trade and distributional impact of genetically modified ... · pdf filetrade and...

44
1 Trade and Distributional Impact of Genetically Modified Crops in India: A CGE Analysis * Amrita Chatterjee Associate Fellow National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER) New Delhi, India Arpita Ghose Reader, Department of Economics Jadavpur University Kolkata, India and Sanjib Pohit Chief Economist National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER) New Delhi, India 1. Introduction Application of Biotechnology in agriculture and commercialization of Genetically Modified (GM) Crops have been an issue of much debate. The benefits of GM crops in terms of increase in crop productivity, alleviation of poverty, reduction of Environmental footprints of Agriculture, mitigating climate change, reducing Greenhouse gases etc are well approved worldwide (James, 2007).At the same time there are questions raised regarding the negative environmental and health effects of these crops by opponents of GM food. This has paved the * This paper was written when the first author was a UGC-Senior Research Fellow in Jadavpur University, Kolkata, Inida.

Upload: lynga

Post on 24-Mar-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

Trade and Distributional Impact of Genetically Modified Crops in

India: A CGE Analysis∗

Amrita Chatterjee

Associate Fellow

National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER)

New Delhi, India

Arpita Ghose

Reader, Department of Economics

Jadavpur University

Kolkata, India

and

Sanjib Pohit

Chief Economist

National Council of Applied Economic Research (NCAER)

New Delhi, India

1. Introduction

Application of Biotechnology in agriculture and commercialization of Genetically

Modified (GM) Crops have been an issue of much debate. The benefits of GM crops in terms of

increase in crop productivity, alleviation of poverty, reduction of Environmental footprints of

Agriculture, mitigating climate change, reducing Greenhouse gases etc are well approved

worldwide (James, 2007).At the same time there are questions raised regarding the negative

environmental and health effects of these crops by opponents of GM food. This has paved the

∗ This paper was written when the first author was a UGC-Senior Research Fellow in Jadavpur University, Kolkata, Inida.

2

way for several economic studies to give a clear idea about the prospective effects of adoption

of GM crops.

India’s approach towards modern biotechnology has been focused and systematic. The

Department of Biotechnology was created in February 1986 to independently pioneer the

multifaceted development of biotechnology in the country. In India use of all GM substances is

regulated under the Environment (Protection) Act 1989 (EPA) and the Rules 1989 (Rules). As

per the notification of the Ministry of Environment and Forest on 5th December, 1989 the

Genetic Engineering Approval Committee (GEAC) was established among others which was

responsible for approval of proposals related to release of Genetically Engineered Organisms

and products into the environment including experimental field trials. On March 2002, GEAC

took a milestone decision to give permission for commercial production and sale of three Bt

cotton varieties. Since then the success story of Bt Cotton in India is a remarkable one. In 2008,

5 million small farmers are cultivating 7.6 million hectare of Bt cotton with an adoption rate of

80% (James, 2008). In spite of this high success rate there have been very strong opponents of

biotechnology who have thwarted the further spread of this techno logy. As a result no other GM

crop has been approved by GEAC so far, though Bt bringal has been approved by GEAC for

commercialization in October, 2009. However, very recently the Ministry of Environment and

Forest announced its decision to impose a moratorium on the release of the transgenic brinjal

hybrid developed by Mahyco, a subsidiary of global seed giant Monsanto. The moratorium will

last till such time independent scientific studies establish, to the satisfaction of both the public

and professionals, the safety of the product from the point of view of its long-term impact on

human health and environment, including the rich genetic wealth existing in brinjal in India.

India and GM crops:

• Department of Biotechnology was established in 1986. • Use of all GM substances is regulated under the Environment (Protection) Act

1989 (EPA) and the Rules 1989 (Rules). • Genetic Engineering Approval Committee (GEAC) was established in 1989 for

approval of proposals related to release of Genetically Engineered Organisms and products into the environment including experimental field trials.

• On March 2002, GEAC gave permission for commercial production and sale of three Bt cotton varieties.

• In 2008, 5 million small farmers are cultivating 7.6 million hectare of Bt cotton with an adoption rate of 80% in India.

3

There have been considerable numbers of papers which have used Computable general

Equilibrium technique to analyze the impact of introduction of GM-potential crops into the

production structure of different countries under various scenarios. Smale et al. (2006) gave a

detailed survey which includes 14 papers involving developing countries using a modified

version of CGE model based on the GTAP database. Among those, we focus on the group of

papers which have analyzed the effect of introduction of specific GM potential crops in some

specific regions. Anderson and Yao (2001) and Huang et al (2004) considered various GM

adoption related policy issues regarding China whereas Elberhri and MacDonalnd (2004) and

Anderson and Jackson (2005a) have analyzed the case of Sub-Saharan Africa. Anderson and

Jackson (2005b) have studied introduction of some GM crops in Australia and New Zealand

under various trade scenarios. Hareau et al (2005) have evaluated the potential adoption of three

different rice varieties in Asian countries without considering any trade scenario. The studies

which have included India as one of the countries in their regional aggregation are as follows.

• On March 10th, 2006 the Central Government of India in consultation with the Central Committee for Food Standards published two draft rules to amend the Prevention of Food Adulteration Rules (1955), introducing labeling and approval requirements for GM food and products derived form it.

• The Draft Rule 37-E Labeling of Genetically Modified Food states that all primary or processed foods, food ingredients or food additives derived from a GM food require to be labeled accordingly and the imported GM foods should indicate the status of approval in the country of origin

• Bt bringal has been approved by GEAC for commercialization in October, 2009.

• On February 2010, with severe pressure from the environmental activists and Brinjal producing states, the Ministry of Environment and Forest announced its decision to impose a moratorium on the release of the transgenic brinjal hybrid developed by Mahyco, a subsidiary of global seed giant Monsanto.

• The moratorium will last till such time independent scientific studies establish, to the satisfaction of both the public and professionals, the safety of the product from the point of view of its long-term impact on human health and environment.

4

Anderson, Neilsen and Robinson (2002), Neilsen and Anderson (2001), Anderson and Jackson

(2005b) have studied the effects of adoption of GMOs on global production, trade pattern and

welfare of several non-European countries (including India) in the context of the policy

reactions from Western Europe. Anderson and Jackson (2006) have studied the cause of the

strong aversion of GM crops by EU and its effects on the developing countries’ welfare.

Anderson, Venezuela and Jackson (2006) have focused on GM cotton adoption in developing

countries and have also compared its effects with the WTO rule of removal of cotton subsidies.

Gruere et al (2007) have studied the potential effects of introducing GM food crops in

Bangladesh, India, Indonesia and Philippines in the presence of trade related regulations on GM

food. However, the effect of GM crop adoption on income distribution has not attracted much

attention so far. Anderson and Jackson (2003) have made a significant assumption regarding the

income of farm household i.e. factor shares for farm households are a weighted sum of factor

income shares used in agricultural production and the factor income shares of capital owners.

Results show that the farmers of USA will welcome the worldwide adoption of GM varieties

whereas the EU farmers would like the continuation of the EU GM moratorium. Jackson (2004)

has also used same factor ownership structure. Anderson, Jackson and Nielsen (2005) have

considered the same set of assumptions as Anderson and Jackson (2003) in terms of factor

ownership to compare the potential welfare gains from consumer focused golden rice with that

of the producer focused other non-golden rice. They have considered a higher productivity of

the unskilled and non-farm workers with better health with larger vitamin A intake from golden

rice. The results suggest that the welfare gains from the health enhancing golden rice will be

bigger than the gain from productivity improvement which in turn will boost the productivity of

the unskilled laborers in Asian countries.

The perusal of the literature suggests that there is dearth of studies which have

exclusively focused on India to analyze various issues related to GM adoption in detail in CGE

framework. This has been the motivation of the current paper which has studied empirically the

effect of the adoption of GM cotton, soybean, maize and rice on various sectors of Indian

economy using a modified GTAP model. Regarding the policy issues, we have considered a

comparison of a possible imposition and reduction of import tariff by India on vegetable oil and

fat imported from major soybean exporting countries to India. Moreover, incorporating the

Draft rule 37-E of India regarding labeling of GM food, we have considered the effect of

5

introduction of labeling for domestically produced rice in one of the scenarios. In addition to

this, as the profitability of introduction of any new product depends upon the consumers’

acceptance towards it, we have analyzed both positive and negative preference shift of the

Indian consumers towards domestic GM rice the effect of which is yet to be explored in a CGE

frame work. Last but not the least, we have tried to capture the effect of a possible ban imposed

by European Union on import of Indian rice as EU are very much skeptical about the

environmental impact of GM foods. We have considered the effects of all the policies on the

welfare of the country along with the effects on the sectors which are closely related to the GM

potential crops and compared them with the situations when the other countries are also

adopting GM crops. Most importantly, we have studied the distributional effects of all the above

policies which have so far been neglected in the GM related CGE modeling. Here the traditional

method is to use an aggregated CGE with representative households to infer about changes in

the income distribution due to certain policy scenario. The paper has been structured in the

following way. Section 2 explains the methodology, Section 3 & 4 gives the overview of

different scenarios and Section 5 contains the concluding remarks.

