from

a prey type is lower than the average rate of return for all higher-ranked prey types (including search time)"

So, the optimal diet means that adding types of prey to diet eventually leads to a decrease in the overall rate of return.

Page 44: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Optimal foraging theory The Aché of eastern Paraguay choose to

hunt chacoan peccaries (which are hard to find and take) rather than armadillos (which are easy to find and take)

Peccaries yield 4,600/hr Armadillos yield 1,800 calories/hr A hunt of only peccaries and deer yields

148/hr

Page 45: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

OFT II Adding coatis and pacas increases the yield

to 405/hr Palm fruit 946/hr; you can’t live only on palm

fruit Adding a total of 16 species yields 872/hr Thus, abundance of a food resource does not

by itself determine its use. The amount it contributes to the overall efficiency of food production is important.

Page 46: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and
Page 47: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Harris’ environmental efficiency rating

Richard Lee studied the !Kung (Bushmen) of the Kalahari desert in South Africa

For a sample of days, there were, on average, 7.4 workers per day, each working, an avg. of 6 hours.

Avg. caloric expenditure is 150 cal/hr, for normal work regimes.

Thus: 7.4 x 6 x 150 = 6660 calories/day

Page 48: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Lee calculated that the !Kung produced, on average, 64,200 cal/day across the sample of days

The efficiency rating of the !Kung is thus: 64,200/6660 = 9.6 Lee counted 20 food producers in the

group. He then calculated the number of hours per year per food producer

23,433,000 = 813 hours/yr

Page 49: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Genieri Genieri of Gambia produce 460,000,000

cal/yr with 334 food producers, each working about 820 hr/yr. Their environmental efficiency is thus about 11.2

For a similar effort, there is a 20-fold increase in calories produced because of the higher carrying capacity of the land under the technology of horticulture.

Thus, the working population of the Genieri village was about 500, or about 25 times that of the !Kung.

Page 50: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Tesmbaga Maring of Papua New Guinea

Early Neolithic technology thus produces larger and more stable populations, but not that much more efficiency in food production.

Tsembaga Maring of highland New Guinea. They produce 150,000 calories per year, with 146 workers, each working, on average, 380 hours per year. Efficiency: about 18.

Page 51: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Tsembaga planted 42 acres out of 864 when Rappaport studied them in 1962-1963.

They also kept pigs -- 160 maximum. The efficiency rating for pigs is much lower (about 2.1), but pigs are a stable source of protein.

The Tsembaga regenerated their forest every 20 years and their density was stable at 67/sq mile

Page 52: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Compare to the !Kung, at 1/sq mile So the Tsembaga depleted the

biomass of the forest, but their pigs and their increased technology sustained them.

Note the principle of intensification

Page 53: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Luts’un Village in China 1947

Lutsu'un village in Yunan province Rice cultivation with intensive agriculture 418 workers (total population of about 700)

in 1947. They produced about about 3.6b calories,

working 1129 hours each, with ER = 53.5. Allow 2,500/day per person. This requires

633 million cal. Where does the surplus go?

Page 54: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Industrial U.S. In the 1980s, about 5 million food

producers generated three trillion calories in the U.S.

They worked 1,700 - 3,600 hours/yr This produced a maximum ER = 210. However, Harris pointed out that in the

1980s it took 8 calories of inputs to produce 1 calorie of food

Page 55: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Technoenvironmental efficiency ratings Source: Marvin Harris 1984 “”People, Culture, Nature” (data from 1980)

Society Annual calories (in millions)

Food producers in 1980

Hours/ food producer

Calories/ hour/ person

Efficiency rating

Technology

!Kung 23 200 805 150 9.6 H/G Genieri 460 334 820 150 11.2 hort. Tsembaga 150

18 146 146

380 400

150 150

18.0 2.1

S/B pigs

Luts’un 3780 418 1129 150 53.5 irrig. ag. US 260,000 5m 1714 150 210.0 indust. ag.

Page 56: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Why do people work more now than they did 30 years ago?

One farmer produces 52m calories or 30,000 calories per hour.

In 1970, the average blue-collar worker earned $3.42/hr and food cost $600/yr.

Food was $600/$6840 annual wages = ~ 9% In 1990, the average blue-collar worker earned

$13.50/hr and food cost about $4860/yr Food was $4860/$27,000 = ~18% Today, Americans are working ~2000 hours per

year and earn, but food costs more.

Page 57: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Chayanov’s rule: Chayanov’s rule: the largest number of

producers relative to the number of consumers in a family yields less work per producer.

So, if household consumption is the only reason to work, the evolution of efficiency in production systems will produce less work per person.

But we see that this rule doesn’t apply in industrial economies with high costs for children.

Page 58: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Political and economic systems Just as we ask how and why did

people give up H/G for agriculture, we should ask why did people develop hierarchical systems of control?

Page 59: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Power, authority and responsibility

Headmen have no real power All hunting groups have leaders “Of course we have headmen!” the !

Kung told Lee. “We are all headmen. Each one of us is a headman over himself.”

Page 60: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Mehinaku leaders give public speeches every night, exhorting people and must show largesse

Among pastoralists, with concentrated wealth, we can see authority with power emerging

Page 61: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Mekranoti Dennis Werner studied the

Mekranoti village of Kayapo in the Amazon

285 people and one village chief Leadership reputation depends more

on knowledge of Brazilians and Portuguese than on closeness of descent from a chief.

Page 62: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The steps to the Big Man complex

Surplus and redistribution is the first step toward inequalities.

Headmen are redistributors, but not chiefs. They must use egalitarian principles to maintain their prestige.

Intensification produced greater surplus, which produced competition for the role of redistributor.

Page 63: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Leopard Skin Chief The Nuer of Sudan: the Leopard Skin

Chief can cleanse murderers and negotiate the cattle price for taking a life.

He can mediate only with the assent of the parties.

Page 64: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

We see the emergence of the Big Man complex with swidden agriculture: for example, the Siuai of Bouganville, Solomon Islands

Douglas Oliver showed how young men fall into the trap of competing for the honor of being a Mumi, or Big Man, where feasts were like potlatches, with different goods being distributed.

Page 65: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Mumis, however, did not have the power of the Kwakiutl chiefs.

Once again, the key was storage technology.

People depend on emergent chiefs during famines and droughts.

This is the transition to chiefdoms and the first social contract.

Page 66: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Economic and Political Systems

Level of integration

Mode of production

Size Principle of organization

Distribution mechanism

BandH/G <200 egalitarian reciprocity

Tribe

extensive ag. and herding

small village

egalitarian reciprocity

Chiefdom

extensive ag. and herding

large village

rank reciprocity and redis-tribution.

State

intensive ag. and herding

city class Redistribu-tion and markets

Page 67: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Demography and cultural evolution

To recap: H. sapiens lived in H-G bands of 30–

50 for 98% of human history As recently as 3000 ya, most

peoples (not people) were still hunters and gatherers

Page 68: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Transition to surplus The transition to redistribution

probably began with seasonal surpluses and then storage technology.

At the first stage, headmen reinforce the principles of egalitarianism, working harder and receiving prestige and perhaps greater access to polygynous marriage.

Page 69: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The first social contract At the next stage, technology made the

storage of surplus possible. This made the headman’s feasts more of

a ratification of wealth and, eventually, power.

The transition is the point in human history in which the social contract was established and the link between power and authority emerges.

Page 70: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Development of chiefdoms The Trobriand chiefs ruled over a set of

10–15 villages with several thousand people.

Gifts of yams from many affinal relatives as chiefs accumulated wives.

The Cherokee also had chiefs and a paramount chief. The granaries were given special donations for chiefs, who lived in luxury.

Page 71: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Chiefdoms and states Chiefdoms everywhere display big

architecture: Stonehenge, Easter Island, Olmec, Ohio-Tennessee-Mississippi Valley

Chiefdoms are all on their way to becoming states.

But stratification based on sex and race and class are quite recent in human history.

Neither inequality nor war are genetic.

Page 72: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

Why then, do we have war? Melvin and Carol Ember have studied this

across cultures: 1. Centralized societies have armies, and all

that this entails in terms of arms and organization, but the frequency of war is no greater than in band or tribal level societies.

2. War is unlikely in small populations and territories.

3. Formal alliances don’t lessen the chance of war.

Page 73: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

4. Trading partners go to war more often than non-partners.

5. Military equality did not traditionally lessen the likelihood of war, though the nuclear age has partly changed this – at least temporarily.

6. Democracies do not go to war with one another, the American Civil War notwithstanding.

Page 74: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The problem of causation, again

Societies do not go to war over chronic food shortage.

In preindustrial societies, people often go to war over fear of unpredictable natural disasters.

Page 75: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

War is not universal The Semai of the Malay penninsula

hold nonviolence as an ideal. Among 12,000, Clayton Robarchek

found a single case of homicide during 1963-1976, or <1/100k

Richard Lee found 29/100k for the !Kung

Page 76: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

The Yanamamo case The Yanamamo have very high level

of violence – 64/100 F/M ratio for under 10 years, despite the killing of men in battle (25% of all male deaths).

Page 77: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

New Guinea case In New Guinea highlands, warfare was endemic. There was an increase in intertribal warfare after

contact with Europeans in some areas of New Guinea.

Prior to contact, tribes traded for salt, axes, shells, feathers, pandanus oil, and fur. After contact, European trade goods led to endogamy and a lack of trading between villages at different elevations.

The reduction in intertribal marriage led to loss of political relations between autonomous groups

Page 78: Economic anthropology All societies have systems to allocate access to natural resources, systematic ways to convert resources to goods and services, and

War in New Guinea highlands before and after contact

Before contact After contact

N percent N percent

Between tribes 85 75 30 40

Within tribes 29 25 44 60

Total 114 100 74 100