2. Methodology and Database

The impact of adoption of GM crops in Indian agriculture has been assessed using the

well-known GTAP (Global Trade Analysis Project) modeling framework which is in detail

documented in Hertel (1997). The model is run through widely used GEMPACK software

package developed by Monash University of Australia. The GTAP model is a multi-region

multi-sector static computable general equilibrium model based on neoclassical macroeconomic

theory. Thus markets are perfectly competitive; profit maximizing producers use the technology

that exhibits constant returns to scale. Like any other general equilibrium model GTAP provides

detailed bilateral trade, transport and protection data with the vertical and horizontal linkages

between all product markets both within the model’s chosen countries and regions and also

between the countries and regions via bilateral trade flows. We have modified the GTAP model

to incorporate the cost of labeling incurred by the j th industry which uses i th commodity as

intermediate input. Further, we have followed Nielson and Anderson (2001) to modify the

model to capture the issue of consumer preference (See Appendix 1 for details of the modified

6

model). The database used here is that of version 7 with 113 countries/regions and 57 sectors

(Badri Narayanan G. and Terrie L. Walmsley, 2008) with a base year of 2004. For the present

purpose this database has been aggregated for 13 regions and 14 sectors (Given in Table 1).

Among them 8 regions (USA, Argentina, Brazil, Canada, India, China and South Africa) are the

top 7 countries (other than Paraguay, included in rest of South America) producing 50,000

hectares or more of biotech crops from the ISAAA brief no 39 (James, 2008). The others are

comprised of rest of the countries in the list of 14 mega countries producing biotech crops, EU

and some Asian countries. The sectoral aggregation has been done keeping in mind the main

GM potential crops and their related processing industries.

2.1 Scenarios:

The main objective of this paper is to assess the possible economic impact of

commercialization of GM crops in India on both the producers and the consumers in presence of

different relevant policy prescriptions. In achieving this goal 6 prospective scenarios have been

designed. Among the biotech crops which are providing maximum benefits are soybean, maize

and cotton (James, 2006). Thus the GM driven productivity improvement is considered in these

three crops. Moreover, rice being the most important food crop for the poor people of the world,

deserves it’s inclusion in the analysis. Accordingly, the first scenario deals with adoption of GM

cotton by India. The second scenario considers the adoption of GM soybean and GM maize

whereas the third scenario analyzes the possible impacts of adoption of GM rice. In each of

these first three scenarios a 10% Hicks-neutral productivity shock has been given i.e. a uniform

reduction in all the inputs to obtain the same level of production (i.e. a total factor productivity

(TFP) shock). Since GTAP database does not contain separate sectors for cotton, maize and

soybean, a proportionality factor (proportion of area under cultivation of seed cotton in fiber

crops, maize in total cereals and soybean in primary oil crops ) has been used as a weight to

productivity shock (Source: FAOSTAT). To segregate the GM and non-GM crop production,

the adoption rate of respective GM crops is used as a second weight to productivity shock. For

all these three crops two alternative sub-scenarios have been developed to compare the impact

of a lower adoption rate of the GM crops with that of a higher one. An adoption rate of 50% is

compared with a more prospective rate of 80%. We have also reported the situation where other

countries except EU are adopting all the GM crops along with India at a flat adoption rate of

7

50% for all the crops. For other countries also the respective proportionality factors have been

considered. The above scenarios are additive in nature as we add one after another crop in each

scenario.

Furthermore, we have brought into consideration some important policy scenarios.

Scenario 4 deals with the comparison of imposition and withdrawal of import tariff by 20% by

India on vegetable oil and fat imported from Other Asian countries (being the largest exporter

of vegetable oil and fat to India) given the fact that India as well the three trading partners have

adopted only GM soybean. The fifth scenario is designed to capture the issue of increase in

labeling cost for domestically produced GM rice under the condition that India is adopting only

GM rice. The next scenario investigates the consumer’s response towards GM rice in India.

Thus both positive and negative response to domestically produced rice has been considered in

presence of labeling policy adopted in only rice sector, when India adopts only GM rice and no

other country has adopted GM rice. The last scenario takes into account the hypothetical

situation when European Union imposes an import ban on Indian GM rice, given the fact that

only India adopts GM rice and exports it.

Table: 1 Regions and Sectors used for General Equilibrium Modeling of the present study

Regions Sectors

1. Oceania

2. China

3. USA

4. Argentina

5. Brazil

6. India

7. Canada

8. South Africa

9. Other Asia (Hong Kong, Japan,

Korea, Taiwan, Rest of East Asia,

Cambodia, Indonesia, Lao

People’s Democratic Republic,

Myanmar, Malaysia, Philippines,

1. Rice

2. Cereal Grains (Maize)

3. Oilseeds (soybean)

4. Grains Crops (wheat, vegetable, fruits

and nuts, Sugar cane, sugar beet, crops

necessary)

5. Plant based fibers (cotton)

6. Processed food (sugar, food products

necessary, Beverages and tobacco

products)

7. Meat products and livestock (cattle,

Sheep, goat, horses, animal products

necessary, wool, silk-worm, cocoons,

8

Singapore, Thailand, Vietnam,

Rest of southeast Asia, Bangladesh

Pakistan, Sri Lanka and Rest of

South Asia )

10. Other Latin American Countries

( Other Latin America,

Bolivia, Chile, Colombia,

Ecuador,Peru,Mexico, Colombia,

Chile, Uruguay, Venezuela,

Rest of South America, Costa Rica,

Guatemala, Nicaragua, Panama,

Rest of Central America, Caribbean.

11. EU_25

12. Sub-Saharan Africa

13. Rest of the world

meat: (cattle, sheep, goats, horse, meat

products necessary))

8. Milk and dairy

9. Extraction (Forestry and fishery,

coal,oil, gas, Minerals necessary)

10. Vegetable oil and fats

11. Processed rice

12. Textile

13. Manufacturing

14. Services

3 Assessment of economic impact under various scenarios:

3.1 Scenario 1: commercialization of GM cotton in India

India is the largest cotton growing country in the world. As per ISAAA brief 39, in 2008,

5 million small farmers planted 7.6 million hectares of Bt cotton in India which is equivalent to

82% of adoption rate. Thus we have compared, in this scenario, two prospective adoption rates

of 50% and 80% for Bt cotton with a 10% Hicks-neutral productivity shock to the cotton sector.

A 10% reduction in the overall production cost in cotton sector will have its effect of textile

sector as well. Table 2 and Table 2(a) show the effects of adoption of Bt cotton in India with a

lower adoption rate of 50% and a higher rate of 80% respectively on the cotton and textile

sector. With a fall in production cost due to adoption of GM cotton, there is increase in output

which is followed by a fall in supply price. However, the magnitude of these changes depends

on the adoption rate. For a lower adoption rate supply price is reduced by 4.16% and 0.46%

respectively whereas output is increased by 2.24% and 1.32% in cotton and textile sector. With

a higher adoption rate supply price is lower by 6.66% in cotton sector and 0.74% in textile

sector. Output will also increase at a higher rate of 3.58% and 2.12% respectively. The lower

9

supply price has led to an increase in consumer demand which is up by 1.63% and 0.32 %

respectively. A higher adoption rate prompts a much higher demand for cotton and textile at the

rate of 2.61% and 0.5% respectively. Also there is an increase in exports. With a lower adoption

rate of 50%, export increases by 18.26% in cotton sector and by 3.08% in textile sector. A

higher adoption rate of 80% shows the prospect of increase in export by 29.22% and 4.93% in

the two sectors in concern. Thus the extent of increase in exports increases with increase in

adoption rate. Here we must take note of the fact that, domestic demand may have increased less

than proportionately compared to the increase in output level. This has led to an increase in

export and a fall in import in both the sectors by 8.64% and 1.17%. Import will be much lower

(by 13.83% and 1.87% in cotton and textile sector) if India adopts Bt cotton at a higher rate.

With rise in export and fall in import, trade balance is obvious to improve. It has improved more

in textile sector (450.4 million USD) than in cotton sector (62.42 million USD). Trade balance

will further improve with 80% adoption rate (see Table 2 (a)).

Table 2: Sectoral effects (in % change form) of adoption of Bt Cotton in India when the

adoption rate is 50%

Sector Supply Price Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

Demand (Million USD)

Cotton -4.16 2.24 1.63 18.26 -8.64 62.42

Textile -0.46 1.32 0.32 3.08 -1.17 450.4

Table 2 (a): Sectoral effects (in % change form) of adoption of Bt Cotton in India when the

adoption rate is 80%

Sector Supply Price Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

Demand (Million USD)

Cotton -6.66 3.58 2.61 29.22 -13.83 99.88

Textile -0.74 2.12 0.5 4.93 -1.87 720.63

10

3.2 Scenario 2: commercialization of GM maize and soybean along with GM cotton in India

This scenario considers the adoption of GM maize and soybean in addition to GM cotton

in India. With 10% Hicks neutral productivity shock in these two sectors, output increases by

0.16% and 0.34% respectively with an adoption rate of 50% (See Table 3 and 3 (a)). As the

adoption rate increases to 80%, output in these sectors increases by 0.26% and 0.54%. The

supply price on the other hand is lower by 0.48% and 1.13% in the two sectors respectively

which leads to increase in consumer demand by 0.12% and 0.19%. For higher adoption rate

supply price falls by 0.77% and 1.81% in maize and soybean sector leading to a rise in

consumer demand by 0.19% and 0.31% respectively. In India 51% of total Maize consumption

goes to poultry sector and only 26% is used for human consumption (The Associated Chambers

of Commerce and Industry of India (ASSOCHAM) report, 2009). Thus consumer demand for

maize is not growing at a very high rate, but with higher adoption rate situation is expected to

improve. Exports of maize increase by 1.09% whereas imports showed a decline by 0.48% with

a lower adoption rate leading to an improvement in trade balance by 1.36 million USD. A

higher adoption rate reduces maize import by 0.77% and raises export by 1.75% thereby

improving the trade balance by 2.17 million USD. As far as soybean is concerned, with a fall in

import and rise in export the trade balance gets improved by 12.7 million USD which is further

reinforced by a trade balance of 20.31 million USD with increase in adoption rate.

Table 3: Impact on maize and soybean sector (in % change form) due to adoption of GM maize

and GM soybean along with GM cotton at the rate of 50% by India

Sector Supply Price Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

Demand (Million USD)

Maize -0.48 0.16 0.12 1.09 -0.48 1.36

Soybean -1.13 0.34 0.19 4.71 -2.56 12.7

11

Table 3(a): Impact on maize and soybean sector (in % change form) of adoption of GM maize

and GM soybean at the rate of 80% by India

Sector Supply Price Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

Demand (Million USD)

Maize -0.77 0.26 0.19 1.75 -0.77 2.17

Soybean -1.81 0.54 0.31 7.53 -4.09 20.31

3.3 Scenario 3: Adoption of GM Rice in India with 10% productivity shock and 50%

adoption rate along with GM cotton, maize and soybean

The current scenario deals with GM rice adoption in India over and above GM cotton,

maize and soybean. Rice being the most important food crop in India, two different rates of

adoption i.e. 50% and 80% are considered. A 10% productivity shock and 50% adoption rate

will lead to a rise in output in rice sector by with a fall in supply price. It will lead to rise in

consumer demand. However, rise in demand may be less than the expansion of output, thereby

leading to an increase in export. With fall in import, there is an improvement of trade balance.

With a higher adoption rate of 80% the direction of change are same though the magnitudes are

higher. Results can be seen for both lower and higher adoption rates from table 4.

Table 4: Impact on rice sector (in % change form) of adoption of GM rice in India

Sector Adoption Supply Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

Rate Price Demand (Million USD)

Rice 50% -6.45 1.08 0.77 46.25 -31.6 51.26

80% -10.32 1.74 1.24 74 -50.56 82.01

3.3.1 Decomposition of Economic Welfare:

12

Now, table 5 shows, how the adoption of these GM crops have substantial welfare effect

in India, which is measured in terms of equivalent variations of income. This can be interpreted

as the change in the regional household income at constant prices that is equivalent to the

proposed change. We have further decomposed the EV into three components as per Huff and

Hertel (2000). The adoption of only GM cotton leads to an improvement of welfare of 393.36

million USD, most of which is due to the value added augmenting technical change (arises out

of change in the uses of inputs available for production). With addition of maize and soybean

the welfare is further enhanced to 609.43 million USD. However, the adoption of GM rice leads

to considerable jump in welfare (1192.93 million USD). In both cases major share of

improvement in EV comes from productivity shock.

Table 5: Decomposition of economic welfare when India adopts GM cotton, maize, soybean and

rice in India

Commodity Equivalent Variation Decomposition of Welfare

adopted (EV,Million USD)

Allocative Terms Of Value Added

Efficiency Trade Augmenting

Effect Effect Technical

Change

Cotton 393.36 27.29 9.99 259.64

Cotton,

maize and 609.43 22.43 10.89 464.09

soybean

Cotton, maize, 1192.93 40.68 2.02 1005.77

Soybean and

rice

3.3.2 Distributional Effects:

Table 6(a) and 6(b) give the change in the distributional effects of adoption of GM

cotton, soybean, maize and rice, adoption rate being 50%. Land being a sluggish factor of

production can not be easily reallocated between alternative uses. Hence land rent differentials

13

are allowed across sectors. As Hicks neutral productivity shock has been given to cotton, maize,

soybean and rice sectors, demand for land falls in these sectors leading to a fall in land prices in

these sectors. As factors have become more productive, in aggregate less land is required for

higher production. Labor and capital are perfectly mobile domestically. Though less labor is

needed for production in these sectors due to improvement in productivity, total demand for

labor will increase with increase in total production. Moreover, with a fall in supply price of the

sectors which are experiencing productivity shock (as they together enjoy a significant share in

the consumption basket of India consumers), the real income of laborers may rise for both

skilled and unskilled labor. However, the income of the skilled labor increases more compared

to the unskilled labor. Here we note that the capital income has also increased, though the

percentage increase is higher than unskilled labor and lower than skilled labor. Thus the highest

benefit goes to the skilled labor which gives an interesting insight into the fact that the GM

technology needs more scientists and extension workers to spread its benefit to the grass root

level. Another observation can be made here, which points out to the widening wage gap of

skilled to unskilled wages. This is in conformity with the existing literature. Shariff and Gumber

(1999) has put forward the evidence that suggests that the wage-gap between the graduate and

non- literate has widened significantly in transport and storage, agriculture and in services in

India. This trend has continued even if the productivity shocks are experienced.

Table 6 (a): % change in demand for factors used in different sectors in India

Factor Rice Maize Soybean Cotton

Land -5.12 0.31 -0.31 -2.43

UnSklab -7.16 -0.5 -1.26 -3.85

Sklab -7.2 -0.54 -1.3 -3.89

Cap -7.17 -0.51 -1.27 -3.87

14

Table 6(b): Effects of adoption of GM crops on factor income (in % change form) in India

Factor Prices Adoption of GM cotton, GM maize, GM soybean and GM Rice

(real income)

Land -1.96

Unskilled labor 0.44

Skilled labor 0.56

Capital 0.48

3.3.3 Effect on other sectors:

The adoption of GM cotton, maize, soybean and rice will have its effects on the other

sectors which are closely related to these sectors. A fall in land price has led to expansion in

output and accordingly a fall in supply price of the crops which use land more intensively than

others such as wheat, sugar and other food crops. The sectors like animal products, milk and

dairy are gaining as they use soybean, maize and rice as their intermediate inputs at a cheaper

price. Soybean and rice are also used in vegetable oil and fat and processed rice. Moreover, the

land not used by the GM adopting sectors can well be utilized by other sectors which will also

help then to raise the production level. The change in magnitudes can be seen from Table 7.

15

Table 7: Impact of adoption of GM cotton, maize, soybean and rice (in % change form) on the

other sectors of the economy

Sector Supply Price Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Demand Grains Crops -0.44 0.29 0.22 1.94 -0.82 Processed food 0.02 0.15 0.17 -0.09 0.2 Meat and Livestock -0.45 0.47 0.34 2.88 -0.69 Milk and Dairy 0 0.24 0.24 -0.04 0.25 Veg oil and fat -0.62 1.37 1.06 3.54 -0.87 Processed Rice -0.99 0.4 0.25 3.4 -2.26 Extraction 0.06 -0.16 0.21 -0.56 0.02 Manufacturing 0.16 -0.09 0.18 -1.11 0.49 Services 0.23 0.09 0.24 -0.76 0.43

3.3.4 Trade effect on other countries

Now, if we look at the trade effects on trade balance of other countries (Table 8) when

only India is adopting GM crops, it is clear that the major rice exporting south-east Asian

countries which are part of our other Asian countries are losing the market share to India. Even

in case of textile also the major cotton exporting countries like Bangladesh, Pakistan (among

other Asian countries), China and USA are affected adversely due to low cost products of India.

As far as maize and soybeans are concerned, though India does not enjoy much trade share in

these sectors, USA and Brazil will be to some extent on the losing side which will be a gain for

some other Asian countries.

16

Table 8: The effect on trade balance of the other countries when only India is adopting the GM

crops (in million USD)

Countries Rice Cotton Textile Maize Soybean

USA -9.81 -23.39 -40.12 -3.72 -9.16

Argentina -0.04 -0.01 -0.18 -0.24 -1.53

Brazil -0.09 -3.32 -1.95 -0.29 -6.21

South Africa -0.01 -0.83 -3.14 -0.1 -0.03

China -1.39 0.15 -98.97 -0.33 0.91

Canada -0.18 -0.18 -3.64 -0.07 -3.36

Rest of

Latin

American -2.81 -0.89 -12 0.17 -1.06

Countries

Oceania -0.3 -5.68 -3.66 -0.23 -0.9

Other Asia -15.18 -0.27 -77.25 2.25 9.61

SSA -0.61 -15.11 -0.7 0.07 -0.68

3.3.5 Trade Scenario:

3.3.5.1 Scenario 3(a): Adoption of GM cotton, maize, soybean and Rice in India and in all

other countries except EU with 10% productivity shock and 50% adoption rate

This scenario shows how the adoption of GM crops by other countries except EU

(Canada not adopting GM cotton) changes the global trade pattern. First we consider the effects

on India when other countries are also producing GM crops (Table 9). With other countries

17

adopting the GM crops, India has lost its export share in world market both for the rice and

cotton sectors which is reflected in the significant fall in the trade balance in these two sectors

compared to the situation when only India was adopting GM crops. In textile sector though,

India’s dominance is continued with a slight improvement in trade balance in this sector.

However, in maize and soybean sector India is losing its market to other major trading countries

in the world.

India:

Table 9: Sectoral effect (in % change form) in India when all the other countries except EU is

adopting all the GM crops under consideration

Sector Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance

(Million USD)

Rice 30.3 -11.67 30.16

Cotton 10.77 -4.98 35.83

Textile 3.44 -1.03 487.19

Maize -1 -0.02 -4.58

Soybean -0.11 -2.43 -5.35

Now, if we compare these results with the other GM adopting countries in the world

(Table 10), it is observed that the other Asian countries (mostly south-east Asia) which are the

main rice exporters have gained the most from the GM rice adoption. India has gained much

more than China in terms of exports revenue from rice. Brazil, other Latin American countries

and sub-Saharan African countries have also gained. As far as textile sector is concerned, China

has the possibility of gaining the most which in fact gives tough competition to the other major

textile exporting countries in Asia and also USA, though in cotton sector almost all the countries

are doing well. In maize sector, USA and Argentina are losing their share to other Latin

American countries and some Asian countries. The three major players in the world soybean

market i.e. USA, Argentina and Brazil have lost their market share to some extent to China,

Other Latin American countries and other Asian countries. Thus adoption of GM crop is giving

18

greater benefits to the Asian countries and low-income developing countries of Latin America

along with the Sub-Saharan Africa compared to the high- income developed countries.

Table 10: Secrotal effects (in % change form) of GM adoption on all the other countries Sector USA Argentina Brazil Canada South Africa China Other Latin Other Asia Oceania SSA

American

Countries

Rice

Export 0.3 -7.37 -5.7 -26.19 -13.03 1.06 3.94 13.9 -5.65 9.28

Import 7.1 4.61 -0.73 3.48 1.22 1.05 -3.55 -5.02 0.84 -2.57

Trade

Balance -18.54 -3.27 4.23 -0.23 -0.29 -2.35 14.4 40.89 -1 15.76

Cotton

Export 3.95 -2.79 3.12 -7.72 -5.9 -0.38 1.06 -1.64 5.12 5.77

Import -3.85 1.38 0.54 2.05 3.15 0.79 0.48 0.47 -1.94 3.07

Trade

Balance 35.08 -0.01 3.9 -1.23 -5.41 51.33 3.76 81.37 10.39 43.45

Textile

Export -0.08 -0.75 -0.38 -0.42 -0.64 0.55 -0.31 0.02 -0.09 1.5

Import 0.11 0.11 0.26 0.09 0.4 -0.02 0.09 0.15 0.09 0.06

Trade

Balance -26.33 -3.95 -10.31 -17.1 -13.54 392.88 -44.72 -100.42 -1.36 50.13

Maize

Export 1.08 -0.55 3.06 -1.73 1.01 -0.43 2.63 1.03 -1.48 0.68

Import -1.22 1.69 -0.79 0.73 -0.83 -1 -0.56 0.04 0.76 0.35

Trade

Balance -46.8 -18.99 8.99 -8.2 -0.06 -4.48 29.67 88.91 -13.81 3.5

Soybean

Export 2.81 0.43 2.29 -4.05 -3.66 -1.06 3.74 -0.76 -4.3 -5.07

Import -2.75 5.52 2.24 2.22 -0.41 0.31 -0.81 0.01 0.42 0.64

Trade

Balance 3.94 -41.48 -27.28 -89.07 -0.4 111.71 39.62 107.06 -25.46 -24.02

19

3.3.5.2 Decomposition of Economic Welfare:

It is easily observable from Table 11 that the maximum welfare gain is captured by the

Asian countries like China, India and the south-east Asian giants. The interesting fact is that

though they have gained from cotton, maize and soybean adoption, rice is the main source of

this improvement in welfare. The enhancement in export revenue from rice has led to this huge

gain. Thus the adoption of GM rice has a very significant role to play in these Asian economies.

Here we want to note that USA is gaining more from cotton, maize and soybean adoption rather

than rice. EV after rice adoption has gone down slightly for USA (from 716.91 million USD

after cotton, soybean and maize adoption to 618.25 million USD) which can be attributed to the

increase in rice export share of China and other Asian countries. Same is the story for

Argentina. It is evident from the loss of EV from the terms of trade effect. Brazil, South-Africa

and other Latin American countries have improved their welfare with GM adoption, though the

magnitude of their gain varies. As far as Canada and Oceania are concerned, though they have

considerable share in soybean export, they are facing steep competition mainly from USA. As a

result their welfare has gone down. Australia-New Zealand, however, having a large share in

cotton and textile export, gains from cotton adoption.

20

Table 11: Decomposition of economic welfare measured in terms of EV (in million USD)

Country EV(Million USD) EV(Million USD) EV(Million USD)

After cotton adoption after cotton, maize and after cotton, maize,

By all the countries soybean adoption by soybean and rice

all the countries adoption by

all the countries

USA 290.44 618.25 716.91

Argentina -1.06 90.56 76.54

Brazil 3.87 209.1 263.76

Canada 14.36 14.01 15.62

South Africa 8.01 30.25 38.1

China 290.04 586.46 1292.52

Rest of Latin 24.21 237.26 325.06

American

Countries

Oceania 54.88 18.89 -24.19

Other Asia 182.04 484.59 2487.46

SSA 51.15 178.42 316.83

4. Policy scenarios:

4.1 Scenario 4: Comparison of withdrawal and imposition of 20% import tariff by India on

vegetable oil and fat imported from Other Asian countries

21

Among the GM potential crops soybean and soybean oil are the major agricultural

products imported by India. According to the Directorate General of Commercial Intelligence

and Statistics under the Ministry of Commerce and Industries, government of India, India has

imported oilseeds worth Rs.12133.09 lacs and vegetable (edible) oil, which includes soybean

oil, worth Rs.1443769.26 lacs within the period April 2008-February 2009. The major exporters

of vegetable oil to India are other Asian countries. The Government of India on 28th November

2008 imposed a 20 per cent import duty on crude soybean oil, while keeping the import duty on

other crude vegetable oils at zero. However, it has subsequently abolished the 20 per cent import

duty bringing it on the same level as other crude vegetable oils such as palm, sunflower, and

rapeseed. This has led to the current scenario, where we compare the effect of withdrawal and

imposition of import tariff by 20% on vegetable oil imported from other Asian countries by

India. In this scenario we have assumed that India and Other Asian countries are adopting only

GM soybean which is modeled as a 10% productivity shock (with 50% adoption rate) to

soybean sector in these four countries while no other country is adopting any other GM crop.

Over and above this, the shock corresponding to 20% tariff reduction and imposition on

vegetable oil and fat imported from other Asian countries are given separately. Table 12 (a) and

12 (b) respectively give the sectoral effects of withdrawal and imposition of 20% tariff on India.

Withdrawal of import tariff has led to significant flow of cheap import of vegetable oil and fat to

India (by approximately 20%) whereas the imposition of tariff will lead to obvious fall in

import. Comparing with the scenario of productivity shock to soybean sector in India and other

Asian countries, it can be observed that, there is a significant fall in output of vegetable oil & fat

after the additional shock of withdrawal of import tariff. With the withdrawal of import tariff

there will be a fall in price of imported vegetable oil & fat which will lead to a fall in demand

for the domestic counterpart of the product. This will lead to rise in India’s export of vegetable

oil & fat, though it will be outweighed by large rise in import. As a result there will be

considerable fall in trade balance compared to the productivity shock scenario. On the other

hand, with imposition of import tariff, imported vegetable oil and fat will be costlier which will

lead to significant rise in demand for domestic soybean. As a result there will be rise in

domestic production of vegetable oil & fat accompanied by a fall in export, though its

magnitude is not very significant. Since import has been reduced to a great extent, there will be

much improvement in trade balance.

22

Table 12 (a): Sectoral effects of 20% reduction of tariff on vegetable oil and fat imported from

Other Asian countries Sector Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Demand Balance Vegetable oil -12.35 -19.1 7.73 20.41 -384.68 and fat

Table 12 (b): Sectoral effects of imposition of 20% tariff on vegetable oil and fat imported from

Other Asian countries Sector Output Consumer Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Demand Balance Vegetable oil 14.16 20.43 -2.61 -21.85 474.23 and fat

4.1.1: Decomposition of Economics welfare:

From Table 13 (a) and (b) it is evident that there is huge improvement in the economic

welfare after the withdrawal of import tariff, which is mainly due to the allocative efficiency

though there are adverse terms of trade effect. However, there is significant fall in EV from

imposition of import tariff due to allocative inefficiency, even if terms of trade effect improves.

23

Table 13 (a): Decomposition of economic welfare measured in terms of EV (in million USD)

with withdrawal of import tariff Equivalent Variation

(EV,Million USD)

Decomposition of Welfare

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms Of

Trade

Effect

Change

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical

800.85

736.77

-91.85

187.14

Table 13 (b): Decomposition of economic welfare measured in terms of EV (in million USD)

with imposition of import tariff

Equivalent Variation

(EV,Million USD)

Decomposition of Welfare

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms Of

Trade

Effect

Change

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical

-402.95

-745.84

95.33

187.14

4.1.2 Distributional effects:

Table 13 (c) and 13 (d) give the change in demand for different factors of production

used in vegetable oil & fat sector due to withdrawal and imposition of import tariff respectively.

24

With the imposition of import tariff there will be a rise in demand for domestically produced

vegetable oil and fat. As a result demand for all the factors of production rises in this sector

compared to the situation when India and its trading partners are experiencing productivity

shock in soybean sector only. However, with rise in domestic demand, there will be rise in

domestic price of vegetable oil and fat as well. This can outweigh the rise in nominal income of

the factors of income as both soybean and vegetable oil and fat as significant share in total

consumption of Indian consumers. This can be the possible cause of fall in real income of

capital, skilled and unskilled labor. Opposite happens when the tariff is withdrawn. As there will

be a fall in demand for domestically produced vegetable oil & fat, the demand for all the factors

of production will fall in this sector accompanied by a larger fall in price of the domestically

produced vegetable oil and fat. This may lead to rise in real income of capital, skilled and

unskilled labor. Here also skilled laborers have benefited more than the unskilled laborers. The

impact on real income of the factors of production is reported in table 13 (e).

Table 13 (c): % change in demand for factors used in vegetable oil & fat sector in India after

withdrawal of import tariff

Factor vegetable oil & fat

Land -4.91

UnSklab -12.31

Sklab -12.43

Cap -12.37

Table 13 (d): % change in demand for factors used in vegetable oil and fat sector in India after

imposition of import tariff

Factor vegetable oil & fat

Land 6.22

UnSklab 14.15

Sklab 14.2

Cap 14.16

25

Table 13(e): Effects of adoption of GM crops on factor income (in % change form) in India

after withdrawal of import tariff

Factor Prices Withdrawal of import Imposition of import

(real income) tariff from vegetable tariff on vegetable

oil and fat oil and fat

Land -1.39 0.68

Unskilled labor 0.32 -0.17

Skilled labor 0.42 -0.21

Capital 0.36 -0.18

4.2 Scenario 5: Labeling cost increases by 10% on intermediate input used by GM rice and

their related sectors

This scenario examines the effect of introduction of mandatory labeling requirement for

GM food adopted in India. On March 10th, 2006 the Central Government of India in

consultation with the Central Committee for Food Standards published two draft rules to amend

the Prevention of Food Adulteration Rules (1955), introducing labeling and approval

26

requirements for GM food and products derived form it. The Draft Rule 37-E Labeling of

Genetically Modified Food states that all primary or processed foods, food ingredients or food

additives derived from a GM food require to be labeled accordingly and the imported GM foods

should indicate the status of approval in the country of origin (Gruere and Rao, 2007). Now, this

labeling involves some costs and there are few studies evaluating the cost of labeling in

developed countries. As far as the developing countries are concerned, a study regarding

Philippines evaluated that the mandatory labeling leads to an increase in production cost of 11-

12% (Gruere, 2007). Since cotton is a non-food crop, it does not require a label. So in this

scenario we have considered the adoption of only GM rice by India. Here we have assumed a

10% increase in the production cost of domestically produced GM rice and also for the sectors

which use rice as intermediaries due to labeling requirement (milk & dairy and processed rice)

over and above 10% productivity shock. The GTAP model has been modified accordingly to

incorporate the labeling cost for domestically produced GM rice (see appendix A.2). Currently

we are refraining from the issue of labeling on imported commodities. Table 14 gives the

sectoral effects this labeling policy for domestic GM rice in India.

Table 14: Sectoral effects (in % change form) of labeling policy in India Sector Output Export(fob) Import(cif) Trade Balance (Million USD) Rice 0.79 47.03 -31.19 52.14 Milk and Dairy 0.04 1.1 -0.53 1.5 Processed Rice -0.14 -2.09 1.48 -17.96

Here we note that, the price of rice used as intermediate input was reduced by 6.32%

from baseline situation after the 10% productivity shock to rice sector in India, which has

increased by 3.35% from the baseline in rice, milk & dairy and processed rice sector under the

labeling policy scenario, which is obvious given the fact that the production cost has gone up

due to labeling requirement. Due to increase in production cost output has fallen in both rice and

rice related sectors compared to the situation of GM rice adoption (from 1% to 0.79% in rice

sector, from 0.36% to -0.14% in processed rice and from 0.13% to 0.04% in milk & dairy). The

27

domestic demand for rice as intermediary in all these sectors has fallen compared to previous

scenario, may be due to rise in price level, which has prompted a fall in import (expect

processed rice sector) and a rise in export leading to an improvement in trade balance. Here we

observe that even after a rise in price of processed rice due to labeling its demand has increased

though output has not grown to satisfy that. This has prompted a rise in import and a fall in

export, leading to a deterioration of trade balance. This may be explained by a price inelastic

demand for processed rice, if processed rice contains the finer and costlier varieties of rice.

4.2.1 Decomposition of Economic Welfare:

Table 15: Decomposition of Economic Welfare

Country Equivalent Variation(EV,Million USD) Decomposition of Welfare

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms

Of

Trade

Effect

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical

Change

India -43.16

2.34

-74.16

541.69

Since labeling is costly and any positive utility towards the consumers arising out of the

availability of new information about GM crops are not considered he re, there is a fall in

welfare in terms of equivalent variation for India (table 15).

4.2.2 Distributional Effects:

Due to imposition of labeling policy, demand for all the factors of production falls as

output has reduced in rice and related sector compared to the scenario where only adoption of

the GM crop take place. As a result real return to all the factors of production falls. However,

even if output falls, it remains above the baseline projection. Thus, the effect of productivity

shock outweighs the negative effect of labeling policy. Accordingly, price of both skilled and

unskilled labor rises. Here an important observation is that skilled labor is benefited more

compared to the unskilled labor. As a result the skilled-unskilled wage gap has increased from

the productivity shock scenario to the labeling policy scenario, thereby widening the wage gap.

28

Table 15 (a): % change in demand for factors used in different sectors in India after imposition

of labeling policy

Factor Rice Land -3.56 UnSklab -4.72 Sklab -4.74 Cap -4.73

Table 15(b): Effects of adoption of GM crops on factor income (in % change form) in India

after imposition of labeling policy

Factor Prices Labeling on domestic rice

(real income)

Land -1.43

Unskilled labor 0.12

Skilled labor 0.2

Capital 0.18

4.3 Scenario 6: Preference shift towards domestically produced rice and its related sectors

with labeling policy applicable on GM rice India, when no the other country is adopting GM

crops

In this scenario we try to analyze the consumer’s attitude towards GM crop. Rice being

the most important food crop for Indian consumers, it is essential to investigate how Indian

consumers will accept the introduction of GM rice in their consumption basket. Deodhar et al

(2008) have studied the Indian consumer’s awareness; opinion and willingness to pay for GM

food and have shown that, consumers are willing to pay a premium of 19.5% for golden rice and

16.12% for edible oil due to high nutritional value and low pesticide usage in GM crops. This

study is based on the questionnaire survey on 602 respondents in the city of Ahmedabad and

110 other over internet. There is dearth of literature which has tried to capture the issue of

Indian consumer’s preference towards GM food through a CGE analysis. In this paper we have

29

considered Nielson and Anderson (2001) model to modify the existing GTAP model to

incorporate the above issue (see appendix for details of the modifications). We have assumed

that India is adopting only GM rice and a labeling requirement is there on the GM rice given

that no other country is adopting GM rice. Under such circumstances both positive and negative

preference shift of 25% has been given to GM rice and its related sectors which use rice as their

intermedia te input such as processed rice and milk & dairy. This has been done to capture the

exclusive effect of preference shift for and against GM food by Indian consumers. From Table

16 it is clear that a positive preference shift towards GM rice will lead to an increase in

consumers demand for GM rice which will push the supply price upwards. Accordingly output

will rise. It seems it will be unable to meet the domestic demand prompting an import of rice

and a cut in export. Thus further productivity boost will be required in rice sector along with

wider adoption of GM rice to handle the emerging situation. As far as the other sectors are

concerned, milk & dairy sector is not much affected as it does not use significant amount of rice

as intermediate input. However processed rice sector is facing reduced export revenue due to

rise in prices as it has got an important share in India’s export basket. If there is a negative

preference shift of the consumers towards GM rice in India (see Table 17), consumer’s demand

for rice will be reduced by 23% leading to an excess supply of rice that prompts a fall in supply

price. As a result import of rice gets reduced and export rises, lading to a substantial

improvement in trade balance.

Table 16: Sectoral effects of +25% preference shift towards GM rice in India

Sector Supply Output Consumer Export Import Trade Balance

Price Demand (Million USD)

Rice 3.96 21.3 24.62 -28.26 20.46 -31.29

Milk & Dairy 0.72 -0.14 -0.1 -5.01 2.46 -6.84

Processed Rice 2.71 -0.71 -0.26 -9.46 6.71 -80.09

Table 17: Sectoral effects of -25% preference shift towards GM rice in India

Sector Supply Output Consumer Export Import Trade Balance

Price Demand (Million USD)

Rice -17.04 -19.73 -23.35 122.32 -82.84 135.57

30

Milk & Dairy -1.03 0.22 0.15 7.22 -3.53 9.85

Processed Rice -1.55 0.43 0.16 5.27 -3.74 44.17

4.3.1Decomposition of Economic Welfare:

Now if we compare the welfare effects of a positive and a negative preference shifts, it is

evident that India will be better of with a positive preference shift towards GM crops as the

welfare measured in terms of EV will be enhanced by 387 million UDS (see Table 18(a)). Here

we note that, with only rice adoption the welfare effect was much higher, though with labeling

requirement it has gone down substantially. However, with a positive preference shift it has

again recovered and showed a considerable improvement from the baseline. With a negative

preference shift against GM rice the welfare will further go down and will settled much below

the baseline projection (see Table 18(b)). Thus there is a trade off with this policy scenario

between a positive trade balance and a negative welfare for consumers. If there is higher

adoption of GM rice accompanied by higher productivity shock, the situation may improve.

Table 18 (a): Decomposition of economic welfare with Positive preference shift

Country Equivalent Variation

(EV,Million USD)

Decomposition of Welfare

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms Of

Trade

Effect

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical Change

India 387.38

-170.94

350.16

541.69

Table 18 (b): Decomposition of economic welfare with negative preference shift Country Equivalent Variation

(EV,Million USD)

Decomposition of Welfare

31

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms Of

Trade

Effect

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical Change

-473.71 175.62 -498.53 541.69

4.4.3 Distributional Effects:

Table 19 (a): % change in demand for factors used in different sectors in India with preference

shifts Factor Rice

Positive preference shift Negative preference shift

Land 13.7 -20.82

UnSklab 18.33 -27.78

Sklab 18.41 -27.89

Cap 18.38 -27.85

Table 19(b): Effects of adoption of GM crops on factor income (in % change form) in India

with preference shifts

Factor Prices Rice

(real income) Positive preference shift Negative preference shift

Land 6.19 -9.05

Unskilled labor -0.49 0.73

Skilled labor -0.8 1.2

Capital -0.69 1.05

With a positive preference shift towards GM rice, to meet the rising consumer demand,

there is an increase in demand for both land and labor. As a result land prices rise. However,

with excess demand in product market, price of rice rises which in turn reduces the real income

of the laborer in rice sector marginally. Opposite happens in case of preference shift against GM

32

crops. With fall in consumer demand accompanied by a fall in output, there is a substantial

reduction in demand for all the factors of production. However, with a considerable fall in

consumer price, there is a small improvement in real income of the factors. Here also skilled

labor is better off than unskilled labor and thus the skilled-unskilled wage gap has widened.

4.4 Scenario 7: Adoption of GM rice by India in presence of ban on import of rice from India

to EU

The main reason of European Union being skeptical regarding the adoption of GM crops was

because of environmental and food safety concerns, thereby endangering the export market

prospects for adopters of the transgenic crops (Pinstrup-Andersen and Schioler, 2000; Paarlberg,

2003). As a result European Union imposed a de facto moratorium on the production and

importation of food products that may contain genetically modified organisms (GMOs) in 1998.

Though the EU replaced its moratorium in May 2004 with new regulatory arrangements, but

they involve complex and laborious segregation, identity preservation and labeling

requirements.

The perceived risks from the GM-derived foods are that they may contain toxic substances

resulting in allergies and they can alter the genome of the person or animal consuming them.

But such concerns are baseless as per the reports of the EU scientific community (European

Commission, 2001), and the report commissioned by the UK government (King, 2003, p.23).

The latter report concludes that, “the risks to human health are very low for GM crops currently

on the market” (King, 2003, p.23). A newer report, by the Food Safety Department of the UN’s

World Health Organization, concludes: “GM foods currently on the international market have

passed risk assessments and are not likely to, nor have been shown to, present risks for human

health” (WHO, 2005, p.v).They could not find any theoretical reason or empirical evidence to

suggest that GM crops can be more invasive or persistent, or toxic to soil or wildlife than

conventional crop varieties, or spread their genes to other plants. The Nuffield Council on

Bioethics also concluded in a recent discussion paper: “We do not take the view that there is

currently enough evidence of actual or potential harm to justify a blanket moratorium on either

33

research, field trials or the controlled release of GM crops into the environment.” (Thomas et al.,

2004, p.62). However, Anderson and Jackson (2006) has examined the impact of the extreme

position taken by EU regarding the adoption of GM food crops on the developing countries.

In this scenario we have assumed a hypothetical situation such that EU, being very much

skeptical about the adoption of GM foods, has put a ban on import of rice from India to EU if

India adopts GM rice.

Table 20: Sectoral effect of adoption of GM rice in presence of Import Ban from EU

Sector Supply Output Consumer Export Import Trade Balance

Price Demand (Million USD)

Rice -6.52 0.6 0.71 8.26 -32.18 9.36

Referring to table 20 we can observe that, with the imposition of import ban by EU on

Indian GM rice, India’s export will be down by substantial amount. As a result domestic

production has reduced though it is still above the baseline projection. There is marginal fall in

domestic price level. This can prompt a rise in domestic demand for rice. Since export has been

reduced significantly, domestic production is sufficient to feed the domestic demand which can

cause a fall in import as well. Fall in export has resulted in a considerable fall in trade balance.

4.4.1Decomposition of Economic Welfare:

Table 21: Decomposition of economic welfare with Import Ban on Rice

Country Equivalent Variation

(EV,Million USD)

Decomposition of Welfare

Allocative

Efficiency

Effect

Terms Of

Trade

Effect

Value Added

Augmenting

Technical Change

India 584.21

21.84

-9.01

541.69

34

As far as the economic welfare (see table 21) is concerned, India is slightly better off in

spite of the import ban. Though welfare has been reduced due to terms of trade, it is outweighed

by positive allocative efficiency effect.

4.4.3 Distributional Effects:

There is not much distributional effect of import ban by EU on India. As there is a significant

fall in export and output of rice, demand for all the factors of production falls from the scenario

where India adopts GM rice without the ban. Land price has fallen as expected. However, there

is marginal rise in the real return to the other factors of production. This may be due to the fact

that the labor and capital released by the rice sector are absorbed in some other sector where

there were demands for those factors, which is on the balance outweighed by the fall in demand

for factors in rice sector (See table 22 (a) and (b) for the distributional effects).

Table 22 (a): % change in demand for factors used in different sectors in India with import ban

from EU

Factor % change in demand for

factor

Land -3.72

UnSkilled lab -4.93

Skilled lab -4.95

Cap -4.94

Table 22(b): Effects of adoption of GM crops on real factor income (in % change form) in India

with import ban from EU

Factors of % change in Factor Prices

Production (real income)

Land -1.32

Unskilled labor 0.24

Skilled labor 0.33

35

Capital 0.29

Thus we get an interesting observation that import ban on Indian rice has no negative

welfare effect on Indian consumers, in fact it is marginally improved. However, India is losing

much of its export earning from rice.

6.5 Conclusion:

This paper has studied the overall macro-economic impact of adoption of GM cotton,

soybean, maize and rice in India using a modified GTAP model and GTAP 7 database with a

regional aggregation comprising 13 countries and 14 sectors. It tries to contribute in the

literature by exclusively focusing on India taking into account the sectors directly and indirectly

related to above GM potential crops, though the effects on other major GM producing countries

are also reported. Apart from the productivity shocks with both low and high adoption rates the

important policy scenarios considered here are: a comparison of withdrawal and imposition of

import tariff by India on vegetable oil and fat imported from other Asian countries and

introduction of labeling policy for domestically produced rice. We have also analyzed the effect

of both positive and negative preference shift towards GM food crops for Indian consumers.

Moreover, we have studied the possible effect of an import ban imposed by EU on Indian rice.

All these policies have their significant effects on the welfare of the country along with the GM

potential sectors and their allied sectors. Last but not the least we have captured the

distributional effects of all the above policies. Moreover, these results have been compared with

the situation when other countries except EU have adopted GM crops.

The productivity improvement due to GM technology adoption in India has led to an

increment in output for all the GM potential crops considered in the paper followed by a fall in

supply price. Domestic demands have also increased though less than rise in output. This has led

36

to fall in import and expansion of export registering positive trade balance. The economic

welfare measured in terms of EV has improved with adoption of each additional GM crop

though there is a considerable jump in EV with GM rice adoption. The decomposition of the

welfare shows that the major source of it is the productivity shock. As far as the other sectors in

the economy concerned, wheat, sugar and the other food crops, which use land more

intensively, have experienced higher output and a lower supply price. Other sectors which use

either of maize, soybean or rice as intermediate inputs such as animal product, milk & dairy,

vegetable oil & fat and processed rice have also gained. Now, the aspect of income distribution

gives an interesting finding. As far as income distribution is concerned, it has been observed that

the real income of both skilled and unskilled income rises with GM adoption, though maximum

income benefit accrues to the skilled labor. This highlights the importance of skilled

professionals in dissemination of GM technology. However, the skilled-unskilled wage gap has

aggravated, which is supporting the evidence documented in literature though.

The adoption of GM crops by India has some trade effects on the other countries who

are not adopting any GM food products. The major rice exporting south-east Asian giants will

lose market share to India. In textile sector also countries like Bangladesh, Pakistan, USA and

China are adversely affected in terms of trade balance. However, when these countries along

with India adopt GM crops, India loses some of its market share in rice and cotton though its

dominance in world textile market continues. The south-east Asian countries have gained the

most from the GM rice adoption whereas Brazil, other Latin American countries and sub-

Saharan African countries have also gained. As far as textile sector is concerned, China has the

possibility of gaining the most which can give tough competition to the other major textile

exporting countries in Asia and also USA. In maize sector, USA and Argentina are losing their

share to other Latin American countries and some Asian countries. The three major players in

the world soybean market i.e. USA, Argentina and Brazil have lost their market share to some

extent to China, Other Latin American countries and other Asian countries. Thus adoption of

GM crop is giving greater benefits to the Asian countries and low-income developing countries

of Latin America along with the Sub-Saharan Africa compared to the high- income developed

countries. As far as the welfare gains are concerned, China, India and South-East Asian

countries are the major gainer and their main source of gain is GM rice.

37

Turning to the policy scenarios we find, withdrawal of import tariff from vegetable oil

and fat imported from other Asian countries to India when accompanied by productivity

improvement in soybean sector will lead to significant flow of cheap import vegetable oil and

fat to India whereas the imposition of tariff will lead to obvious fall in import. With the

withdrawal of import tariff there will be significant fall in output along with a fall in price of

imported vegetable oil & fat which will lead to a fall in demand for the domestic counterpart of

the product. This will lead to rise in India’s export of vegetable oil & fat, though it will be

outweighed by large rise in import. As a result there will be considerable fall in trade balance

compared to the productivity shock scenario. On the other hand, with imposition of import

tariff, imported vegetable oil and fat will be costlier which will lead to significant rise in

demand for the domestic product. As a result there will be rise in domestic production of

vegetable oil & fat as well as a fall in export, though of insignificant amount. Since import has

been reduced to a great extent, there will be much improvement in trade balance. There is huge

welfare improvement resulting from withdrawal of import tariff from vegetable oil & fat

accompanied by fall in real income. However, opposite happens in both the cases with

imposition of tariff.

The policy of mandatory labeling which raises the production cost by 10% in domestic

rice sector will cause a fall in output and domestic demand, may be due to higher prices. This

will be accompanied by a fall in import and higher exports. Since labeling involves higher

prices and we have not considered any psychological gain from the available GM related

information from the label, there is a fall in EV in India with this policy. As far as the

distributional effects are concerned, the skilled labor has gained more than unskilled labor and

thereby widening the skilled-unskilled wage gap. In the following scenario we compare a

positive and a negative preference shift towards the domestically produced GM rice by the

Indian consumers. A positive preference shift towards GM rice will lead to an increase in

consumers demand for GM rice pushing the supply price upwards and thereby resulting in

output expansion. However, a 10% productivity shock will not be sufficient to meet this boost in

domestic demand prompting an import of rice and a cut in export. Thus further productivity

boost will be required in rice sector. On the other hand if consumers are critical about GM rice

in India, rice sector will face a reduced demand for rice leading to an excess supply of rice that

prompts a fall in supply price. This will result into contraction of import volume and expansion

38

of export, lading to a substantial improvement in trade balance. As far as the welfare gain is

concerned with positive preference shift the country is gaining whereas a negative attitude

towards GM rice reduces economic welfare. However, in case of the negative preference shift

the country has to choose between the negative social welfare and a positive trade balance. The

positive acceptances of the consumers towards GM rice will lead to a rise in land price with

higher demand for land for higher production though rise in price of rice will reduce the real

income of both skilled and unskilled laborers marginally even if there is higher demand for all

the factors of production. In case of negative preference with a fall in price level there is slight

improvement in labor income even if there is fall in demand for factors. Last but not the least; in

order to capture the negative views regarding adoption of GM technology we have analyzed a

hypothetical scenario of imposition of an import ban on Indian rice by EU. This ban will lead to

a significant fall in total export of rice by India. Domestic production will also fall but it will be

sufficient to meet the domestic demand. As a result there will be fall in import as well with an

overall fall in trade balance. However, India will be slightly better off in terms of the economic

welfare and there will be marginal rise in real return to both skilled and unskilled labor.

Thus the macroeconomic overview of various scenarios gives an overall promising

future of India if it adopts the above GM crops. With higher adoption rate of course the benefits

will be higher. This analysis, of course, has taken recourse to the environmentally sustainable

and human health enhancing positive attributes of Genetically Modified food crops, though we

acknowledge that there is a school of thought which has strong reservation against the

commercial production of such crops. Both the views, however, are well supported in the

literature.

6. Appendix:

6.1 GTAP Model:

In the GTAP model the firm’s production structure is characterized by Constant

Elasticity of Substitution functional forms to combine intermediate inputs and primary factors of

production such as land, natural resources, skilled and unskilled labor and capital. Intermediate

inputs are composites of foreign and domestically produced components. International trade is

39

characterized by Armington specification (Armington 1969) such that foreign components of

intermediate goods are differentiated by region of origin. Thus firms can decide the sources of

their imports and based on the composite import price they decide on the optimal mix of the

domestic and imported inputs. On factor market, full employment is assumed with labor and

capital being mobile within the countries but immobile internationally. Natural resources are

only used in non-agricultural primary industries and land is specific to agricultural usage. The

mobility of these factors is determined by a Constant Elasticity of Transformation revenue

function (Powell and Gruen 1968). Land has a negative unitary value of CET whereas natural

resource has the value of -0.001. The greater the absolute value of CET, the greater will be the

mobility of the factor and hence the extent to which the rental rates across alternative uses move

together.

On the demand side of the GTAP model, each region is comprised of a representative

household who disposes of the entire regional income according to a Cobb-Douglas utility

function specified over three forms of final demand such as private household expenditure,

government expenditure and savings. Now, private household expenditure is defined over a

Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE) demand system that permits different price and income

responsiveness across countries (MacDougall 2003).

Moreover, there is an explicit treatment for international trade and transport margins and

a global banking sector intermediates between global savings and consumption. The model

determines trade balance in each region endogenously and hence foreign capital inflow may

supplement regional domestic savings.

The closure of the model is of general neo-classical general equilibrium type with saving

investment equality and clearance of the factor markets. It ensures endogenous wages and full

employment of all the resources. Each of the economic relationships described in the model are

based on literature reviews and econometric estimates.

A.2 Modifications in the present model: 1. We have incorporated a new exogenous variable named labeling cost (lbc) in the

equation that links the domestic market and the firm prices. The new equation becomes: pfm (i,j,r) = tfm (i,j,r) + pim (i,r) + lbc (i,j,r) 2. Following Neilsen and Anderson (2001) (GMOs, Trade policy and Welfare in Rich

and poor countries) we have incorporated preference shift parameters in the behavioral relations

40

of producers and households. The original model has a set of equations that describe the individual producing sector’s demand for domestically and imported intermediaries respectively. A sector j in region s uses intermediate input i which can either be imported or domestically produced. The following two equations determine the j th sector’s demand for imported and domestically produced intermediate input qfm (i, j,s) and qfd (i, j,s) respectively.

(1) qfm (i, j,s)= qf (i,j,s) -ϒ(i )* [pfm (i,j,s)-p f(i,j,s)] + ffm (i,j,s)

(2) qfd (i, j,s)= qf (i,j,s) -ϒ(i )* [pfd (i,j,s)-p f(i,j,s)] + ffd (i,j,s) (3) pf (i,j,s )= FMSHR (i,j,s)* pfm (i,j,s)+ [1- FMSHR (i,j,s)] * pfd (i,j,s) In the first two equations two preference shift parameters have been included which are

ffm (i,j,s) and ffd (i,j,s). ffm (i,j,s) = 25 implies a 25% increase in the demand for imported

intermediary i in sector j in region s whereas ffd (i,j,s)= -25 implies a reduction in the demand for domestically produced intermediary i.

The following are the behavioral relations for private household and the public sector:

(4) qpm (i,s)= qp (i,s) - ϒ(i )* [ppm (i,s)-pp (i,s)] + fpm (i,s)

(5) qpd (i,s)= qp (i,s) - ϒ(i )* [ppd (i,s)-pp(i,s)] + fpd (i,s) (6) pp (i,s)= PMSHR (i,s) * ppm (i,s)+ [1- PMSHR (i,s)] * ppd (i,s)

(7) qgm (i,s) = qg (i,s) - ϒ(i )* [pgm (i,s)-pg (i,s)]+ fgm (i,s)

(8) qgd (i,s) = qg (i,s) - ϒ(i )* [pgd (i,s)-pg (i,s)]+ fgd (i,s) (9) pg (i,s)= GMSHR (i,s) * pgm (i,s) + [1- GMSHR (i,s)]* pgd (i,s) Above equations have two dimensions and contain preference shift parameters as earlier

equations. References

Anderson, K., and L.A. Jackson (2005a). Some Implications of GM food technology policies for

Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of African Economics 14(3): 385-410.

Anderson, K., and L.A. Jackson (2005b). GM crop technology and trade restraints: economic

implications for Australia and New Zealand. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 49:

263-281.

Anderson, K., and S. Yao. 2003. China, GMOs and World trade in agriculture and textile products.

Pacific Economic Review 8: 157-169.

41

Anderson. K., C.P. Nielson., and S. Robinson.2002. Estimating the economic effects of GMOs:

The importance of policy choices and preferences. In Evenson, R.E., V. Santaniello., and D.

Zilberman. (eds), Economic and Social Issues in Agricultural Biotechnology. CAB International,

London.

Anderson., K., and L.A. Jackson (2006). Transgenic crops, EU precautions and developing

countries. International Journal of Technology and globalization. Vol 2 (1/2): 65-80.

Anderson., K., E. Valenzuela and L.A. Jackson. 2006. GM cotton adoption, recent and prospective:

A global CGE analysis of economic impacts. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.

3917.

Anderson., K., L.A. Jackson., and C.P. Nielson (2004). Genetically Modified Rice Adoption:

Implications for Welfare and Poverty Alleviation. World bank Policy research Working Paper.

WPS 3380.

Armington.P.S., 1969. A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production.

International Monetory Fund Staff Paper 16: 159-176.

Badri Narayanan G. and Terrie L. Walmsley, (Ed). 2008. Global Trade, Assistance, and Production:

The GTAP 7 Data Base, Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

Deodhar ., Y. S., and S. Ganesh and W.S. Chern (2008) Emerging Markets for GM foods: An

Indian perspective on consumer understanding and willingness to pay. International Journal of

Biotechnology. 2008. Vol 10(6): 570-587.

Elbehri, A., and S. MacDonald. 2004. Estimating the impact of Bt cotton in west and central Africa:

A general equilibrium approach. World Development 32 (12): 2049-2064.

European Commission (2001) GMOs: Are There Any Risks?, Press Release by Research

Directorate-General European Commission, October 8, available at http://europa.eu.int/

comm./research/press/2001/pr0901en.html.

42

Gruere. G., A. Bouet., and S. Mevel.2007. Gene tically Modified Food and International Trade: The

Case of India, Bangladesh, Indonesia and the Philippines. IEPRI Discussion Paper 740.

Gruere., G. and S.R. Rao (2007). A Review of International Labeling Policies of Genetically

Modified Food to Evaluate India’s Proposed Rule. AgBioforum, Vol 10(1): 51-64.

Gruere., G., 2007. Labeling Policies of Genetically Modified Food: Lessons from an

International Review of Existing Approaches. PBS, IFPRI Policy Brief 7.

Hareau, G.G., G.W. Norton, B.F. Mills, and E. Peterson. 2005. Potential benefits of transgenic rice

in Asia: A general equilibrium analysis. Quarterly Journal of International Agriculture 44(3): 229-

146.

Hertel. T. W. (Ed). 1997. Global Trade analysis: Modelling and Applications. Cambridge university

Press.

Huang, J., R. Hu., H. Meijl., F. Tongeren. 2004. Biotechnology boosts to crop productivity in

China: trade and welfare implications. Journal of Development Economics 75, 27-54.

Huff. M.K., and T.W. Hertel (2000) Decomposing welfare changes in GTAP model. GTAP

technical paper no. 5.

James, Clive. 2006. Global Status of Commercialized Biotech/GM Crops: 2006. ISAAA Brief No.

35. ISAAA: Ithaca, NY.

James, Clive., 2007. Global Status of Commercialized Biotech/GM crops: ISAAA brief 37, ISAAA:

Ithaca, NY.

James, Clive., 2008. Global Status of Commercialized Biotech/GM crops: ISAAA brief 39,

ISAAA: Ithaca, NY.

43

King, D.K. (2003) GM Science Review: First Report, Prepared by the GM Science Review

Panel under the chairmanship of Sir David King for the UK Government, July.a, NY.

MacDougall. R., 2003. A new regional household demand system for GTAP. GTAP Technical

Paper No.20. Purdue University. Available at: http://docs.lib.purdue.edu/gtaptp/20.

Nielson., C.P., and K. Anderson 2001. GMOs, trade policy, and welfare in rich and poor countries.

In Quantifying the Impact of Technical Barriers to Trade. Ed. J. Maskus, and J. Wilson. Ann Arbor:

University of Michigan Press.

Paarlberg, R.L. (2003) The Politics of Precaution: Genetically Modified Crops in Developing

Countries, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

Pinstrup-Andersen, P. and Schioler, E. (2000) Seeds of Contention: World Hunger and the

Global Controversy Over GM Crops, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

Powell A.A. and F.G.H. Gruen., 1968.The constant elasticity of transformation production

frontier and linear supply system. International Economic Review. Vol. 9(3): 315-328.

Smale, M.,P. Zambrano., J. Falck., G. Gruere. (2006). Parables: Applied Economics literature about

the impact of genetically engineered varieties in developing economies: EPT Discussion paper 158.

International Food Policy Research Institute.

Thomas, S. et al. (2004) The Use of Genetically Modified Crops in Developing Countries,

Nuffield Council on Bioethics, London.

WHO (2005) Modern Food Biotechnology, Human Health and Development: An Evidence-

based Study, World Health Organization, Geneva, June.

44